Loading...
HomeMy WebLinkAbout; Agriculture Committee General Info (1979); Program Report; 1979-05-30. , c- ", DATE : May 30, 1979 REV1 SED : June 1, 1979 TO: Paul Bussey, City Manager '. FROM: James C. Hagaxnan, Planning Director A6# RE : CITY COUNCIL POLICIES ON CALAVERA HILLS WASTEWATER TREATMENT PLANT The Carlsbad City Council has approved the following new City policies in their consideration of the Calavera Hills treatment plant. I have listed the policies in two groupsl the first being those policies applying to the City generally and the second being those policies related directly to the proposed Calavera Hills wastewater treatment plant. A) City Wide Policies: . 1. 2, 3. 4. 5. It is the City Council policy and determination that a satellite treatment facility is aGceptab1e in the north- east drainage basin of the City. The City Council. has determined that no wastewater facility will be considered by this Council unless it is also designed to be used for water reclamation, The City Council has determined 'that it is necessary to develop a city wide reclamation policy including the . principle uses of reclaimed water and has requested City staff to develop a work program for a reclamation policy, City Council has requested City staff to prepare a work program for agricultural land preservation for the City, City Council requested staff to prepare a work progrun providing €or mitigation of growth inducing aspects considered in the Mon.tgornery report as follows: a) Public facilities element and capital improvement .d 9 program. b) Mandated General Plan review every three years. c) Urban land reserve program. d) Growth monitoring program. e) Specific Plan for special treatment areas, f) Work plan which includes a City growth management proqram. .* -. x%, Fmorandum - Paul y May 30, 1972 /Revisec June 1, 1979 Page 2 s B) Determinations directly related to Calavera Hills: 1. 2, ' 3, 4. 5. 6. 7. City Council indicated a pref-erence for the alternate site 3-B identified in the Montgomery Report, City Council indicated desire to review pump station sites along with the treatment facilities for environ- mental considerations. City Council accepted the percolation beds contained jin the Montgomery Report and indicated their desire to s-dy and analyze potential recharge areas near Rancho Carlsbact Mobile Home Park. City Council determined that additional failsafe iines beyond the normal back-up systems to be built into the p1an.t not be included for raw sewage and further deter- mined it would delay a decision on an effluent failsafe system until an overall Master Plan of satellite treatment plants has been adopted by the Council. City Council determined that a l,Z3mgd plant will be built initially at the Lake Calavera Hills site. City Council determined that the financing for- +&e plant will be provided by the developer and that the developer and staff shall enter into negotiations which will, hopefully, require a minimum of .reimbursement.snd City involvement in the financial aspects of .the project,. When staff .and developer complete their negotiations, they shall return to the City Council'for their approval, City Council determined that the City will maintain and operate the plant after completion. JCH: jd 6/1/7 9 c END OF PREVIOUS DOCUMENT. ANOTHER DOCUMENT FOLLOWS <. THE TiIUSl' FOR PUBLIC LAND - 1ntrc;duction One of the most pervasive threats to the filture of family farming in this country is the escalating va1v.e of farmlmd. While many farmers md ranchers view their land as the fsm- ily's nest egg, increasingly there are those who realize that the land's value, hidden in the total operarion, can j,eopardize an heir's ability to inherit the farm intact. The high price 04 land also restricts young, aspiring farmers and ranchers from szwting their own operation. in any case, with growing frequency family I farms end ranches are falling into . the hands ~f ebsentee owners, hobby farmers, and energy and residential developers. Many experts predict that in the long run this trend will seriously damage the quality of life in rural communities and greatly decrease our nation's capacity to produce fwd. Land entered the debate ovei- methods to reverse this trend by proposing a land conservation model for agricul- , tural communities that enjoys wide- rarlgirig smcess elsewhere in the cozntry : locai land trusts. In Colorado, Wyoming and California, TPL has since helped ranchers and farmers incorporate the nation's first local agricultural land trusts. They have Seen formed to ease the speculative pressures on productive land and promote its continued use for agri- culture. In 1979, the Trust for Public What Is a Land - Trust? A land trust is a locally-based, nonprofit corporation governed by a board of residents responsible to the community at large. Forming a land trust enables a community to own or control land rind thus pro- vides- an important non-govern- mental mechanism to affect local land-use decisions. The primary activity of an agri- cultural land trust, as envisioned by TPL, will be to acquire develop- ment rights over farmland in the form of Conservation easements. This will be accomplished when the landowner donates or sells the development rights to the local lnnd trust, thereby lowering his eventual estate and inheritance taxes. By contributing a portion of the land value to the land trust, the owner may ais0 qualify for important income tax benefits. In instbnces where the farmer has sold the devel- opment rights, he can invest the money as part of a long-term estate planning program. Should the owner want to sell the operatim, the reduced land value will make the land more affordable for new farmers and ranchers. Land trusts can also employ other land-s&ving techniques such as acquisition and lease-back, partial develcpment, and transfer of devel- opment rights. Agricultural Land Trusts: The Nation's ,First Examples TPL is guiding agricultural cornmu- nities to assess the feasibility of local land trusts. One is a group of orchardists on the west slope of the Rockies, near Grand Junction, Color- ado. There they have consistently opposed subdividing local lands and installing sewer interceptors that would enable energy-related deveiop- ment to occur. Concerned by pre- dictions of growth in their area, I orchardists and other citizens hauG formed the hlesa County Land Conser- vancy. The new land trust expects to complete its first transactions in 1981, when it acquires conservation easements over productive orchard lands. Dairy ranchers in west Marin County, pressured by urban sprawl in the San Francisco Bay area, formed the Marin Agricultural Land Trust in the summer of 1980. Despite prefer- ential property tax laws and strict county zoning regulations, ranchers continue to see dairies transformed into 60-acre "ranchettes." Such ( subdivision squeezes out ranching in . the area by pushing land values higher still. In several presentations to Farm Bureau members and conservationists, TPL was able to show, based on hypo- thetical financial analyses, how a land trust can offer an alternative to paying burdensome death taxes and provide some assurance of continued family ownership. The new land trust is currently drafting a model conservation easement for the are,a's interested ranchers. END OF PREVIOUS DOCUMENT. ANOTHER DOCUMENT FOLLOWS AGRICULTURE ELEMENT BASIC DATA REPORT DEPARTMENT OF PLANNING AND LAND USE MAY 1979 BAS IC DATA REPORT FOR THE AGRICULTURE ELEMENT Author Lee Vance, Assistant Planner Contributing taff Ken Carlson, Associate Planner Nick Marinovich, Research Analyst II Jeff Parsons, Planning Alde I Lana Lacy, Planning Aide I Text Process in9 Janet Ross, Senior Clerk/Typist Betty Farnam, Intermediate Clerk/Typist Technical Support John Schmitz, Planning Technician II Patricia Rutledge, Planning Aide I1 Jose Wright, Planning Aide II Department of Planning and Land Use 1600 Pacific Highway San Diego, California 92101 TABLE (bF CONTENTS PART I .. INTRODUCTION ....... 1 ................ 1 Introduction ........................ 2 Direction ........................ 2 Study Area ......................... 2 Purpose ......................... 2 Assumptions ........................ 4 Resources ....................... 3 PART I I .. PHYSICAL RESOURCES ... 1. ............... 5 Chapter 1 .. Climate Areaclimates . . Air Quality . . Chapter 2 .. Soils . Chapter 3 .. Water . Background ... Availability . . cost ...... Water Quality . Use ...... Reuse ..... Summary of Part II . ............... :::::I ............... 12 6 ..... ............... 13 ..... ............... 16 "~ ..................... 23 ..................... 23 .....,.......... ...... 23 ...................... 26 ..... ............... 29 ..................... 30 ..... 7 ............... 31 ..................... 34 PART I I I .. CULTURAL RESOURCES ................... 36 Chapter 1 .. Subregional Areas ................ 37 A . Pendleton-Deluz Subregion .............. 37 B . Fa1 lbrook ...................... 40 C . Bonsall ....................... 43 D . North County Metropol i tan Subregion ......... 46 E . San Diegui to Community Plan ............. 49 F . Pa1a.Pauma ...................... 52 G . Valley Center .................... 54 H . Otay Mesa ...................... 56 1 . Poway ........................ 59 J . Ramona ........................ 61 Summary of Chapter One .................. 69 Chapter 2 .. Fruit and Vegetable Packing Industry ....... 70 Fruit Packing Industry .................. 70 Vegetable Packing Industry ................ 71 Fruit and Vegetable Wholesalers In San Diego County ... 72 K . Rainbow-Lakeside-Valle de Oro and Crest/Dehesa .... 64 i . Page PART IV .. ANALYSIS OF THE AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY OF SAN DIEGO COUNTY .................... 73 Chapter 1 .. Introduction and Summary ............. 74 in San Diego County ............... 77 Chapter 2 .. Copley International and Pacific Consultants Economic Analysis of Agricultural Viability Chapter 3 .. University of California Extension Service Summary Chapter 4 .. An Economic Impact Analysis of Agriculture in of the Agricultural Economy in San Diego County . . 82 San D iego County ................. 87 Summary and Conclusion ................. 87 Detailed Results of the Economic Impact Runs ....... 88 Methodology ....................... 91 Land Producing Tomatoes ................ 92 A Comparison of Low Density Residential Development On PART V .. METHODS OF PRESERVING AGRICULTURE ............ 94 Chapter 1 .. Compensatory Programs for Preserving Agriculture . 95 Preferential Property Tax Assessment: The Williamson Act .................... 95 Transfer of Development Rights .............. 104 Purchase and Lease-Back ................. 106 Methodology ....................... 107 Large-Lot Zoning ..................... 110 Density Zoning ...................... 114 Chapter 2 .. Regulatory Methods for Preserving Agriculture . . 110 PART VI .. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS ................. 119 Summary and Conclusions ................. 120 - . FOOTNOTES ............................. 122 . ii LIST OF TABLES Table Number 1 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 Page Temperature Summary Of San Diego County In Relation To Areaclirnates ............ 9 Annual Temperature Data Comparison ......... 9 Criteria For Avocado Suitabi 1 ity .......... 18 Criteria For Citrus Suitability .......... 18 Criteria For Truck Crop Suitability ........ 19 Criteria For Tomato Suitability .......... 19 Criteria For Flower Suitability .......... 19 Subregional Soil Table ............... 22 Water Rates .................... 28 Water Quality And Plant Tolerance ......... 29 Water Use By Crop ................. 30 Water Use By Residential Density .......... 31 Subregional Resource Table ............. 38 Return On Investment Of Agricultural Crops In San Diego County ................ 77 Cost Of Local Water In Agricultural Production ... 78 Agricul ture Revenue Summary. San D iego County -9 Selected Crops (In 1977 Dollars) ........ 80 Land Value Per Production Unit Of Agricultural Land For Agricultural Uses .. San Diego County .... 81 Trends In Agricultural Sales And Acreage Under Production ................... 83 Dollar Value Of Output And Employment By Agricultural Subsector ............. 83 Multiplier Effect By Agricultural Subsector .... 83 20 ... Ill Page 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 Percent Of Agricultural Sales To Local Economic Sectors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 84 Cumulative Economic Impact Of A 1,000 Job Gain In Wholesale And Retail Services And Non-Durable Manufacturing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 88 Cumulative Economic Impact Of A 1,000 Job Loss In Agricultural Services And Production Employment . 89 Key Economic Indicators . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 89 Indirect Employment Impacts . . . . . . . . . . . 90 Net Impact Residential Development . . . . . . . . . 92 Cumulative Personal income To The Region Residential Versus Agricultural Use . . . . . . . . . . . . . 93 Property Tax Savings Of Williamson Act (1969-78) - 96 Wi 1 1 i amson Act Contract Lands . . . . . . . . . . . 98 Property Tax Savings Of Williamson Act by Crop Category . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 99 Dollar Value Of Crop Categories (1977) . . . . . . . 100 Market Value Agricultural Land . . . . . . . . . . . 108 Ten Fiscal Impacts Of Financing Agricultural Land Via Acquisition 10 Years . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109 Minimum Lot Sizes (Pol icy 1-38) . . . . . . . . . . 11 1 Agricultural Use By Land Use Categories . . . . . . 112 iv LIST OF MAPS r' Map Number 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 Page July Mean Maximum Temperature ........... 7 January Mean Minimum Temperature .......... 7 Average Seasonal Precipitation ........... 8 San Diego County Areaclimates ........... 10 Good And Fair Agricultural Soils .......... 20 County Water Authority Boundaries ......... 24 Lands Within All Three Criteria (Climate. Soils. Water) ..................... 35 LANDS IN AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTION Pendleton-Deluz Subregion ............. 39 Fa1 1 brook Communi ty P1 an .............. 41 Bonsall ...................... 44 North County Metropol i tan Subregion ........ 47 San Dieguito Community Plan ............ 50 Pala-Pauma Subregion ................ 53 Valley Center Community Plan ............ 55 Otay Subregion ................... 57 Poway Communi ty Plan ................ 60 Ramona ....................... 62 Rainbow Community Plan ............... 65 Lakes ide Communi ty P1 an .............. 66 Valle de Oro Community Plan ............ 67 Crest-Dehesa .................... 68 V PART I INTRODUCTIOW INTRODUCTION PURPOSE During the past few years concern has been expressed at the National, State and local levels of government about the retention of agricultural lands for ! agricultural uses. This Basic Data Report for the Proposed Agriculture Element of the County of San Diego's General Pian wi 11 examine the status of the local agricultural industry and recommend actions intended to help retain agricul- .. tural land uses in the County. STUDY AREA With some major exceptions the study area encompasses all of San Diego County. Not included are the fourteen incorporated cities (IS%), State parks (18%), National parks (15%) or other federal lands (12%). (1) The 40% of the area under the County's land use jurisdiction contains the vast majority of land in, or capable of agricultural production. D I RECTI ON County staff's original direction to prepare an Agriculture Element is contained in Policies 2 and 3 of Chapter 6, "Soils", of the Conservation Element. Adopted for the General Plan which would not only designate "exclusive agricultural areas,'' but "analyze, improve and promote methods of preserving agriculture."(2) In June of 1977 the Board of Supervisors approved the Agriculture Element as a project in the Integrated Planning Office's (IPO) FY 1977-78 work program and budget. (3) In August of 1977 the Board directed IPO to accelerate the work on the Agriculture Element. The Board of Supervisors' concerns about agricultural preservation found parallel expression at both the State and National level. During fiscal year 1977-78 the State legislature saw reintroduction of two major bills designed to reinforce the existing Wi 11 iamson Act. Both SB 193 (ZENOVICH) and AB i900 (CALVO) contained language stating that the preservation of agricultural lands was of paramount interest to the welfare and economy of the State, that actions needed to be taken to "preserve" agricultural lands for agricultural uses and that it was a matter of public interest to discourage the premature conversion of agricultural lands. The intent of both bills was to place mandatory restrictions on both density and use in areas of agricultural production.(4) - in January, 1976, these policies directed IPO to prepare an Agriculture Element The passage of Proposition 13 effectively killed both bills in FY 1977-78 primar- ily because they both contained provisions to subvent local yovernments for lost property tax with revenues from the State surplus, Whether these or other bills intended to enforceably restrict agricultural areas will be passed in the future remains to be seen. Also in FY 1977-78, H.R. 5882 (JEFFORDS) was introduced into the U.S. Congress. That bill seeks to establish a national policy of retaining, protecting and improving agricultural lands. It is specificall aimed at reducing - the amount of land converted from agricultural to other uses.(5 1 2 ASSUblPT I ONS When the Board included the addition of an Agriculture Element in the IPO Work Program it was apparently in response to the widely-held belief that San Dieyo County's agricultural lands were being significantly diminished by urbanization. This belief can be broken down into the following component parts: " That important natural resources are being diminished; " That the local agricultural economy in the long run is being disrupted; " That the loss of agricultural land is resulting in higher food prices; " That our "open space" agricultural vistas are being destroyed; and " That the historically rural character of certain parts of the County is in danger of being lost. In responding to the Board's concerns, staff identified the following six major assumptions which have guided the effort on the Agriculture Element to date: 1. That the agricultural lands of San Diego County ought to be malntained at or near their current level. - 2. That agriculture in San Diego is or can be an economically viable enterprise. This assumption is borne out by the fact that despite increased land, water, labor and equipment costs and despite large increases in property taxes, farmers in San Diego have continued to Significantly increase their produc- tion value each year. 3. That the existing trends of urban development in San Diego County pose a direct threat to agricultural production in the County. This assumption is based on the fact that urban development and agriculture in San Diego County appear to have similar locational criteria and that urban development has a much higher economic return. When development and agriculture compete for the same land agriculture is almost certain to lose. 4. That the economic threat to agriculture posed by urban development can be affected by the County. The County may reduce the threat of development in agricultural areas by developing a growth strategy which limits "leapfrog development" and by restricting the density and uses on agricultural lands. The intended economic effect of these actions will be to reduce the speculative value of the agricultural land. 5. That some areas in San Oiego County are better suited for agriculture than other areas. - 3 Productive agriculture demands three basic physical criteria: soil, and climatic conditions conducive to the particular needs of a given crop, and sufficient water. A number of cultural criteria are also important. 6. That, in order to preserve agriculture in San Diego County, it will be necessary not only to identify those areas having the best chance for continued production but also to restrict the development of those areas SO that a viable agricultural economy can be maintained. A number of recent studies of the Williamson Act have shown that voluntary efforts to preserve agricultural lands have been, on the whole, unsuccessful in California and in San Diego County. (6 - a, b, c) If the agricultural lands of San Diego County are to be preserved, then some system of rnan- datory restrictions is necessary. RESOURCES In order to test assumptions, and to determine which areas of the County might contain the resources necessary for long range, commercial, production County staff divided the evaluation of the resources into two parts: Physical Resources and Cultural Resources. The component parts of each of the two basic types of resources were selected after reviewing comparable studies of other jurisdictions. Under the heading of Physical Resources such topics as soils, climate, and water will be analyzed. For those planning areas in the County which appear to possess the natural resources for production the Cultural Resources section will examine such things as the amount and type of production, increases or decreases in acreage since 1970, the price of water, the cost of land and what impacts the County's current plans may have on continued production. P 4 PART I I PHYSICAL RESOURCES 5 CHAPTER 1 CL I MATE San Diego County has a mild, equable climate with considerable variation between the coastal, mountain, and desert areas. In general the coastal area has a very small temperature range; temperature variations are greater in the mountains, and greatest in the desert. Rainfall is concentrated in the November to April season, with infrequent precipitation during the summer. Higher elevations receive the most moisture, with total amounts diminishing rapidly down the eastern slope of the mountains. Winds are generally light and variable in direction except for persistent westerly winds during summer afternoons along the coast. The strongest winds usually occur during the occasional migrant storms of winter that cross the area. Humidities remain moderate throughout the year except for quite low values found in the desert area on summer afternoons. The County generally has abundant sunshine. The weather of San Diego County, as in most of southern California, is profoundly influenced by the Pacific Ocean and its semi-permanent pressure systems that result in dry summers and wet winters. The moderating influence of the ocean is primarily felt along the coastal plain and in the coastal valleys. In the clear air of the mountains, daytime temperatures rise and nighttime temperatures fall further than corresponding values near the ocean while the range is even F greater in the desert area to the east. Winds are generally light, and near the coast they reflect the large scale cir- culation of the nearby ocean area. Inland, however, local terrain is often the dominant factor, and wind directions are likely to conform to the direction of the valleys and ridges. As in most mountainous areas, there is a tendency for wind to blow up the valleys during the day and down the hills and valleys at night. The average annual temperature is in the low 60's on the coastal plain and in the coastal valleys; drops into the middle 50's at higher elevations in the mountains; increases to values around 70" in the desert area at the eastern edge of the County. In January the mean minimum temperature is in the middle 40's along the immediate coast and in the middle 30's over the desert, but it drops to below 30" in the mountains. However, daytime temperatures are moderate even in January, the average maximum temperature for the month ranging through the 50's and low 60's over the County. Extreme lows have dropped to around freezing along the coast. In the mountain and desert areas extreme minimum readings have dropped into the teens and, in some locations, slightly belaw zero. 6 July maximum temperatures average in the 70's along the coast, increasing to around 90" in the mountains, and to more than 100" in the desert area. Extreme high temperature readings have exceeded 100" at all points within the County and have exceeded 120" at some desert points. Minimum readings in July normally drop to around 60" along the coast into the 60's in the desert, and into the 50" in the mountains. I i 7 .F- Temperature data are available from only a few selected locations, and some care should be used in interpolating these data into other areas. Local topographical influences are often responsible for marked changes in temperature within short distances. Most of the County experiences light rainfall, although some of the central mountain areas receive more than 30 inches per year. The average seasonal precipitation figure along the coast is 10 inches or slightly less. The amount increases with elevation as moist air is lifted over the mountains. Some report- ing points in the Laguna Mountains measure more than 35 inches per year; the Mount Palomar area receives 45 inches per year. Totals diminish rapidly with decreasing elevation on the eastern slopes of the mountains, with some desert stations report- ing less than five inches per year. .~ ~- 0 .- -la &ma@ #@##@MI PWlp)tO(lOn (inohd Annual totals vary over a wide range. One year in 20 will receive less than five inches along the coast and only 20 to 30 inches in the wettest parts of the mountain areas. With the same frequency, however, wet years produce in excess of 20 inches along the coast and more than 10 inches in the desert, with 50 to 70 inches at some mountain stations. r 8 TABLE 1 J P n A H J I 62.9 63.3 64.6 66.1 68.1 69.7 I1 66.3 66.7 60.4 70.0 72.7 74.4 66.3 66.0 68.0 70.7 74.2 76.6 I11 66.6 67.5 70.0 73.5 77.3 82.3 63.4 64.3 67.9 72.5 77.1 84.9 63.7 65.1 61.9 72.0 76.3 83.4 N 50.9 60.6 64.0 69.9 74.6 84.6 51.0 52.5 55.3 61.5 67.0 78.3 V 68.8 73.7 76.8 0S.6 91.7 100.6 pan MRxiraum Ppr Mean ninimum (OF1 I 45.0 46.1 40.2 51.6 54.7 57.8 E XI 41.5 42.3 44.5 48.7 52.2 55.4 40.0 41.9 44.0 48.6 52.6 56.0 111 38.1 40.1 42.5 47.0 50.6 53.9 33.7 36.2 39.4 44.3 40.6 51.8 37.0 38.1 39.4 42.3 46.4 49.5 IV 30.9 32.0 34.0 37.1 40.3 44.0 31.2 31.8 33.9 37.9 41.3 48.5 V 36.5 40.6 44.6 51.4 56.0 62.6 1 54.0 54.7 56.4 58.9 61.4 63.8 11 54.0 54.2 56.3 59.7 63.2 66.0 53.2 54.3 56.2 59.7 62.7 65.2 1x1 52.4 53.8 56.3 60.3 64.0 60.1 50.4 51.6 53.7 57.7 61.4 66.5 fv 44.9 46.2 49.0 53.5 57.5 64.7 Temperature 48.6 50.3 53.7 58.4 63.2 68.4 41.1 42.3 44.6 49.7 54.6 63.4 v 52.7 57.2 60.7 68.5 73.9 81.6 J A S 0 N D 73.3 82.5 79.1 09.8 93.11 91.7 92.4 85.1 106.0 74.6 82.8 80.2 89.0 91.0 Y3.4 05 .o 92 .4 104.3 74.3 71.6 68.9 65.2 82.3 77.2 73.8 69.2 80.5 76.8 74.0 69.1 88.9 81.6 76.0 70.0 91.0 01.5 73.4 61.0 09.1 81.4 73.5 67.0 00.0 70.0 68.5 61.8 00.9 70.0 60.4 54.0 100.8 90.5 77.3 70.4 61.4 62.6 60.2 55.7 49.8 46.6 59.5 60.4 57.9 53.1 46.2 43.2 59.6 60.3 57.6 51.8 44.1 41.4 50.9 58.7 54.7 47.1 39.0 35.2 50.1 58.7 56.5 50.1 42.4 39.5 55.0 55.9 52.1 46.9 41.4 30.0 52.6 51.9 40.4 41.7 35.2 32.0 56.2 55.9 51.1 43.8 36.2 33.1 70.3 69.4 63.6 54.2 42.9 37.4 67.4 68.6 67.3 63.6 59.4 55.9 71.0 71.7 70.2 65.3 60.0 56.2 69.4 70.3 69.1 64.3 59.1' 55.3 74.0 74.2 72.7 65.9 59.2 54.8 76.4 16.1 72.9 64.3 56.2 51.1 73.5 73.9 70.6 64.1 57.3 52.5 70.7 70.4 60.0 57.3 4R.6 43.5 72.4 72.2 68.6 60.2 51.8 47.0 88.2 86.9 82.2 72.4 60.1 53.9 "- TABLE 2 1 I1 11 I11 I11 I11 IV IV V - Higherr of Record )*an wxlpm ban Mean Hintmum Lovest of Record 32' DAYS AND NIQI"& Days between median dater Spring 50% probability data Fall 507. probability dat4 b.l I. n 28. DAYS AND DAZFg, Days between rdlan dates Spring 50% probability data Pall 50% probability Date pROBAeILlTY OF CCClJw 32' 24' 2 0. 16. 2 n* 107 69 61 29 53 365 # * 365 # * 50% 2 3% " " " 115 73 50 62 21 2 /14 3 00 12/11 3 65 # 42% 90% " " " 108 74 62 24 50 335 1/30 # 359 116 # 67X 641 " " " 114 78 63 48 17 355 1 I/ 24 3/13 3 14 2/3 12 / 14 loox 9 1% " " " 111 78 46 62 15 261 3/9 11/25 281 2/23 12/1 97% 92X " " " 114 61 77 45 17 .' 2 05 4/19 11/10 274 3/6 12 I5 lOOz 94% 88% 2 5% " 110 51 75 40 11 138 5/20 lO/jO 2 03 4/20 11/9 104, 100% lo(* 941 34, 10s 67 54 41 -1 162 5/11 10/20 4/28 158 10/3 I 00% 100% 1 00% 80% 63% Moan mnxhum. man. and aman mintmum temparaturar are average figurar datermined frar a11 rtationr within thr I-. All othrr Ciguran arm the mort extreme conditionr which can b. expectad. 121 . 87 70 52 15 2 85 2/21 11 123 308 2 I1 12 /6 100% 8 bX 5?% 14% " 9 , -- d 0 1. intensities of precipitation also vary with elevation. The heaviest intensities are found in the mountains, while the least intensity is recorded in the desert area. It is estimated that thunderstorms are experienced less than three days per year on the coast, while some of the mountain areas have thunderstorms on 15 days or more per year. Along the coast the relative humidity averages from 50 to 70 percent during the fall and winter months, and from 60 to 80 percent during the summer. Stations in the desert report 40 to 60 percent humidity during the winter, with noon readings dropping to 25 percent or lower during the summer. Night readings in the desert, however, remain near the 50 percent value. Humidities in the mountains are generally between the values on the coast and those on the desert. Wind records are limited to those along the coast. These show predominantly westerly winds, although there are times when north or northeast winds are significant. In general wind speeds are light to moderate; San Diego, for example, shows winds of less than eight miles per hour (mph) 64 percent of the time. Winter storms chat move inland from the Pacific Ocean are usually responsible for the strongest winds observed in the area. Extreme readings of 60 to 65 mph occur in moderately exposed areas about once in 50 years, and readings up to 80 mph may oc,:ur as often as once in 100 years along the immediate coast. At intlervals of three or four times per year, usually in the fall or winter, pressure conditions cause a fairly strong, gusty flow of air from the north or east. This air is usually quite dry and, at times, may be unseasonably warm. The circulation is often shallow and hence is responsive to local terrain. One area may receive 30 mph winds, while a neighboring locality a quarter mile away can be alGost calm. - The coastal area receives some 3,200 hours of sunshine per year or about 70 percent of the possible total. The amount increases inland to around 4,000 hours in the desert approximately 90 percent of possible. Winter storms are infrequent within the County, with the result that sunshine percentages are about the same during the summer as they are during the winter. Along the immediate coast sunshine percentages actually decrease slightly during the summer due to night- time and early morning cloudiness typical of most of the California coast.(7) 1 In considering climate from an agricultura the University of California has developed plant -- climate relationships in Californ is the dominant factor affecting plant dis specific kinds of plants can be grown. So the other hand, may determine where climat found. Climate's most important component perspective, Dr. M. H. Kimball of a climatic rating system based on a. His basic premise is that climate ribution. C1 imate determines where 1 factors and water availability, on cally suitable plants are actually in California is temperature (maxi- mum, minimum, and extremes) which affects the yield and quality of plant performance. Rainfall deficiencies can be offset by irrigation. The frost hazard, high temperature extremes, wind presence or absence, moisture reyinle and all other climate components have a bearing upon the distribution and seasonal behavior of plants. The presence and performance of insects and diseases are sinlilarly influenced, as are the we1 I-being of donlestic and wild an i ma 1 s . 11 From the above it is apparent that climate, either directly or indlrectly, deter- mines agricultural enterprises, location of urban areas, parks, industries, recreational activities, and in turn has a great impact upon human health and welfare. California has a wide variety of climates due to three main influences: First is the Pacific Ocean with its stable environment over the water surface, and the wind patterns which arise from pressure differences in the air mass. Because pressure differences exist and air mass movement is generally from west to east, moist air tends to move inland from the ocean. The distance it moves is determined by the intensity and duration of pressure differences, and by topography. Second is the sun as a source of energy. The sun's energy is absorbed and released slowly by the ocean. Hence the water becomes a stable modifier of climate. Land masses behave differently, however, in that they warm and cool quickly. Latitude reflects two components of sun energy. California extends from approxi- mately 32.5' to 42O North Latitude - a distance of nearly 700 miles. The effect of this range is evident in both summer and winter. At the onset of ''official" summer (June 21) the period of sunshine per day is nearly an hour longer at the Oregon line than at the border of Mexico. The converse is true during the latter along the southern border during both summer and winter, hence a warmer or hotter climate exists. P part of December. In addition the angle of incidence of sun energy is more direct - Third is the topography of the land surface. Because of the roughness of the land and the differential heating and release of heat energy by the land surface, air masses are differentially heated or cooled. Also land forms tend to channel air flow, or even impound it, which tends to further create different climates in different areas. These features -- the ocean, the sun's energy throughout the broad width of latitude, the soil surface, and the land masses in various shapes, altitudes, and orientation with respect to the coastline -- cause a great diversity of California climates. These diversities can be broadly grouped and defined, using the ocean, topography, and distance inland as starting criteria. On this basis five major "areaclimates" have been established for California. AREACLIMATES rc 1. MARITIME - The Maritime Areaclimate ln San Diego County occupies a long, narrow belt along the ocean. Although limited in width in places to a few hundred yards, it may at times penetrate inland five or six miles. The cliffs, mesas, and ridges which border the beaches usually rise rather abruptly to elevations of 400 to 500 feet or higher. This effectively confines most of the Maritime Areaclimate to a narrow shorelfne strip, but where canyons or valleys open onto the coastal plain, the Maritime influence is apparent further inland. 12 2. 3. 4. 5. COASTAL - The Coastal Areaclimate, 1 ike the Mari time, is continuous I 1-0111 north to south across the County. It 1 ies inland frotll the shoreline stril) which is dominated exclusively by the Maritime influence, and varies f'ronl approximately 10 to 30 miles in depth. Direct ocean influence diminishes with distance inland, and with elevation. Summer fog is a frequent modify- ing factor. Topographically the Coastal Areaclimate comprises an area of hills, mesas, and ridges extending from beaches and cliffs on the west to the seaward slopes of the low elevation mountains on the east. TRANSITIONAL - The Transitional Areaclimate occupies a series of valleys partially screened from maritime influences by low mountains to the west, and limited by the western extension of the Peninsular Range to the east. These valleys may be coastal in character for part of the day, or for a week or a month, and then be dominated for similar periods of time by continental air. This area, designated as the Transitional Areaclimate in the state-wide system, is referred to locally as the "Coastal Valley" section of the San Diego County. Topography includes valleys, foothills and rnountain ranges from 2,500 to 3,000 feet when parallel to in-flowing marine air. INTERIOR - Interior Areaclimates are defined as those dominated by conti- nental air at least 85 percent of the time. The upland area of San Diego County fits this description. This area, which is continuous north to south, is characterized by wide diurnal and seasonal temperature fluctuations in contrast to the other areaclimates, and the air is characteristically warm and dry in summer. Topographically, it consists of valleys and foothills, mountain valleys, and the seaward slopes of high mountains. - DESERT - A line of high peaks in the Peninsular Range, which creates the rain shadow to the east, marks the beginning of the Desert Areaclimate. This desert areaclimate (5) is dominated to a greater extent by continental air masses than is Interior Areaclimate (I). It is trcated separately due to its unique and distinctive characteristics, which include: high daytime summer temperatures with very low humidities; drying and occasional extreme winds; slight, variable rainfall (generally under five inches a year) which, from the standpoint of all but specialized plants and animals, is often very unevenly distributed. (8) AIR QUALITY Air pollution is a major environmental problem in San Dieyo County. The San Diego Air Basin has a high potential for trapping smog because of topography and climate. In 1976, San Diego County exceeded the federal oxidant standard of 0.08 parts per million on I70 days, on the worst day by 350 percent (0.29 parts per millicn). Health advisory levels were reached on 11 days. The air quality problem is a result of topography, climate and the emission of pollutants into the atmosphere. Frequent low inversions and an abundance of sunlight create a high potential for the production of photo chemical smog. This problem is peri- odically intensified by the transport of air pollutants into the County from the Los Angeles Air Basin. - Air Pollution Damage: An Unknown Poor air quality can significantly damage some crops. Kenneth F. Sims, Plant Pathologist with the U.S. Department of Agriculture, for the County of San D i ego, commen ted : "Pollutants could cause serious damage to the County's 228 million-a- year agricultural output. Crop damage, shifts to less desirable crops, and loss of the multimillion-dollar flower industry could be the effect to the basic agricultural industry should pollution levels rise. Although crop loss damage estimates and research have been minimal in the County to date, studies in ten other counties, including Los Angeles, Orange, and San Bernardino indicate an annual crop loss in excess of $55 million. These figures do not reflect the additional millions lost as a result of damage to urban, parkland, and native vegetation." Result of smog damage elsewhere is evidenced by the fact that many of the 55 new nurseries in San Diego County, a growing business that currently employs about 2,400 people, moved from Los Angeles and Orange counties because of the smog. If San Diego's air quality declines significantly, the nursery and many other agricultural pursuits may have to move or cut back. Studies in Riverside County demonstrated that smog reduced production as much as 50% in lemons; the loss of navel oranges was more than 60%. Orange and'lemon production in 1975 was worth over $25 million in San Diego County. The monetary impact of smog here is obvious. Since several hundred people are involved in growing and picking these crops, the impact on employment of changes in produc- tion, either increased due to cleaner air or reduced because of dirtier air, could be noticeable. - William Simmons, San Diego Air Pollution Control Officer, states that damage has been seen in flowers and a few other crops, and on trees in the Cleveland National Forest. "Damage should not be as great here as in Riverside and Los Angeles because our oxidant levels are lower," but he says it is safe to assume some damage has a1 ready been done. (9) Ox i dan t Trends San Diego County has two oxidant trends -- its own and imports from the South Coast Air Basin. San Diego's own smog apparently reaches highs of about .20 to .22 ppm oxidant and exceeds the Federal standard of 0.08 ppm on 47 percent of the days during the year. Imports come from the South Coast Air Basin only I5 to 25 days a year but create high readings of approximately 0.28 ppm oxidant. Emissions in San Diego are responsible for about 85 percent of the total pollu- tion episodes in the County. The number of days in which oxidant standards are exceeded increase eastward from the coast to the foothi 11s (up to 3,000 feet). The quantity of oxidant precursors -- RHC and NOx -- emitted into the air basin is highest in the San Diego metropolitan region. This region, however, experi- ences the lowest levels of oxidant pollution in the County. The daily sea breeze - 14 transports the primary pollutants emitted along the coast inland. Sunlight reacts with the primary pollutants in the atmosphere forming secondary pollutants such as oxidant. The oxidant then impacts areas downwind from the sources. The measured oxidant level therefore increases inland, so the average daily ambient air quality deteriorates from the coast inland to the foothills. The Alpine monitoring station regularly records the highest levels of oxidant in the County. Future Trends As the population living in San Diego County increases, air quality in the basin will proportionately decline unless stringent control measures are taken to limit the quantity of future emissions. As an Air Quality Maintenance Area, the San Diego region has formulated a program designed to control emissions and achieve Federal air quality standards by 1980. The plan -- The Regional Air Quality Strategy (RAQS) -- was formally accepted by both the CPO Board of Directors and the County Board of Supervisors in December, 1976. The RAYS is now being refined into a Regional Air Quality Maintenance Plan. As part of the work proyram for designing the RAQS, an extensive effort was undertaken to assess the magnitude of the air quality problem, to protect the amount of control of future emissions necessary to meet clean air standards, and to provide data for estimating the effectiveness of proposed control. One product of this work plan was a projection of "future trends'' in air quality for the San Diego Air Basin. - The "Future Trends" projection was based on the EPA approved Rol lback Model which assumes a 1 inear relationship between reactive hydrocarbon emissions (RHC) and oxidant formation. The model is simply a tool for scaling the projected regional concentration of oxidant up or down to reflect similar changes in gross emission rates. An integral part of the "Future Trends" projections was an inventory of present day reactive hydrocarbon emissions which catalogued the contribution of various source categories to total RHC emissions. Using the 1 inear Rollback Model and the initial RHC emissions inventory, future oxidant trends in the San Diego Air Basin were projected for the years 1972-2000. Possible future air quality ranges in the County were projected both with and without imports from the Los Angeles area. Two sets of variables were incorpor- ated in this projection: (I) Growth rates in San Diego County; and (2) smog transport. Projections of air quality were made using three possible growth trends: existing trends, trends in the Regional Transportation Plan, and energy shortage trends. Trends were projected for each growth level both with and without irnports from South Coast Air Basin. The range of air quality with the contributions from the South Coast Air Basin is probably the best guess of real future air quality since Los Angeles will continue to be a source area under certain meteorologic conditions. The most significant result of these projec- tions shows that even the most favorable forecast of air quality will not meet Federal standards by the year 2000. In fact, depending upon the activity level assumptions, somewhere between 1980 and 1985, the downward trend in air pollution begins to turn upward. (10) CHAPTER 2 so I LS Agriculture is one of the major land uses in the unincorporated areas of the County with between 77,000 and 117,500 acres in production in 1977.(11) ) Approxi- mately 75 percent of the 335 million dollars made in agriculture in San Diego last year was made in some form of crop production. (12) A major distinction between the County's crop and animal production is the relative importance of soil characteristics for crop production. In addition to certain climatic and water criteria the specialty crops, which are a mainstay to the County's agricultural industry, have a range of soil criteria which normally need to be met. There are a variety of methods currently used to rate agriculture soils. In California the two most commonly used systems are the Storie Index Rating System and the Soi 1 Conservation Service's (S.C.S.) Capability Groups. One of the reasons for their widespread use is that the State law relating to agricultural preservation (Williamson Act) uses in its definition of "prime" agricultural lands elements of both the Storie Index and the Capability Groups. Specifically the Williamson Act in defining the soils criteria for a "prime" designation uses a Storie rating of at least 80, on a 100 point scale, and an S.C.S. Class I or I I rating, out of VI I I classes.(l3) The Storie Index is a rating system which gives a numerical value indicating the relative suitability a soil group has for general agricultural practices. In this rating system four factors are evaluated separately on a percentage basis. The final rating is arrived at by multiplying the four factors, expressed as a percentage, times each other. To receive a rating of "prime" (80 or more on a 100 point scale) a given soil unit would have to receive a minimum rating of .95 for a1 1 four factors (.95 x .95 x .95 x .95 = .81). In fact if a given soil unit is rated perfect for any three factors and less than .80 in the fourth it cannot receive a "prime" rating (1.00 x 1 .OO x 1.00 x .79 = .79).(141 r- The first factor evaluates the relative quality of the soil profile. Soils that permit deep root penetration are rated at 100 percent, soils which for whatever reason do not permit root penetration are rated at less than 100 percent. The second factor rates the texture of the surface soi 1. Soi 1s which flll the range between l'moderately coarse" and "medium texture" receive a rating of 100 percent, coarser and finer soils are rated at less than 100 percent. The third factor rates the slope. Nearly level or slightly sloping soils are rated at 100 percent, anything more are rated less than 100 percent. Finally the fourth, so-called X factor evaluates any other condition which may affect the soil, such as acidity or alkal ini ty. (15) The Soil Conservation Service's Capability Groups are a three tiered rating system which evaluates the limitations of cultivated soils. In general, the groups contain mapping units arranged by the kind of limitation they pose to cultivation. The broadest segment of the Capability Group are the Capability Classes. The classes, numbered I-VIII, indicate progressively greater limita- tions and narrower choices for most kinds of agricultural use. To receive a "prime" rating a given soil unit needs to meet the criteria for either Class I or Class II. 7 16 Class I soils have "few" limitations, and Class I I soi Is have "moderate" I inli- tations. Classes I I I and IV have "severe" or "very severe'' 1 imitations which restrict the choice of plants, require special management practices or both. Classes V, VI and VI I are rated as having such severe limitations that they are generally only uses for range, woodland, wildlife habitat or recreation purposes. Class VI11 lands are those judged to be so limited that they can only be used for recreation, wildlife habitat, water supply, or aesthetic purposes.(l6) During the early phases of this report an attempt was made to use the soils criteria contained in the Williamson Act as a basis for describing those soils in the County which might best represent a natural resource. An evaluation of the 251 soil mapping ur;its mapped for the Soil Survey by the United States Department of Agriculture, Soil Conservation Service revealed that only 13 of the units met the criteria for a ''prime" designation under the Storie index (.80). An additional 23 soil mapping units met the S.C.S. "prime" criteria (Class I or I I). In terms of acreage, a total of 131,329 acres in the County satisfy one or both of the above "prime" criteria. This means that by using the Storie Index and the S.C.S. Capability Groups "prime" criteria, only six (6) percent of the soils in the County can be considered "prime."(17) Moreover these 131,329 acres are in scattered locations throughout the County. Typically composed of alluvium, the soils are generally located in valleys, many of which have already been developed for urban uses. The net effect of this distribution pattern is that there is considerably less than the 130,000+ acres available for agricultural production, and that those which are available are scattered in pockets all over the western half of the County. In comparing the location of these "prime" soils to the location of existing production, it was learned that some of the most productive lands in San Dieyo County are located on soils with ratings well below the prime ratings of Storie or the S.C.S. For example, a typical soil mapping unit found in the flower fields around Carlsbad is the unit MIC which has a Storie rating of 54 and an S.C.S. Class ill. In Paul Ecke's agricultural preserve, located in San Dieguito, a typical unit is CfC which has a Storie rating of 32 and an S.C.S. Class IV rating. Further south in the Rancho Otay area, a center for tomato growing in San Diego, a typical unit is DaD which has a Storie Index of 37 and an S.C.S. Class Ill rating. Up in Valley Center it is a preferred cultural practice to grow avocados on steep slopes. A typical soil mapping unit of that area is Fan2 which has a Storie rating of 48 and an S.C.S. Class IV rating. It should be noted that both the Storie Index and the S.C.S. Capability Groups were developed for application in areas most suited for large scale farnlirlg. These areas, the central valley of California and the plains of the Midwest, can be characterized by relatively deep soils and a laininlunl of clinlatic diI'C1~r- entiation. San Diego has the reverse situation. Most crop produclion is s111a1 I scale, intensive and very specialized. The soils of the County can generally be characterized by their shallowness, and the County has, as discussed in the previous chapter, five different climatic zones. 17 TABLE 3 ”” CRITERIA FOR AVOCADO SUITABILITY= Criteria Depth to impermeable rock or hardpan * SUOSO~! permeabiiity Subsoil or substratum msterial Not Rated Fair -I Less than 36 inches 36 to 60 inches Very siow, slow, or ately rapid, moderately slow Moderate, moder- rapid, or very rapid Clay B horizon, ite or alluvium hardpan, or hard Decomposed gran- rock Good More than 60 inches Moderate, moder- ately rapid, rapid, or very rapid Decomposed granite or alluvium a Preparrd by the Soil Conservatidn Service and accepnd by the San Diego County Planning Deparrmenr, 1971. b Dscomposed granite is not considered impermeable rock. Thus decomposed grsnits is not considered a depth limitation for avowdos. TABLE 4 CRITERIA FOR CITRUS SUITABILITY’ Criteria Good Fair Not Rated Soil rooting depth * More than 36 20 to 36 inches Less than 20 inches inches - ” Subsoil permeabi!ity Moderate, moder- Moderately slow Slow, very slow, or very rapid ately rapid, or rapid Slope 0 to 15 percent 15 to 30 percent More than 30 percent 6 Prepared by the Soil Conservat;on Service and accepted by rha San Dlego County b Dscomposd granite restr;:ts roots of cirrus trees. I Planning Department, 1971. 181 SOIL SURVEY -- PART Ill 18 TAeLE f CRITERIA FOR TRUCK CROP SUITABILITY# Not Rated 1 I Fair 1 t'!;!; 111;111 20 irlctlcs 70 to 36 itlctjtls Ci;~ycy, rocky, cob- Clay loarrr, loalrl, bly, stony, very gravelly, or rock sand, pr gravelly outcrops loamy coarse sand "_ .. Very slow Slow, moderately slow, moderate, or very rapid More than 9 percent 5 to 9 percent - - Mort! 111;111 36 itlclws Fine sardy loam, very fine smdy loam, sandy loam, loamy sand, or loamy fine sand Moderately rapid, or rapid - I t 0 to 5 percent a Prepared ~y rha Soil Cor:servation Service and arctyted 3f the San Diego County Planr~rq Deparrment, 1977. h Clays and cldy loarns art? preferred for celery because wnd 1s undesrrable m mature heads. Well matlaged ciays arc tarr for srr>wbrrries. I - "" - " _______~"""_ "_ TABLE G - ~ . . -. -. . . - " .. _". - . . .. "- I Ci?!TEl!lk FOR TOMATO SUITAl3lilTYJ i Cri?cr ia Soil depth Sur face layer tcxture - " " Very gravelly, Sandy loam, rocky, stony, gravelly fine I i loamy sdnd, sand or I sarrdy loam, or 1 "I 0 to i5 percent TABLE 7 C,RETIR"FOR F~~ER SUITRBILITV .- ! Criteria Good SO;I depth -." 10 to 20 inches Surface layer Clay, very gravelly, Loam, clay loam, Sandy lo3m, loamy tcxture rocky, Or stony or yrwelly sand, smd, coarse sandy lom1, fine sandv ioarn, very fine smdy loam, loamy fine sand, or loamy coarse sand "" L Slope I 3 Prepcrrd bi' rhe Soil Conservation Servicc. and acceprrd bv rhie Sari 3kgo Csumy " I Pmnq Depxtmenr, 1971. I 182 0 h, From the above, it becomes clear that if there is to be a meaningful analysis of the agricultural potential of soils in San Diego it will be necessary to use a rating system which takes into account the kinds of production which occur in the County. Fortunately the Soil Survey developed by the S.C.S. and the San Diego County Planning Department in June of 1975 contains just such a rating system in Chapter VI I (Interpretations for Farming and Ranching) of the "Soi 1 Interpretation Manual" (Part I I I of the Soil Survey). The rating system in the Soil Survey first selected five crops or crop categories (Avocado, Citrus, Truck Crops, Tomatoes, and Field Flowers) which represent the majority of lands under cultivation. Then, for each of these crop categories certain criteria were developed so that each soil mapping unit could be evaluated as "good", ''fair'1 or "not rated". The "not rated'' evaluatim meaning that the soil unit did not meet even the "fair" criteria. The tables on the preceediny page show what specific criteria were used for the ratings. The tables are from pages 181-182 of the "Soil Interpretation Manual". Once these criteria were identified they were then applied against the 251 soil mapping units in the County, and 123 of those satisfied at least the "fair" rating for at least one crop category. (18) Maps of the County were then pre- pared for each crop category and a1 1 of the soil mapping units which received a "good" or "fair" rating were colored in. Finally a set of maps were prepared showing all those soil mapping units which satisfied either a "good" or "fair" rating for any of the five principal crops. These maps have been used as the basis for determining which soils in San Diego County have some degree of potential for agricultural use. 4 As noted above, previous studies indicated that there was little relationship between agricultural production and the presence of "prime" soi 1s in San Dieyo County. There is, however, a very high incidence of agricultural use on soils rated "good" or "fair" in the Soi 1 Survey. Of the 24 community plan/subreyional areas, nine (Bonsall, Fallbrook, North County Metropolitan, Otay, Pala-Pauma, Rainbow, Ramona, San Dieguito, and Valley Center) contain the majority of the crop production occuring in this County. For these nine areas the average percentage of production occuring on "good" or Ilfair'I soils is 85 percent with the range going from a low of 66 percent in Rainbow to a high of 98 percent in Otay.(l9) The chart on the following page shows the total acreage, acreage rated good/fair, acreage in production, and production acreage on good/fair soils for each of the Community Plans and subregional areas. As in any rating system there are limitations to the kinds of interpretations that can be made. What the Soil Survey ratings do mean is that other considera- tions, such as climate and water aside, the soilsof a particular soi 1 unit exhibit the kinds of mechanical properties that wil 1 a1 low production to occur. 21 TABLE 8 GOOD/FA I R PRODUCTION TOTAL sot L PRODUCTION ON % ON PLANN I NG AREA ACREAGE ACREAGE ACREAGE GOOD/FAIR GOOD/FAIR Alpine Bonsal 1 Centra 1 Moun ta i ns Crest/Dehesa Desert Fa 11 brook Jamul/Dulzura Ju 1 ian Lakes i de Moun ta i n Emp i re North County Metro North Mountain 0 tay Pala-Pauma PendeltonDe Luz Poway Ra i n bow Ramona San D i egu i to Santee South Bay Sweetwater Val le de Oro Valley Center 70,848 19,200 69,120 22,400 35,520 113,280 47, IO4 168,320 57,600 78,720 20,480 27,520 9,920 81,920 63,360 12,352 4,480 6,848 22,400 53,120 33,920 38,960 13,450 10,370 15,680 28,416 22,656 1,696 23,550 126,240 23,040 27,552 4,090 15,136 3,470 32,768 22,180 8,650 3,580 3,770 10,080 42,500 700 7,829 297 38 1 (NOT RATED) 14,803 3,781 1,327 1,017 20,392 13,696 9,205 2,280 1,709 8,440 5,201 210 200 53 76 7 24,104 (NOT RATED) (NOT RATED) 2 , 592 696 6 , 963 175 36 1 I 2,078 2,761 S 1,001 16,316 13,460 8,135 1,325 1,137 7,968 4,171 22 4 200 43 692 22,514 2,249 9 9% 8 8% ;:: 81% 73% 0% 98% 80% 98% 88% 5 8% 86% 66% 94% 80% 93% 100% 81% 90% 93% During the preparation of the Soil Survey the Comprehensive Planning Organization (CPO) adopted policies relating to the preservation of agricultural soils. One policy states that lands to be preserved for agriculture should be selected on the basis of: the Soil Interpretations for Farming contained in the Soil Survey, on the overall agricultural productivity of the soil, on the specialty crop productivity of the soil, on the multiple-use and open space guidelines and on adopted urban development policies. Another policy states that among the soil interpretations available in the Soil Survey, the Crop Suitability ratings should be consulted and that the Crop Suitability ratings supercede both the Capability Group and Storie Index ratings insofar as the five principal crops (Row Crops, Tomatoes, Flowers, Citrus, and Avocados) are concerned. 22 CHAPTER 3 WATER BACKGROUND The Metropolitan Water District (MWD) is the Southern California wholesaler of water, supplying the regional wholesalers in San Diego, Riverside, Orange, Los Angeles and Ventura Counties. Formed by its charter members in 1928, the HWD was established to supply water for "...municipal and industrial uses and pur- poses." Although the District has supplied water for agricultural uses at a reduced rate since its inception, it considers such water to be "surplus" and a service which can be interrupted by the District at any time.(20) MWD purchases and stores its supply of Colorado River water at Parker Dam on the California-Arizona border. The water is subsequently pumped through a network of pipes and aqueducts to Lakes Skinner and Mathews in Riverside County. From there the water is pumped south to San Diego through the four pipelines constructed by the County Water Authority (CWA) since the end of World War I I. The County Water Authority (CWA) is the regional wholesaler of water. Formed in 1944, its primary function has been to provide the facilities for transportiny and storing water purchased from the MWD for its member agencies. The CWA - currently consists of 22 independent water districts and covers the western third of the County. The eastern two-thirds of the County have as yet not joined the CWA primarily because they have sufficient groundwater to meet their 1 imi ted local needs. (21) In this chapter the importance of water to agriculture will be analyzed in terms of its availability, cost, quality, use and reuse. AVAILABILITY The MWD policy for distributing water is based on the total assessed valuation of each district. The higher the assessed value, the higher the water entitlement. The CWA accounts for approximately 13 percent of the assessed value of the MWD, hence its legal entitlement is 13 percent of the supply, or approximately 71,500 acre feet (AF).(22) In practice, however, the CWA has consistently been able to import water far in excess of its legal entitlements. In 1974-75, for example, the CWA received 388,485 AF from MWD, or approxiIuatc1y 35 percent of the District enti tlcnwnt. (23) There are two basic wasons why the CWA can acquire so rrluch water. First, the MWD's leyal entitlclllent to Colorado Rivcr water is 550,000 AF but in 1975-76 the District imported 1,200,000 AF. (24) The MWD is able to exceed its legal entitlements because other agencies and states which have rights to the water have not as yet been able to claim their full share. This situation is expected to change by the mid 1980's principally as a result of the Central Arizona Project going on line. The second reason why the CWA is able to exceed its legal entitlement is that the Los Angeles Department of Water and Power, which is entitled to 25 percent of the MWD's supply, is only claiming six percent of their entitlement. The Department of Water and Power meets most of its current water needs with water from the Owens Val ley. (25) " 23 I The status of future water supplies for San Diego were recently analyzed by the County's Regional Growth Management Task Force. (26) Their analysis made five basic assumptions, then presented a "worst case" and a "best case" scenario. The assumptions made include the following: 1. Per capita water use wi 11 average 0.209 AF/year. 2. San Diego's 1995 population will be 2,444,588. 3. Agricultural water use will be 108,000 AF/year. 4. There will be no new significant sources of water. 5. The State Water Project will be able to meet its contractual obligations. In addition to the above assumptions both scenarios would restrict the MWD to its legal water entitlements. Under such a restriction the MWD's supply of Colorado River and State Water Project water would equal: 1376-85 2,092,374 AFIyear 1986-95 2,409,572 AF/year Worst Case If the County Water Authority were restricted to its 14 percent entitlement the annual yield would be: 1976-85 292,932 AF/year 1986-95 337,340 AF/year Best Case If the County Water Authority continued to receive 35 percent of the MWD's entitlement its annual yield would be: 1976-85 732,331 AF/year 1986-95 843,350 AF/yea r "Under best conditions, the region will experience full growth, and will have a supply equal to 138 percent of need in 1985 and 136 percent of need in 1995." Although it is unlikely that agricultural water use would remain constant at 108,000 AF per year in the "worst case" scenario, it is interesting to see what happens if agricultures share of the available water remains at its historic average of 26 percent. -. WORST CASE: FIXED PERCENTAGE OF WATER FOR AGRICULTURE Agricultural Percentage Reduction Total Water Supply Water Supply of Agricultural Water 1976 : 425,851 AF 26% = 108,000 AF 1985 : 292,932 AF 26% = 76,162 AF 1995 : 337,340 AF 26% = 87,708 AF 41% 23% It seems reasonable to assume that if water for agricultural purposes is cut by a significant percentage that there would be a similar cut in agricultural produc- tion. In 1977 the MWD instituted two policy changes which will have an effect on the availability of water for agricultural purposes in San Diego. First, on July 1, 1980 the minimum acreage standards will be changed so that in order to qualify for an "agricultural water rebate" (see below) a property Owner wi 11 have to have a minimum of five acres under cultivation instead of the current minimum standard of one acre. The second policy change limits the area eligible for the agri- cultural rebate to the land under the jurisdiction of the CWA and its member agencies as of August 19, 1976. Any lands subsequently added to the CWA will not be eligible for the discount. (27) - In summary, water availabi 1 ity through 1995 is 1 ikely to range somewhere between 74 percent-of the present need and 136 percent of the need in 1995. It should be reemphasized that there may be a problem with the assumption that agricultural water use will remain constant at around 108,000 AF per year. Historically, agriculture in San Diego has used approximately 30 percent of the imported water. If water avai labi 1 i ty trends toward the "worst case" projection this percentage figure is likely to decrease dramatically because of MWD policies which gives urban water uses a higher priority than agricultural uses. (28) COST In FY 58-59 the MWD charged the CWA $15 AF for Colorado River water. The current (FY 77-78) MWD charge for Colorado River water is $67 per acre foot, an increase of 346 percent in 21 years.(29) After adjusting for inflation this rise in price works out to an annual increase of 7.77 percent. The average, annual, adjusted rate of inflation for the Consumer Price Index since FY 58-59 has been 3.85 percent. (30) The HWD began delivery of State Water Project water to the CWA in June of 1978. Because the State water does not meet the State's blological standards it requires treatment prior to being pumped into San Diego.(31) This treatment increases MWD's selling price by $17 AF, bringing the delivery cost of State Project water for the CWA to $86 AF. (32) The MWD has offered a discount price or rebate for agricultural water use for a number of years. From the MWD's perspective a major reason for the rebate has been to ensure optimal use of their water delivery systems.(33) 26 The local water districts, using standards developed by ElWD, report to the CWA detailing the amount of water used for agricultural purposes. The CWA then reports these figures to the MWD which rebates back to the CWA and the districts a sum of money based on a rebate figure of $34/acre foot. In FY 58-59 the rebate was $3 or 18 percent off of the MWD/CWA charge of $17 per acre goot. In FY 77-78 the $34/acre foot rebate amounted to 49 percent off of the MWD/CWA charge of $69 per acre foot. (34) The MWD has conducted a number of studies dealing with projected water costs. The initial study completed in 1974, and updated annually since then, made a number of assumptions in analyzing their projected 1995 rate structures. Three of their basic assumptions are listed below: 1. Increased energy costs will significantly increase the cost of all imported water. 2. Everyone within the District's service area benefits either directly or indirectly from imported water. 3. Whatever the future rates of imported water turn out to be, they should not be less than the out-of-pocket costs incurred in delivering the water.(35) The two variables which will most directly impact the cost of water are the source of the water and the energy costs of delivery. Other less direct costs could include the bonding capability of the State Water Project, the level of indebtedness of the MWD, CWA, and the individual districts as well as any future federal regulatory impacts. The MWD generally announces water price increases two years in advance. The schedules published to date indicate that the current rate of $67/AF for untreated water wil 1 be increased by $7/AF next year bringing the total to $74/AF. (361 The base water rate is currently anticipated to continue to increase at the rate of $7/AF per year through 1987. (37) This rate increase is being undertaken to cover the anticipated rise in the cost of electricity. The contract for power generation held by the MWD has a current rate of three mills per kilowatt-hour through 1983. Estimates from the State Department of Water Resources indicate a rise in costs to as much as 25 mills per kilowatt-hour, a 733 percent increase in energy costs. (38) Although the MWD has considered a change in formula, and even the total elimina- tion of the agricultural water rebate, it appears at this time that the rebate will continue in its present form.(39) In the "1978 Water Pricing Study" thc MWD estimated the cost or water for agricultural purposes to be: 1976-77 $ 30 1986-87 $ 80 166% increase 1999-2000 $145 383% increase 190-84 $ 70 133% increase The County Water Authority adds a surcharge to the MWD's price in order to cover the Authority's costs of operation and maintenance. The costs of capital projects are covered by the Sale of General Obligation bonds and tax revenues, which for the last few years has been set at the rate of 11 cents per $100 of assessed valuation. (40) The surcharge rate the Authority adds onto the MWD price has ranged between a low of $1.25/AF to a high of $2.50/AF.(41) Indications are that an increase to as much as $3/AF may occur in the next few years. (42) The twenty-two local water districts that receive water from the CWA purchased it at the rate of $69 per acre foot ($67 MWD + $2 CWA surcharge) in FY 1977-78. They in turn add on a surcharge to cover the costs of their maintenance and operation. These costs vary considerably throughout the County ranging from an additional 62 percent to an additional 398 percent for domestic water. The range for agricultural water is from a low of an additional 13 percent to a high of an additional 347 percent. TABLE 9 $ % % $ DOMESTIC INCREASE $ INCREASE MWD/CWA RATE OVER BASE AGRICULTURAL OVER BASE WATER D I STR I CT BASE RATE ACRE FT. RATE RATE/ACRE FT. RATE fl San Marcos Vista Car 1 sbad Del Mar De Luz Heights Escond ido Fa 1 1 brook He1 ix National City/So. Oceans i de Olivenhain 0 tay Pad re Poway Ra i n bow Ramona R i ncon San Diego San Dieguito Santa Fe Val ley Center Yu ima Ba Y 69 150 131 144 192 135 133 174 135 170 296 257 166 337 126 344 112 169 174 135 152 182 AVERAGE 117 111 60 89 83 20 108 96 39 178 158 128 95 113 63 92 99 43 152 166 140 95 118 71 1 46 136 97 328 157 127 272 179 159 1 40 132 91 388 135 95 82 91 31 398 309 3 47 62 78 13 144 169 144 152 122 76 95 118 71 120 118 71 163 150 117 (same as C i ty of San D i ego) 181 +162% - 28 ' On the average in FY 1976-77 local water districts sold domestic water for $181/AF, an increase of 162% over the MWD/CWA base rate. Water for agricultural purposes was sold by the districts for an average of S135/AF, an increase of 95 percent over the base rate. The ability to forecast the costs of water past the next two or three years is frought with difficulty. There are literally dozens of events which could affect the price of water in Southern California. If the base agricultural rate for water increases from around $30/AF to $70/AF in 1983-84 as forecast by the MWD; and if the relationship between the districts average selling price and the MWD/CWA base rate remains constant, the average district selling price of agri- cultural water in 1983-84 should be around $212 per acre foot, an increase of 57 percent . WATER QUALITY The quality of the water used for irrigation has an obvious and important impact on the qual ity and quantity of agricultural production. The quality of the water imported into San Diego from the Colorado River is relatively high in the amount of total disolved solids (TDS) averaging around 760 parts per million. The Colorado River water satisfies the Federal minimum standard of 1,000 ppm and is within the maximum standards developed for the principal crops grown in San Diego. Generally speaking, Colorado River water can be used on most of the crops grown in San Diego with little or no difficulty. TABLE 10 - TDS mg/l -5000- COMMON BERMUDA GRASS TDS TOLERANCE PERENNIAL RYE TDS TOLERANCE LIMIT TRUCK CROP TDS TOLERANCE LIMIT TOLERANT ORNAMENTAL PLANT AND CITRUS FRUIT TDS LIMIT COLORADO RIVER WATER BLENDED Cnl.ORADO RIVER AND ~~~ ~ ~ STATE PROJECT WATER CALIFORNIA STATE PROJECT WATER ~~ -3 000- -2500- -2000- - 1 500- - 1000- - 540- TALL FESCUE TDS TOLERANCE LlMl T PERMISSIBLE. BY STATE FOR TEMPORARY POTABLE SUPPLY PERMISSIBLE BY STATE FOR PERMANENT POTABLE SUPPLY WHERE E10 OTHER SOURCES ARE AVAILABLE AVOCADO TDS TOLERANCE LIMIT RECOMMENDED CRITERIA FOR POTABLE PUBLIC WATER SUPPLY -. 0 29 ,P Avocados, however, are fairly sensitive to salts and the current sodium absorb- tion ration of Colorado River water is just about as high as most avocado plantings can tolerate. As discussed on the previous page, the sources for imported water in San Diego will be changing from a sole reliance on the Colorado to a blend of Colorado and State Project water. Eventually a 50-50 blend will be reached which will produce a standard rating of around 540 ppm.. When this occurs the quality and quantity of the local agricultural produce wi 11 increase, although at this point no'one appears to know to what degree. icultural water use varies cons lity, method of application, so lower the permeability rate of water requirements. ,. iderably depending upon crop type, water il conditions and climate. Generally speaking the soil and the milder the climate, the lower Estimates have been made by the County Farm Advisor showing the annual water needs, per acre, for individual crops. The figures listed below are averages based on the use of furrow or sprinkler application techniques and other local irrigation practices. TABLE 11 ~~~ ~ ~~ ~ ~~ WATER APPLICATION IN CROP ACRE FEET/ACRE/YEAR Strawberries 6 Toma toes 2-4 Other Row Crops 2-4 Citrus 1 -5-3 Avocados 3-4 Nurseries/Greenhouse 3-4 . (43) The County's Regional Growth Management program recently computed estimates of water use by residential categories. Approximately three quarters of the water used for agricultural purposes is used to irrigate avocados and citrus orchards which on the average have a combined water usage of around 2.8 acre feet/acre/ year. Overall most residential classifications are comparable in their water usage to most of the agricultural water use. The highest consumer of agricul- tural water is strawberries (6 AF/acre/year) but this can be discounted since the average annual planting seldom exceeds 700 acres Countywide. 30 TABLE 12 ACRE-FEET PER YEAR WATER USE DU/AC DOMEST I C IRRIGATION TOTAL 43 29 14.5 8 7.3 5.8 4.4 4 2 1 8.10 5.47 2.73 1.50 1.37 1.09 .83 76 .38 .I9 .21 .3 1 .61 1.11 1.28 1.66 2.00 2.10 2.60 2.85 8.3 1 5.78 3.34 2.61 2.65 2.75 2.83 2.86 2.38 3.04 REUSE The reuse of water for agricultural purposes has been an important part of the two major water reuse studies conducted locally. The Comprehensive Planning Organization (CPO) in its "208" study and the joint City-County "San Diego Water Reuse Study'' looked in considerable detail into the potential for the agricul- tural applications of recycled water. In the 208 study, wastewater reclamation and reuse were identified as key elements of the areawide water quality management plan. This study estimated the potential market for agricultural uses of reclaimed water at around 322,000 acre feet over the next eighteen years.(45) This would average out to 17,888 acre feet per year or about 16 percent of the current agricultural water use. After identifying the potential market, specific project alternatives were examined. Out of an initial 118 reclamation alternatives, 46 underwent a detailed evaluation. On the basis of that evaluation 28 reclamation projects have been recommended for implementation by 1988. As much as 70 percent of the 91,852 acre feet targeted for reclamation in these projects could be used for agricultural purposes. (46) A major s the stand agency ha ticking point in making reclaimed water available for agriculture are ards developed by the Regional Water Quality Control Board. This State IS been fairly rigid in its use of a standard divisor or "one-third rule". Basically this standard requires that any reclaimed water used for agricultural purposes may not on a volume basis contain a level of more than one-third of the dissolved solids contained in the groundwater basin. Typically this would require reclaimed water to have not more than 300-350 parts per mi 1 lion (ppm) for ayri- cultural use. This standard appears to be somewhat excessive in that the Colorado iego contain on the Board together appear le approach in attenlpt- River watcr currently being used to irrigate crops in San D averayc 700 pp111. CPO and the State Water Resources Control to have convi nccd the Regional Board to adopt a more flex i b ing to meet the water quality objectives of the plan. (47) 31 The other major concern regarding the use of reclaimed water for agriculture is the ultimate cost to the consumer. From the outset of the CPO study it was apparent that the traditional methods of funding water projects would not be capable of providing the necessary funds that these kinds of projects would need. The resultant funding strategy has as its hypothesis the belief that the reclama- tion of waste water can legitimately be considered an activity with beneficial borne regionwide impacts, and that the costs of financing such projects should be by the largest possible segment of the population. From this a two-pronged strategy of subsidization resulted. First the CPO or other appropriate reg body will secure a grant under the Federal Clean Water Grant program. Such grant will fund 87.5 percent of the capital costs. It may be possible that balance of the capital costs will be covered by an additional regional subs Secondly, partial subsidization of operations and maintenance costs may be through surcharges on the imported water supply. The CPO study has projected tentative costs for reclaimed water using three different funding scenarios: a. That the capital costs would be unsubsidized. i ona 1 a the idy. ra i sed b. That 87.5 percent of the capital costs would be subsidized by a Federal Clean Water Grant. c. That all capital costs will be subsidized through a combination of '. Federal and regional subsidies. (48) Within each of these three funding scenarios the costs of reclaimed water are broken down further depending on whether the water is reclaimed to either "design" or "regulatory" criteria. The design criteria permits a minimum level of treat- ment prior to application, the regulatory criteria requires that the wastewater be fully treated before use. The final cost estimates take one more factor into account. Because of problems relating to market and facilities location, the final figures on the cost of reclaimed water divides the County into two planning areas: the Santa Margarita-San Luis Rey Hydrological Units (SM/SL) and the Western San Diego County Planning Area (WSD) . Using the above scenarios as a guide, CPO has projected the following tentative costs for reclaimed water. I. UNSUBS I D I ZED Design Criteria SM/SL: $88-330 per acre foot WSD: $40-1,252 per acre foot Reg u latory Criteria SM/SL: $451-798 per acre foot WSD: $lO5-l,552 per acre foot 11. SUBSIDIZED SM/SL “ Des i yn : $ 35-225 per acre foot Regulatory: $235-520 per acre foot WSD -- Des i gn : $ 24-537 per acre foot Regulatory: $ 55-830 per acre foot Clean Water Grant (87.5 percent plus), Other Regional Subsidy (12.5 percent) SH/SL ” Des i gn : $ 27-210 per acre foot Regulatory: $235-520 per acre foot WSD -- Des i gn : $ 22-830 per acre foot Regulatory: $ 42-1,072 per acre foot(49) The joint City-County Water Reuse Study has as its primary function the implemen- tation of as many of the water reclamation projects identified in the 208 report as possible. Phase I of that study, completed on August 1, 1978, has analyzed in detail the costs associated with the implementation of the 20 reclamation projects scheduled for the next five years. 33 SUMMARY OF PART I I This section of the Basic Data Report examined the three basic physical resources needed for agricultural production: climate, soils, and water. Generally speaking, all three tend to restrict commercial agriculture to the western two-fifths of the County. From a climatic standpoint, the climate is a positive production factor in the maritime and coastal area climates which make up the western one-fifth of the County. The transitional areaclimate located directly east of the coastal areaclimate is essentially a neutral production factor. These three area- climates, which together make up the western two-fifths of the County, contain the basic climatic resources necessary for long-range commercial production. The soils resources necessary for commercial agricultural production in San Diego County are for the most part restricted to the western half of the County. Although metropolitan San Diego developed on land which does not satisfy the "good or fair" criteria of the Soil Survey, many other communities in the County were founded on, .and continue to expand on, "good and fair" agri- cultural soi 1s. Examples of these communities include Lemon Grove, La Mesa; El Cajon, Otay, Lakeside, Poway, Ramona, Escondido, the beach communities in San Dieguito, San Marcos, Carlsbad, Oceanside, Vista, Fallbrook, and Valley Center. Essentially there are two sets of soil criteria needed in San Diego. Row crop production requires relatively flat land, while orchards can be located on land with slope characteristics ranging from slightly rolling to very steep. The undeveloped soil resources of San Diego best suited for long- range production are for the most part situated in the northwestern quadrant of the County. The eastern quadrants are deficient in soil quality and the southwestern quadrant, except for Rancho Otay and Otay Mesa, is either essentially all urbanized or deficient in quality. " The availability of water is the third physical resource. eecause the major of the County's agriculture depends on imported water and because the M.W.D. has restricted agricultural water hookups to lands within the C.W.A. boundar as of August, 1977, commercial agriculture in San Diego is effectively restr to the western third of the County. The colored areas on the following map illustrate those areas of the County within the Maritime, Coastal, or Transitional areaclimate; within the bound- aries of the County Water Authority; and have soils rated "good or fair" according to the Soi 1 s Survey. i ty i es i c ted 34 . PART I I I CULTURAL RESOURCES CHAPTER 1 SUBREG I ONAL AREAS In Part II, "Physical Resources," the twenty-four subregional areas which make up the unincorporated part of San Diego County were examined to see which of them contained the combination of natural resources (soil, climate, and water) necessary for agricultural production. Of the twenty-four areas, fourteen were found to contain significant quantities of land meeting the soil, climate, and water criteria examined in the previous section. The fourteen planning areas included Pendleton-DeLuz, Fallbrook, Bonsall, North County Hetropol itan, San Dieguito, Pala-Pauma, Val ley Center, Otay, Poway, Ramona, Rainbow, Lakeside, Crest-Dehesa, and Valle de Oro. In this section, each of the above areas will be analyzed. The table on the following page provides a summary of the information used in the analyses. A. PENDLETON-DELUZ SUBREGION Production The Pendleton-DeLuz Subregional area is located in the extreme northwest corner within the Cleveland National Forest or military reservations. The area around DeLuz (14,500 acres) is the only part of the 163,700-acre Subregion which is in private ownership. About 15 percent (2,280 acres) of the land in private owner- ship is in agricultural use. This subregional area contains about 2 percent of the County's agricultural acreage, and the production consists principally of vegetables, citrus, avocados, and nurseries. Orchards account for about 60 percent of the Subregion's production acreage, while nurseries and row crops make up the balance. Some additional row crop production takes place at both San Onofrc and Stuart Mesa on land leased from the Marine Corps. All of the orchard production is located in the DeLuz area of the Subregion. ,_ of San Diego County. The majority of the area is in public ownership, either Orchard production has increased by 420 acres (44%) and the "other" crop pro- duction category has increased by 155 acres (22%) since 1973. Field observations in the late summer of 1978 indicate that even more orchard acreage has been recently planted. Parce 1 S i ze The 14,500 acres in p approximately 522 par of those 522 parcels lrivate ownership in this subregional area are divided into ,eels, for an average parcel size of 27.8 acres. Ninety-six (18%) are engaged in some form of crop product ion, and these agricultural parcels have an average size of 13.3 acres. Except for Otay Mesa, 1 size is smaller for the 1s. this is the agricultura only area examined, where the average parce 1 parcels than for the nonagricultural parce 37 TABLE 13 I PENDELTON-DELUZJ 14.551 J 2.280 I FALLBROOK 1 30609- I EONSALL 17.331 I 7.829 N. COUNTY METRO 69.801 20.392' I SAN DlEGUlTO 54.842 PALAPAUMA 36.787 5.201 9.205 24.1 04 ~ OTAY ~ WWAY RAMONA RAINBOW LAKESIDE CREST-DEHESA VALLEY DE OR0 - ' IUCLL:D)ES fkGRlCil~ TL 72.041 8.720 I I 431 ~132 30% CURRENT I (POMWD; I - 25 i S 5,114 5 855 13.222 - 11% id, 11 - Tg2 g:Lyc 3 132 (POMWD) - 2% 10'aCURRENT 5157 (OMVID) + 16% + 16% 58% 29% 0.8 19.4 2157 (OMWD) 59b5:LtiE' , %132(WMWD) -- 2% I b. 1977 Dep: of Water Resources land use study C. 1977 Dept of Land Use and Environmwta! Rq d. 1978 (Somrnerl Field check dation (LUER) land use information system Percent- (Increaselbecreaei in ProbcDion 19W 1978: Compiled by I.P.O. Source information in- cluded: a. 1970 Low altitude color imagery b. 1973 Low altitude color imagery in wear +ere percentage of Production Acreage by Land UY Category: Compiled by l.P.O dverlayr snowing ayirulflira! production were plxed sn 130 DI maps showing land use dtsignationr. Average Parcel SizelAverage Agricultural Pard Size; lnformatton source APIS. Total number of acres dwided by number of parcels. Text includes Swi a half acre in size. tional information i.e.. number of parcels less than by I.P.O. Estimates the percentage of the er.:;re plan Regicnal Growth Management Designatiom Compiled area in "Urban: 'Nonurban'. and 'Other'categoria Agricultunl Water Rate; Compiled by I.P.O. Data coilected from individual districts for FY 7879. Aswised Market Value; Information reurce MIS. &de t:np;overnents or personal proper~vi by the Diveded the market value of the land (dxs not in- plan area Sinm information in the Asssor'S fib numk of ares for each land use caiegory in each nn a base date of March 1, 1977, and since the in- ilztion raze on !and in San Diego un be as ha .I q3rkel vaiili. They do, however. reflecl the relative 20 percenr a year. these rates do nor reflect current irir)c 1: cvar. v-ir compared to another. 1970 imagery not available 4 PENDLETON - DELUZ SUBREGION 39 Water and Land Costs The Pendleton-DeLuz Subregional area has water service supplied by two separate agencies. The military reservations have developed their own water supply system and do not receive regular supplies from either the C.W.A. or the M.W.D. The area around DeLuz has water service provided by the DeLuz Heights Municipal Water District. The agricultural water rate in this district is $158 per acre foot (19781, which is about 13 percent higher than the County average of $135 per acre foot. Agricultural land in the DeLuz area costs about 20 percent less per acre than the County-wide average for agricultural lands. According to the Assessor's Office the average cost per acre for the DeLuz area is $1,390. Non-irrigated land costs about $1,100 per acre while irrigated agricultural parcels cost about $2,900 per acre. Land Use Designations The DeLuz area has an "Estate" designation on the Regional Land Use Element Map. Essentially this means that the area is not within those areas of the County which will be requiring urban levels of service. The underlying subregional land use designation for DeLuz is "Multiple Rural Use." This land use designation allows minimum lot sizes of 4, 8, 20, or 40 acres, depending upon slope and water avail- ability. Virtually all of the land in DeLuz is in excess of 25 percent slope, and thus the mimimum parcel sizes will be 8 acres for parcels between 25-50 percent slope and 20 acres for parcels over 50 percent slope. One hundred percent of the - production in DeLuz takes place on lands with a "non-urban" land use designation. Summary The Pendleton-DeLuz Subregion appears to satisfy all of the physical and cultural criteria required for long-range commercial production. There has been a 44 percent increase in production acreage over the last eight years, and 15 percent of the land in private ownership is in production. All of the production occurs on land with a non-urban land use designation, and the entire area is designated "estate" i.e., non-urban, in the Growth Management program. The average parcel size for land in production is 13 acres. Although water costs are 17 percent above the County average, land costs for irrigated parcels are about 20 percent' below the County average. Because of the above factors and because of the geo- graphic location of the area, existing land use designations and controls will probably be adequate to support the continued long-range, commercial agricultural land uses in the area. B. FALLBROOK Product ion The Fallbrook Community Plan area is located in the northwest corner of San Diego County, directly east of the Pendleton-DeLuz Subregional area. There are no significant federal or state land holdings. About 48 percent (14,903 acres) of the plan area is engaged in some form of agricultural production. Except for the northcastern corner, which is vacant land, agricultural production is - 40 I ,- LANDS IN AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTION . . . .. FALL6ROOK 4 community Plan 41 L located throughout the plan area. Eighty-two percent of the production acreage is planted in orchards with the balance in irrigated row crops or nurseries. The Fallbrook Community Plan area accounts for about 12 percent of the County's agri- cultural acreage. I In 1973 Fallbrook had approximately 10,500 acres in orchards. In I978 the acreage in orchards had increased 15 percent to 12,254 acres. Actually, the percentage of newly-planted acreage is considerably higher than these figures indicate because approximately 1,000 of the 1973 acreage has been taken out of production. Parcel Size The Fallbrook area has approximately 8,000 lots distributed over its 30,809 acres, yielding an average parcel size of 3.8 acres. Of the 7,985 parcels, 11 percent, or 939 parcels, is in agricultural production. The average size of the agricultural parcels is 14.5 acres. Most of the smaller parcels are located in and around the town center. There are six other locations in the plan area where there are con- centrations of parcels which have been split down into relatively small urban-type lots. Water and Land Costs The Fallbrook Public Utility District and the Rainbow Municipal Water District together provide water to the Fallbrook area. The F.P.U.D. agricultural water rate is $99 per acre foot, which is a 43 percent increase over the district's - cost. The R.M.W.D. agricultural water rate is $91 per acre foot, which is a 31 percent increase over the district's cost. Fallbrook's and Rainbow's agri- cultural water rates are 33 percent and 27 percent, respectively, below the County average for agricultural water. Agricultural land in the Fa1 lbrook Community Plan area costs about 56 percent more per acre than the County average for agricultural lands. According to the County Assessor's records the average cost per acre in Fallbrook is $8,580. Non-irrigated land costs about $1,840 per acre, and irrigated land costs about $5,680 per acre. Land Use Designations The Fallbrook town center, approximately 9 percent y iven a "current urban'' des ignat ion by the Regiona relatively high densities in the future. The rest designation which will permit new lots to be no sm depending upon slope. The community plan land use part "Estate Residential'' or "Multiple Rural Use," 2 or 4 acres and 4. 8, or 20 acres, respectively. of the Plan area, has been 1 Land Use Element, allowing a1 ler than two or four acres, of the plan area has an "estate" designations are for the most allowing minimum lot sizes of Approximately 60 percent of the plan area has jess than a 25 percent slope,.which is the criteria for the 2 to 4 acre minimum lots. 42 ,F For the balance of the plan area it appears that commerc appears to be a viable land use in the future because of ial agr the fo icul tural production 1 lowing factors: " 48% of the area in production, " 40% increase in orchard acreage since 1970, " 85% of the area in non-urban land use categories, " an average agricultural parcel size of 14.5 acres, and " agricultural water rates about 30 percent lower than County average. The single most important factor which appears to be working against long range production is the cost of land. In 1978 the average cost of irrigated land was 56 percent higher than the County average on a per-acre basis. Slgnificantly, the vast majority of production in Fallbrook is in avocado orchards, which have the best chance of returning a net capital gain on small parcels. Because of the above factors, and because of the tremendous amount of lot-splitting in the Fallbrook area, new land use controls will probably be necessary to help keep the orchards in Fallbrook engaged in commercial production. These additional land use controls are examined in some detail in Part V. r Summa r y Except for the extremely high cost of land, most of the Fallbrook plan area appears to meet both the physical and cultural criteria for long-range, com- mercial production. The town center, as delineated on thhe Regional Land Use Element map, will probably not be able to continue any significant commercial production because of the smaller parcel sizes and the pressures of urban devel- opmen t . C. BONSALL P roduc t ion The Bonsall Community Plan area is located in the northwest quadrant of San Diego County, directly south of the Fallbrook Community Plan area. WIthin the 17,300 acres which make up the plan area there are no signiflcant federal or state landholdings. Approximately 7,800 acres (45%) In Bonsall are in some form of crop production with an estimated 6,400 acres planted with orchards. The growth of orchard production in North County has been fairly dramatic in this subregional area where there were only 180 acres planted in 1970. Orchard production in this area is in large clusters located throughout the plan area. 43 44 Parcel S i ze The average overall size of the i,745 parcels in Bonsall is 9.9 acres. One hundred fifty two of, those parcels were, ?t last report, less than half an acre. Of the 1,745 parcels, 498 (28%) are cle ified as being engaged in some form of crop production. The average parcel 0. the 7,800 acres in production is about 18.6 acres. Except for the San Luis Key Downs development the pattern of parcel size shows a relatively even distribution throughout the plan area. Water and Land Costs The Bonsall Community Plan area has water service provided by the Rainbow Municipal Water District. The agricultural water rate charged by the R.M.W.D. is $91 per acre foot which is 32 percent less than the average charged by the local districts. Land values in Bonsall tend to be slightly above the County average. On the average, land in Bonsall costs about $4,658 per acre. Non-irrigated land has a market value of around $2,940 per acre while irrigated land is worth about $4,069 per acre, about 10 percent above the County average. Land Use Designations Production in the Bonsall area occurs for the most part on land with non-urban land use classifications. Virtually the entire plan area has an "Estate" designa- two and forty acres, depending upon slope and water availability. For the approximately two-thirds of the plan area which has slopes over 25 percent the minimum parcel size will be eight acres. - tion on the Regional Land Use Element map, allowing minimum lot sizes of between The Bonsall Community Plan area appears to satisfy the physical and cultural criteria for long-range commercial production because of the following factors: " 45% of the area in production, " 3500% increase in orchard acreage since 1970, " 100% of the area in non-urban planning categories, " average agricultural parcel size - 18.6 acres, " agricultural water rate 32% lower than County average, and " irrigated land costs about 10% above County average. 45 Although lot split activity over the past several years appears to have been almost as heavy as in Fallbrook, the slope criteria in the tieneral Plan will keep about 60 percent of the plan area with an eight-acre minimum parcel size. For the type of production which could, and does occur, in Bonsall the current minimum lot size is adequate. D. NORTH COUNTY METROPOLITAN SUBREGION Production The North County Metropolitan Subregion is a large subregional area in northwest San Diego. Because there are five incorporated cities in the subregion, the County's land use authority is scattered over a wide area. There are no significant Federal or State landholdings in the plan area. Of the 69,801 acres under the County's jurisdiction 20,392 (29%) are in some stage of crop production. The Subregion extends through three areaclimates, covers a variety of geomorphic provinces, and is within the C.W.A. and therefore can support a wide variety of crops. Along the coast there is extensive row crop and nursery production. Further east there are extensive orchards. Since 1970, orchard production appears to have increased about 35 percent and row crop production about 61 percent. The North County Metropolitan Subregion contains about 18 percent of the County's production acreage. -.4 Parcel Size -1 The unincorporated areas of the Subregion contain about 17,000 parcels, with an average parcel size of 4.1 acres. Five percent of those parcels (847) are engaged in agricultural production, and their average size is 15.7 acres. As might be expected, parcels tend to be smaller the closer they are to urban develop- ment. Relatively unusual is the fact that much of the production in the coastal areas continues to survive, and in some cases expand, on small parcels contiguous to urban centers. Water and Land Costs Water service to the unincorporated areas of the Subregion is provided by the Carlsbad Municipal Water District (C.M.W.D.), Vista Irrigation District (V.I.D.), San Marcos Municipal Water District (S.M.M.W.D.), and the Rincon del Diablo Municipal Water District (R.D.M.W.D.). From west to east the water rates are: $96 (C.M.W.D.), $108 (V.I.D.), $108 (S.M.M.W.D.), and $78 (R.D.M.W.D.). As can be seen, these rates are substantially lower than the County average of $135 per acre foot. Land costs in the North County Metropolitan Subregion are the third highest in the County with an average cost of $5,380 per acre. Non-irrigated land costs about $1,255 per acre while irrigated agricultural land costs about $4,820 per acre. The cost of irrigated agricultural land in this subregion is 32 percent higher than the County average. 46 -- , ao a 0 11 ' .?. c .~ 2 LANDS IN AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTION' ~ ~~ & NO,RTH COUNTY METROPOLITAN SUBREGION Land Use Designations In the Subregion as a whole 16 percent of the production is taking piace on lands with urban land use designations. The amount of land with urban classifications is expected to double in this Subregion as a result of the Growth Management program. Fifty percent of the current production is occurring on lands with non- urban land use classifications with the balance taking place within the incorpor- a ted areas. Summary It is difficult to summarize the potential of commercial agriculture in an area as big as the North County Metropolitan Subregion. For this reason this summary will divide the Subregion into the three following parts: 1. Coastal North County 2. Sheet 1 of Subregional Map (Vista - San Marcos) 3. Sheets 2 and 3 of Subregional Map (Escondido) 1. Coastal North County -- The coastal part of the North County Metropolitan Subregion possesses the physical criteria for commercial production. Those cultural factors which would favor long range commercial production include the following: " 100% (980 acres) of the land in production outside of the Coastal Commission jurisdiction and within the unincorporated area of the County has non-urban land use classifications; " the amount of land in production has remained relatively stable over the " agricultural water rate is 28% below County average; and past eight years; " new LAFCo policies make annexation of agricultural land more difficult. The cultural factors which would tend to reduce the potential for long-range commercial production in the coastal area include the following: " 37% of production acreage within incorporated boundaries, " extremely high value of Coastal Land, " County Island Annexation Policies, County Growth Management Policies in Coastal Area, " conflicts between urban and agricultural land uses, and " rapid growth in North County Subregion. 48 Long-range commercial production in the coastal area of the North County Metro- politan Area could be possible if the various land use authorities in the area portion of the production acreage within the incorporated area is also within the jurisdiction of the Coastal Commission. This may limit their development potential. In the same manner the effect of the County Island Annexation policies and the urban land use c'esignations in the area may be reversed in those areas subject to the Coas-il Commission. The 4,110 acres in production in the coastal area of the Subregir+r represent a significant resource in an area still capable of being retained fc r agricultural uses. - are able to agree on what specific lands are to be preserved. A significant 2. Sheet 1 of Subregional Map (Vista - San Marcos) -- The areas surrounding Vista - San Marcos possess, for the most part, the physical factors conducive to commercial agricultural production. Those cultural factors which would tend to support production include the following: " 6,400 acres in production (6% of County total), " 74% of product ion acreage (4,790 acres) in unincorporated area, " 87% of production acreage in unincorporated area under non-urban land use desi~nation, " 30% increase in production acreage since 1973, " LAFCo Annexation Policies, and - " agricultural water rates approximately 25% below County average. Those cultural factors which would tend to reduce the opportunities for continued commercial agricultural production include: " extremely rapid growth in area, and " high market value for land. 3. Sheets 2 and 3 of Subregional Map (Escondido) -- The areas surrounding Escondido possess the physical factors conducive to commercial agricultural production. Those cultural factors which tend to support continued production include the following: .. " high percentage of production in unincorporated area, " of 8,800 acres ih unincorporated area, 86% (7,537 acres) with designations, and " agricultural water rate 42% below County average. E. SAN DlEGUlTO COMMUNITY PLAN Production The San Dieguito Community Plan area is located along the ce non-urban ".ntral coast of San - Diego County directly south of the North County Metropolitan Subregion and north of the cities of San Diego and Del Mar. There are no substantial federal or State ownerships within the plan area. 49 LANDS IN AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTION SARI DIEGUITO Community Plan t 50 Of the 54,842 acres in San Dieguito only 9 percent (5,200 acres) is in crop production. Generally speaking, production in San Dieguito can be broken down into two distinct categories. Nurseries and field flower production takes place within two or three miles of the coast, and orchard production is the dominant crop type in central Sal( Dieguito. Since 1970, orchard acreage has increased by 13 percent while ro I crop production has virtually disappeared. .c Parce 1 Si =e The average parcel size for the 22,404 parcels in San Dieguito is 2.4 acres. Parcels engaged in crop production only make up 1.3 percent (311) of the total number of parcels, but they equal 8.3 percmt of the total acreage. The average size of parcels involved in crop production is 14.7 acres. The smaller, urban-size parcels are concentrated in the six urban areas of western San Dieguito. Water and Land Costs Water service to San Dieguito is provided by three separate water agencies: the Santa Fe Irrigation District (S.F.I.D.), the San Dieguito Irrigation District (S.D. I.D.), and the Olivenhain Municipal Water District (O.M.W.D.). Most of the crop production takes place in areas under the jurisdiction of the Santa Fe and San Dieguito Irrigation Districts, where the water rates arc 12 and 9 percent, respectively, under the County average. Land costs in San Dieguito are the highest of any of the plan areas studied. The cost per acre averages around $14,000, although market values close to the coast cost of $2,700 per acre while irrigated land has an average cost of $8,265 per acre. - can be many times higher. Non-irrigated land in San Dieguito has an average Land Use Des ignat ions As in the coastal section of the North County Metropolitan Subregion, the coastal area of San Dieguito has been under a great deal of development pressure. This pressure +CIS resulted in a complex land use pattern where urban development is located adjacent to agricultural operations. The field flower and nursery operations in Encinitas and Leucadia are almost all located in either "Low Residential" or "Intensive Agriculture" land use categories, which allow densi- ties of 2.9 dwelling units per acre and 1 dwelling unit per 2 - 4 or 8 acres, respectively. The row crop and orchard production in Rancho Santa Fe is located for the most part in the "Medium Estates" category which a1 lows a density of 1 dwelling unit per 2 acres. Summary The San Dieguito Community Plan area for the most part possesses all of the physical criteria needed for commercial agriculture. Those cultural factors which would tend to favor continued long-range production include the following: " 5% of County production acreage (significant portion of the commercial nursery and field flower production); - " 66% of production acreage on non-urban land use categories, only 14% on urban categories; " average agricultural parcel size of 14.7 acres; ” agricultural water rates 9-l2% below County average; ” 85% of nursery and field flower production within jurisdiction of Coastal Commission; and ” County Policy 1-38 - retention of agricultural lands in path of urban deve 1 opmen t. Those factors which would tend to reduce the potential for long-range commercial production in the San Dieguito Community Plan area include the following: “ high market value of land, 126% above County average; ” rapid growth in coastal areas; and “ urban-agricultural land use conflicts. F. PALA-PAUMA Product ion The Pala-Pauma subregion is located in northern San Diego County directly east of the Fallbrook Community Planning Area. Indian Reservations make up approximately 38 percent (28,532 acres) of the subregional area. Of the 75,319 acres in the plan area, 9,450 (12%) are in production. Production acreage has increased by around 2,500 acres (27%) since 1970 and currently accounts for 8 percent of the County total. Citrus and avocado orchards are by far the dominant crop type in the subregion. - Parcel Size There are 1,825 parcels in the Pala-Pauma subregion on the 46,787 acres in private ownership. The average parcel size in the subregion is 25.6 acres, while the average parcel size for the 412 parcels involved in agricultural production is 27.6 acres. The distribution pattern of the lot sizes shows the smaller parcels concentrated for the most part in the valley bottom. Water and Land Costs Pala-Pauma has water service provided by three dffferant water agencies: the Pauma, Yuima and Mootamai Municipal Water Districts. The Yuima M.W.D. which provides most of the water for agricultural purposes has an agricultural water rate of $150 per acre foot which is 11 percent above the County average. Land costs in Pala-Pauma are on the average significantly lower than the rest of the areas studied. The average cost of land in Pala-Pauma is $1,205 per acre. Non-irrigated land costs, on the average, $434 per acre and irrigated agricultural land has an average market value of $2,269 per acre, which is 37 percent below the County average. -. 4% PALA - PAUMA SUBREGION 53 Land Use Designation - Of the 9,.450 acres in production only 290 (3%) are on lands with urban designations. Most of the balance of the plan area has a four acre minimum parcel size, although the steeper slope areas have minimums of 8, 20, or 40 acres. Growth Management has placed most of the areas now in production in the "Estate" category, which again will require a minimum lot size of 4 acres. Summary The Pala-Paurna subregion has the physical factors required for long-range commercial orchard production. The cultural factors conducive to long-range commercial production in the subregion include the following: 9,200 acres in production, 6% of County production acreage, 27% increase in acreage since 1970, 88% of production acreage on land with non-urban classification, agricultural land costs are 37% below County average, average agricultural parcel size is 27.6 acres, and water costs are only 10 percent above County average. The Pala-Pauma subregion is gne of the most productive agricultural areas in San Diego County. Because of the limited accessibility, lack of capital facilities, the Growth Management designations, and the relatively large parcel sizes the current land use restrictions in the area appear sufficient to encourage the retention of commercial agriculture. G. VALLEY CENTER P roduct ion The Valley Center Community Plan area is located in northern San Diego County, directly south and west of the Pala-Paurna subregion. Eight percent of the 53,120 acres in the plan area are in Indian Reservations. Of the 48,837 acres in private ownership 49 percent (24,104 acres) is in some stage of crop production. Orchard acreage has increased 60 percent since 1973 and Valley Center now contains 23 percent of land under cultivation in the County. Parcel Size 7 The average parcel size in Valley Center is 11.3 acres. The average size of agri- cultural parcels is 16.7 acres. According to the Assessor's Office six-tenths of a percent of the parcels in the plan area are less than one-half acre. The d'istribu- tion pattern of the parcels shows that the smaller parcels tend to cluster among the three main roads which traverse the plan area. - 54 t 23 .. 2G " 35 t 2111G - LANDS IN AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTION Water and Land Costs The Valley Center Municipal Water District (V.C.M.W.D.) is the agency which provides agricultural water to Valley Center. The district's rate of $1 18 per acre foot is 12 percent below the County's average agricultural rate. The cost of land in Valley Center averages about $2,923 per acre. Non-irrigated land sells for $1,845 while irrigated land has an average market value of $3,104 per acre. The rate for irrigated land in Valley Center is about 14 percent below the County average. Land Use Des ignat ions Of the 24,104 acres in production, only 515 (2%) are in lands with urban designa- tions. The vast majority of the plan area has the "Medium tstate" or "Rural Estate" category which allow densities of 2 and 2 - 4 acres, respectively. The Growth Management program has designated most of Valley Center as ''Estate" or "Environmentally Constrained,'' except for a Country Town area of approximately 900 acres. Summa ry- Valley Center, like much of North County possesses unique physical conditions which meet the basic criteria for long-range commercial production. Virtually all of the cultural factors examined tend to support the conclusion that Valley Center can continue as a major agricultural center in San Diego. These factors - include the following: 9,205 acres in production, 23% of County production acreage, 49% of plan area in production, 60% increase in orchard acreage s i nce 1973, 98% of production on land with non-urban classification, average parcel size 16.7 acres, agricultural water rate 12 percent below County average, and irrigated agricultural land costs 14 percent below County average. OTAY MESA P roduc t ion The Otay Mesa subregional area is located in the southwestern portion of San Diego County. Within the 54,295 acres which make up the subregional area 39,112 are in private ownership. The balance is either owned by the City of San Diego, the Otay Municipal Water District, or the federal government. Of the land in private owner- -. ship 13,695 (35%) acres are in some stage of production. In a given year approximatel, . .. 'I - LANDS IN AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTION 4 OTAY SU6REGloNi a 57 1 4,000 acres will be planted to row crops; tomatoes, celery or peppers are the typical crops. The land not planted in row crops is either fallow, planted with some type of field crop, or used for grazing. -. Production in the Otay subregion takes place exclusively in the western half of the subregional area. The principal production areas are Otay Mesa and Rancho Otay. About half of the County's tomato acreage is located in these two areas. Production acreage has been relatively stable since 1970. Some acreage has been deleted on Rancho Otay, and some added to Otay Mesa. Parcel Size The average size of the 564 parcels in the Otay Subregion is 69.3 acres. The average size of the 13,695 acres in production is 45.1 acres. Except for Pendleton-Deluz this is the only subregion examined where the overall parcel size is larger than the average agricultural parcel. Rancho Otay, a large Spanish land grant, skews the average parcel size to the high side, because it consists of fourteen parcels averaging 379 acres. Water and Land Costs Water in the Subregion is supplied solely by the Otay M.W.D. Otay's rate for agricultural water of $179 per acre foot makes water in the area about a third more expensive than the County average. Land costs on the average about $1,135 per acre in the Subregion. Non-irrigated - land in the Subregion averages about $944 per acre, while irrigated land has an average market value of $2,352 per acre. Irrigated agricultural land in Otay costs about 35 percent less than the County average. Land Use Designations About 40 percent (5,500 acres) of the Subregion's production takes place on Otay Mesa where 80 percent (4,400 acres) of the land currently has an urban land use designation. The other 8,195 acres in production have an "intensive Agriculture" designation which a1 lows densities of 2, 4, or 8 acres. Most of the land in the Rancho Otay area would qualify for the 2 or 4 acre minimums. All of the produc- tion acreage north of Otay Mesa has a Growth Management designation of "Estate" which also allows densities of 2 and 4 acres. The Mesa however is identified as a "Special Study Area" in the Growth Management program and future development will depend upon whether the area is to be included in an "Economic Development District." Summa ry The western half of the Otay Subregional area satisfies the physical criteria for long range agricultural production. The cultural factors which would tend to keep the Otay region in production include the following: 13,695 acres in production, " production acreage relatively remote and compact, 58 r " 35% of Subregion in production, " accounts for 12% of County production acreage, " 68% of production acreage has non-urban land use designation, " average parcel size 45.1 acres, " 40% of production area has non-urban Growth Management designation, and " average land cost for irrigated land is 35% below County average. Those factors which would tend to work against long range commercial production include the following: " high water costs 32% above County average, " urban land use designation of County, " establishment of "Second Border Crossing,'' and " establishment of "Economic Development District." I. POWAY ..c Production The Poway Community Plan area is located south and east of the San Dieguito Com- munity Planning area in the foothills of San Diego County. There are no signi- ficant federal or State landholdings in the plan area. Of the 25,174 acres in Poway 2,592 (10%) is in some form of crop production. Although a sizeable section of the production acreage in central Poway has been removed, since I970 there has been an increase of over 900 acres (55%). Most of the new acreage has been planted in orchards in the northern and eastern parts of the plan area. Poway contains about 2 percent of the current County agricultural acreage. Parcel Size The average size of the 25,174 parcels in Poway is 2.4 acres. The plan area has two separate concentrations of urban development, one in the north, and one in the south, Production now takes place between the two urban areas and to the north and east. There are 108 parcels devoted to agricultural uses, and they have an average size of 17.2 acres. Water and Land Costs Water in Poway is delivered by the Poway M.W.D. whose rate for agricultural water, $135, is the same as the County's average. The average cost per acre of land in Poway is $7,687. Non-irrigated land sells for $2,180 per acre, while irrigated agricultural lands have a market value of $3,296 per acre, about 9 percent below the County average. P 59 i " LANDS IN AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTION 60 ," Land Use Designation Approximately 20 percent of the production in Poway tak es place on land with an urban designation. The other 2,076 acres are fairly evenly divided up between lands with four non-urban land use designations: "Medium Agricultural Estates" (2 acre minimum), "Agricultural Preserves" (8 acre minimum), "Intensive Agriculture" (2, 4, or 8 acre minimum), and "Mountain Development" (4, 8, or 20 acre min'imum). I Summary The Poway Community Planning area generally has the physical criteria required for long range commercial production. Those cultural criteria which tend to support continued agricultural uses include the following: " 2,592 acres in production, " 10% of area in production, " 2% of County production acreage, " 55% increase in acreage since 1970, " average agricultural parcel is 17.2 acres, IC " agricultural water rate same as County average, and " irrigated agricultural land is 9% below County average. J. RAMONA Production The Ramona Community Planning area is located in the foothills of Central San Diego County, directly east of the Poway Community Planning area. Within the 72,000 acres which make up the plan area there are 8,720 acres (12%) engaged in some form of agricultural production. Orchards (1,285 acres), field crops, and poultry production (7,155 acres) are the primary agricultural uses. Since 1970 there has been an increase of around 63 percent in production acreage. Although some acreage around the town center has been taken out of production several hundred acres of avocado orchards have been planted in the western part of the plan area, Ramona currently has about 8 percent of the County's produc- t ion ac reage. Parcel Size The average size of the 9,510 parcels in Ramona is 7.5 acres. The average size of the 313 parcels engaged in agricultural production is 26.9 acres. Only one of those 313 parcels is one-half acre or smaller in size. According to the Assessor's Office 63 of those 313 parcels (20%) are engaged in poultry production which has been a primary agricultural use in the area for several years. 61 IS 1/ 19 70 fd i" 29 LANDS IN AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTION - RAMONA 62 16=0 " ' Water and Land Costs The Ramona M.W.D. is the sole provider of imported water in the plan area. The current rate of $309 an acre for.': for agricultural water, which is 128 percent above the County average, is far and away the highest rate in the County. Appar- ently the 900 foot difference in elevation in the nine miles between Poway and Ramona is responsible for the B174 increase in water rates. The cost of land in Ramona avera'ges $2,394 per acre. Non- the average for $698 per acre, while irrigated land sells, $1,914 per acre. This rate is approximately 47 percent be irrigated land sells on low the County's average. on the average for Land Use Des i gnat i ons Only about 5 percent of the production acreage in Ramona has an urban land use designation. Almost 7,000 acres of agricultural production now takes place on land with at least a 2 acre minimum. The Growth Management program slightly expands the boundaries of the current town center where there is about 300 acres under cultivation. The balance of the plan area has an "Estate" designation and because of the topography will probably have a 2 acre minimum lot size. Summary The Ramona Community Plan area satisfies the physical criteria for long range production. The plan area also has a number of cultural factors which suggest that long range commercial production is possible. These include the following: e " 8,720 acres in production, " 125 of plan area, " 8% of County acreage, " 63% increase in production since 1970, " 93% of production acreage has non-urban land use designation, " 90% of production acreage has non-urban Growth Management designation, " average agricultural parcel is 26.9 acres, and " irrigated agricultural land cost is 47% below County average. The major factor working against continued agricultural production in Ramona is the cost of water. Currently the Ramona M.W.D. rate is 128% above the County average.. The water supply problem in Ramona is acute and may get worse. Recent plantings of avocado orchards could use close to 100% of the current R.M.W.D. water supply when they come to maturity. Perhaps the one saving grace is that typical orchard prodcution water usage is about the same as the permitted resi- dential development would be on a per acre basis. The question about continued commercial agricultural uses in Ramona is more clearly an economic question than a 1 and use problem. *c 63 K. RAINBOW-LAKESIDE-VALLE DE OR0 AND CREST/DEHESA Preliminary research into the above four areas revealed that, although they possessed the physical criteria needed for long range commercial production there is relatively little in the way of agricultural production occurring now. All four have less than 2,000 acres each: Rainbow - 1,715, Lakeside - 1,154, Crest/Dehesa - 431, and Valle de Oro - 907, and all four have experienced a rapid and substantial loss in production acreage since 1970. Except for Rainbow, all four areas have experienced a rapid urbanizing trend over the last eight years. Virtually all of the production areas in Lakeside and Valle de Oro have been given a "Current Urban" designation by Growth Management and there is little reason to believe that commercial agriculture can or will continue in these two areas. Crest-Dehesa, isolated from the other production areas in the County has experienced a 22 percent loss in acreage over the last eight years and currently only has 431 acres in production. The Rainbow Community Plan area is somewhat of an anomaly in that while the area satisfies the physical criteria for orchard production, has irrigated land values just below the County average, and has 75 percent of the area with non-urban land use designations agricultural acreage has diminished by about 24 percent since 1970. 64 I 14 - 23 26 35 1 11 _I 14 I LANDS IN AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTION RAINEOW 4 , Community 65 Plan " "" . 4s 7 " " "" 19 30 31 " 6 "- 7 I ,*/ - -- - .- . .. LANDS IN AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTION " LAKESIDE * Community Plan 66 VALLE DE OR0 e Community 67 Plan i 18 7- . _" . ." . 17 16 15 14 0 ' , 19 20 21 22 21 29 32 28 33 " FEET MILES I LANDS IN AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTION A& CREST - DEHEsA 68 , SUMMARY OF CHAPTER ONE This chapter analyzed the principal, cultural resources which effect local , agricultural production to better understand what areas of the County are most likely to be able to continue long range production. Based on that analysis following appear to be the most important conclusions: There are three major areas of crop production in the County: 1. North County: 75% production acreage 2. Coastal: 6% production acreage 3. Otay: 13% production acreage Together these three areas equal 94% of the County’s agricultural acreage. Overall acreage increasing: 1. North County has had tremendous increase in acreage. 2. Coastal area losing some acreage. 3. Otay relatively stable. Qualitatively land going out of production is better, in that there is a relatively wide range of crops that can be planted on it. Sixty percent of the new acreage is planted with avocados and is land unsuited for virtually anything else. Only 7 percent of production acreage ,in the three major agricultural areas have urban designations. Only 14 percent of production acreage in the three major ayricultural areas have R.G.M. urban designations. Average agricultural water rate in the three major agricultural areas is 9.75 percent below County average agricultural rate. Average irrigated land costs are: 1. 24% below County average in most of North County. 2. 126% above County average in Coastal areas. 3. 14% below County average in Otay. Average agricultural parcel in these three areas is 20.7 acres. CHAPTER 2 FRUIT AND VEGETABLE PACKING INDUSTRY Agr i cu 335 mi lture in San D llion dollars iego County had a gross production value of approximately in 1977. Using the multiplier develaped for the agricultural industry in the Regional Economic Impacts of Resource Use, by the University of California, 2.164, the total regional value of the industry was around 725 million dollars in 1977. A 1 ittle over half of the production value is generated by the orchard and vegetables sectors. The objective of this chapter is to provide a brief examination of the packing and wholesaling industries in the County, especially as they relate to the packing and wholesaling of fruit and vegetable production. The information in this chapter is a summary of interviews and research conducted during July, 1978. The chapter is divided into four parts: the fruit packing industry, the vegetable packing industry, the fruit and vegetable wholesaling industry, and appendices. FRU I T PACK1 NG INDUSTRY The f i rms packing f ru i t in San D iego County range in size from 20 to 80 employees. They process primarily avocados and limes; two of the ten firms specialize in lemon and grapefruit packing. The industry is located primarily in the North County area from Rancho Santa Fe - Escondido area north into Riverside County. The packing plants are concentrated around Escondido and Fa1 lbrook. Seven avocado packing firms were - interviewed.. The avocado firms had a production value of over $65,000,000 for 1977, while the two citrus firms' production was valued at over $8,000,000 accounting for virtually all 1977 citrus production in San Diego County. There were four basic types of packing operations among those interviewed: 1) firms which were their own grower, packer, and shipper; 2) firms which purchased fruit grown by farmers; 3) firms that contract with farmers; and 4) co-ops. Due to the year-round growing season and different fruit varieties, the plants remain open all year. In the case of avocados, about 95 percent of the raw produce originates from within San Diego County. The remaining 5 percent comes primarily from Ventura and Santa Barbara areas, with a small amount from Riverside County. The final product is packed fruit. The products are shipped worldwide, with primary markets being Japan (lo%), Europe (5%), Texas (30%), Chicago (30%), East Coast (20%), and about 5% is sold locally or in Los Angeles. The citrus packing plants receive 100 percent of their raw produce from San Diego County. Final products are mostly packed fruit, with a small amount of canned produce. The products are shipped worldwide with the market broken down as follows: Japan (269;), Europe (l5%), East Coast (primarily Atlanta, Philadelphia, and New York - 54%), the remaining 7% is sold to San Diego and Los Angeles. Virtually all products move to market by truck; only one firm still uses any rail service. Rail service to the North County Area is generally inadequate and new rail expansion is not expected. Products moving overseas are moved by ship from Long Beach; 2 percent is shipped by air, primarily to Europe. " 70 About half of the firms are operating at about 50 percent capacity, while the rest are near 95 percent capacity. Spokesmen for the firms do not think urban expansion is, at present, any threat to the industry and several firms are considering building new plants. When asked about stimulating growth in the industry, the primary suggestion was to regulate in some way the individual water districts where great disparities in prices and arbitrary raising of prices were mentioned. VEGETABLE PACKING INDUSTRY The firms packing vegetables in San Diego County range in size from five employees to over 100 employees. They handle primarily tomatoes, strawberries, cucumbers, and celery, as well as lesser amounts of squash, cauliflower, beans, cabbage, lettuce, corn, asparagus, and a few other minor crops. The firms are located in two major areas: the North County Area, ranging from the coastal strip south of Carlsbad to around the metropolitan areas extending north of Vista and inland of Oceanside, and the South County Area from Chula Vista to Otay Mesa. The eleven firms interviewed had a production value of $63,200,000 for I977 which comprises about 74 percent of the total County vegetable production. Of these firms, six are located in the North County Area and account for $47,500,000 (56% of County total), and 5 are in the South County Area and account for $15,700,000 (18% of County tota 1 ) . rc Most of the firms interviewed are large organizations which grow, pack, and ship their own produce. There are also a few co-ops and firms which contract with and purchase from growers. Because of the year-round growing season and variety of produce, the firms remain open all year. Virtually all produce processed originates in San Diego County. Only one has minor acreage in Orange County from where it moved several years ago. The final produce is packed vegetables for wholesale. Nearly 80 percent of the products are shipped to the midwest and the east coast. The Los Angeles and San Francisco terminals received 0 - 15 percent of the products, with the remainder being sold locally in San Diego. Only one firm interviewed ships overseas, through Long Beach. Almost all produce moves to market by truck. At present most plants are operating at between 50 to 80 percent of their capacity with several in the process of expanding. The managers feel they could withstand no more than 10 - 15 percent reduction in production to maintain their present operation. Most of the firms interviewed had a pessimistic outlook for the future, although many are enthusiastic about expanding and welcome any assistance from the government. A few firms in the North County Area, however, indicated their agricultural investment is short term. When asked about stimulating the local economy, most of those interviewed replied that the lack of facilities in San Diego compared to the large terminal and facilities in Los Angeles was the primary deterent to selling more products locally. FRUIT AND VEGETABLE WHOLESALERS IN SAN DIEGO COUNTY The wholesale produce industry in San Diego is characterized by small firms in inadequate facilities supplying independent stores, restaurants and small insti- tutions. Most of the firms are located around 6th and Island in downtown San Diego. These facilities were built early in the century and have changed little. Many firms lack even loading docks, and produce is land-loaded onto trucks along crowded streets. There is no long-term or bulk refrigerating equipment; there- fore produce must be quickly turned over and storage is not possible. As a result, most of the large retailers buy and store produce in Los Anyeles and truck the produce to their stores in San Diego on a daily basis. Representatives of nine firms were interviewed. These firms comprise about 25 percent of the fruit and vegetable wholesalers in the region and have sales of about $35,650,000, which is estimated to be 60 percent of the local fruit and vegetable wholesale total. These firms purchase their produce from several seasonal markets. Over an entire year, it is estimated that local producers supply 17 percent of total produce; Mexican producers about 23 percent of total produce; the Los Angeles market supplies 13 percent of total produce to the local wholesalers; and the remainder comes from the western states, ranging from Washington to Colorado to Arizona. The produce is then sold to local small chain stores, Ma & Pa stores, restaurants, small institutions, and the military. Almost all of those interviewed complained about the inadequate facilities. Due to the congestion, several firms have begun locating elsewhere in the City and County, beginning a decentralization trend in the industry. Most firms feel special facilities should be built, either near the present 6th & Island location or in the centrally located Mira Mesa area. At the very least, they feel the City should recognize the industry by designating a central market area wherein growth could be encouraged. Many indicate business opportunities to supply the expanding San Diego market (estimated 2 million people by 1980) are being lost to Los Angeles due to general non-recognition by the City of the industry and its needs. - In the South County Area wholesaling of Mexican produce is expanding. Since the completion of the Baja Highway by the Mexican Government, agriculture alony the Baja Peninsula has been growing. Several firms have begun handling Mexican pro- duce, a few exclusively, in the past several years. The firms in this business have an optimistic outlook as Mexican agriculture becomes progressively more important to the area and suggest the government review the border regulations and tariffs in the face of changing conditions. At present, the wholesale busi- ness from Mexican produce in San Diego County is estimated to be worth $10,000,000 in gross sales. About 15 percent of this is sold locally with the rest shipped to the midwest and east. Primary crops are tomatoes, brussels sprouts, watermelon, and broccoli. Although Mexican agriculture is limited, due primarily to water, it is felt that the expanding urban areas of San Dieyo will cause agriculture south of the border to become increasingly more important. 72 PART IV ANALYSIS OF THE AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY OF SAN DIEGO COUNTY 73 CHAPTER 1 I NTRODUCT I ON AND SUWt4ARY Two economic studies were prepared for the County of San Diego for the purpose of determining the importance and viability of agriculture in this region. The first study, prepared by the University of California Extension Service, analyzed the interrelationships between the agriculture sector and other economic sectors within and outside the region. The second study, completed by Copley Interna- tional and Pacific Consultants, analyzed the viability of various crops in San Diego County. In addition, County staff has utilized the San Diego County Demographic and Economic Forecasting Model (DEFM) to analyze the local employ- ment impacts of agriculture workers. Based upon this analysis, the following is a summary by County staff of the results of the above mentioned studies: 1. rc 2. 3. - Agriculture, in ternis of dollar value of output, is the fourth largest sector in San Diego County. Only manufacturing, military, and tourism sectors rank higher. Agriculture accounts for 1.7 percent of the personal income, 3.4 percent of County sales, and 2.1 percent of employment in the Reyion. In summary, the two consultant studies have indicated that agri- culture indeed is an important industry in the region. In fact, many crops presently have a positive rate of return on capital investment and given current trends can be expected to continue to show the relationship in the future. In terms of multiplier effect, agriculture contributes substantially to local economic activity. For every $1.00 agriculture sells, an additional $1.16 is generated indirectly in County sales. This multiplier effect does vary but is roughly stable among various agricultural subsectors. On the average, agriculture has a higher multipl ier effect than many other sectors in the local economy. The study by Copley International and Pacific Consultants analyzed the historical trends in revenue and the current cost structure for various crops. Thc costs analyzed included production costs (i.e., soil prepara- tion, water, pest control), overhead (i.e., taxes, equipment repair), land lease costs, depreciation, and harvest costs. The end product of this analysis was a specification of the current expected revenue and cost for major crop categories in the region. In order to have a comnon basis of comparison, these cost and revenue calculations were stated in terms of production units. Typically this production unit is an acre for field crops or per animal for poultry, etc. It must be emphasized that the costs of production do not include debt service costs for land purchases of an owner-grower. Given the present revenue and cost structures, one measure of economic viability was calculated for San Diego's crops. This is the net differ- ence between revenues and costs as a percent of dollar investment in machinery, storage facilities, equipment, etc. That is, a gross rate of return on capital investment was computed. 74 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. - The following crops at the Countywide level currently show a positive rate of return on capital investment and are defined in the context of this study as economically viable: avocadoes, cauliflower, tomatoes, gladiolus, squash, strawberries, cucumbers, milk, lemons, eggs, and nursery crops. These crops currently account for about 80 percent of agricultural sales in San Diego County. An analysis of the specific revenues and costs for various crops within planning subregions indicate the following areas were determined to have economically viable agricultural sectors: North County Metropolitan, Fallbrook, Bonsall, Valley Center, Otay, San Dieguito, Pendleton-DeLuz, and Pala-Pauma. The focus of the subregional analysis was the unincor- porated area of the County only. While there are crops which have positive rates of return on capital investment, it must also be recognized that many of the agricultural lands in San Diego County would be uneconomical to farm given purchase at today's market prices, resulting debt service requirements that would be incurred, and the revenue that the crops would generate in the marketplace. However, it must also be noted that these land values could potentially change drastically, if zoning limits the extent of alternative land uses. This phenomenon can clearly be seen in Table 17 in Chapter 2. In this table the value of agricultural land given risks, revenues, costs, and interest on capital is calculated (land value, risk adjusted figure). It can be seen that the value of agricultural land in terms of what it returns on agricultural production is intuitively less than the land is worth for alternative uses in many cases. For example, the value calculated per acre for tomato production is $3700. Clearly, tomato land in North County could be sold above this if zoned for residential development. " There are data which support the contention that speculation is occurring on agricultural lands in San Diego County. That is, crops are being grown at a loss in order to realize future capital gains on the sale of the agricultural land. Agricultural production in San Diego County is primarily Avocadoes, tomatoes, and flowers are major export crops. percentage of milk, eggs, and citrus fruit produced loca local consumer demand. export oriented. However, a high 1 ly satisfies In addition to the cost of purchasing agricultural land, a very important factor affecting the future viability of agriculture will be the cost and availability of water. It is uncertain what the cost of water will be in the future in San Diego County. This will depend on Colorado River water negotiations and the price of Northern California water. These future water costs wi 11 be largely influenced by pumping costs and therefore energy costs. The consultant reports primarily reviewed the current costs of water and the amount of water used in producing various crops. 75 Hence, the forecasting of how future water prices would affect the viability of agriculture in San Diego County was beyond the scope of this study. Clearly, those crops which use water most intensively are most likely to be affected by cost rises (Table 15 in Chapter 2 i 1 lus- trates water use by crop). What will be extremely important in determining the viability of various crops, given future water costs, is consumer sensitivity to price increases and thus the grower ability to "pass on" the increased water costs. 10. A comparison has been made of continuing agricultural production on land producing tomatoes versus building low density residential development on the land, The results indicate that the region would receive greater long ana 1 yzed . - run income by continuing agricultural production in the one case that was 11. A variety of various possible agriculture acreage losses (i.e., 20 percent reduction in County acreage devoted to the County's five largest crop categories) indicates that the local economic impact would be fairly sub- stantial for these conversions to non-agricultural uses. It should be noted that these "loss scenarios" were analyzed for illustrative purposes only. Hence, they may or may not represent actual losses in the future. CHAPTER 2 COPLEY INTERNATIONAL AND PACIFIC CONSULTANTS ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF AGRICULTURAL VIABILITY IN SAN DIEGO COUNTY Copley International and Pacific Consultants prepared an analysis of the viability of various crops in San Diego and the factors affecting their future in San Diego County. To this end, data was collected and analyzed on factors such as: the historical trends in costs and revenues associated with various crops, agricultural marketing strategies, variables influencing crop productivity, and the unique conditions in San Diego County which deter- mine the viability of various agricultural crops. Summarized below are the major results of this study: 1. San Diego County has crops which show a positive rate of return on gross capital investment and thus, are defined as economically viable in the context of this study. These crops are: avocadoes, cauliflower, cherry tomatoes, gladiolus, squash, strawberries, cucumbers, tomatoes, milk (dairy products), lemons, eggs, and nursery crops. The followiny table presents the average gross rate of return on capital investnxnt for crops in San Diego County: CROP NAME Avocadoes Cauliflower Bedding Plants Nursery Cherry Tomatoes Galdiolus Squash Strawberries Cucumbers Toma toes Si lage Da i ry Lemons Eggs L i mes Green Chop Foliage Plants Cow/Ca 1 f Chicken/Fryers Ce 1 ery Navel Oranges TABLE 14 Return on Investment of Agricultural Crops In San D iego County GROSS PERCENTAGE RATE OF RETURN ON CAPITAL INVESTMENT Tange 1 os Carnations Grapef rui t Va 1 enc i a Orar Rabbi ts Alfalfa Hay Stocker Catt f: ( ) indicates a lges le negative rate of return. 32.54 30.11 28.17 28.17 22.53 22 .oo 21.28 20.80 19-33 14.83 10.80 4.25 1.78 1.04 (.3P (0 49) (1 -30) (3.34) (6.33) (8.12) (1 1.67) (8.8) (12.17) (12.5) (13.13) (1 8.9) (20.8) (23.91) 77 P Those crops which are economically viable account lor- 80 pcr-cc-nt 01' tlrc agricultural sales in San Uieyo County and about 36.5 percent of the harvested acreage in I977 (this does not include dairy and egg production whose relative acreage is small). 2. The major advantage to local agriculture is the mild climate of the region, while topography, soil quality, and water availability provide the major analysis of the viability of planning subregions in the unincorporated areas of the County indicate that the following areas are economically viable with respect to agriculture: North County Metropolitan, Fallbrook, Bonsall, Val ley Center, Otay, San Dieguito, Pendleton-DeLuz, and Pala- Pauma. Quite clearly, the planning subregions of North County Metropolitan, San Dieguito, Bonsall, Fallbrook, and Otay are areas which will increasingly be suhject to urban development pressures. ' physical constraints to the expansion of agricultural production. An What this implies is that these planning subregions have crops which are currently economically viable and thus worth careful consideration for planning the preservation of cropland. 3. The cost of water for agricultural users is higher in San Diego County than most counties in California. California State Project water could increase from $10 an acre foot to $61 an acre foot by the mid-1980's. Likewise current contract is renegotiated. - Colorado River water costs will increase substantially in 1987 when the As mentioned in Chapter 1, the consultant studies did not attempt to forecast future water prices and their effect on the viability of various crops. This type of effort is difficult due to the uncertainty surround- ing contract negotiations. The local effect of these water costs increases will depend on such factors as the cost of water in other areas outside of San Diego County, the sensitivity of consumers to crop price increases, the abi 1 i ty to "pass on" cost increases, etc. Any impact of water costs on various crops will, of course, depend on the intensity at which crops use water. The table below presents the percentage of total production costs that water accounts for in selected crop categories: TABLE I5 Cost Of Local Water In Agricultural Production Crop Name Toma toe s Celery Caul if lower Cherry Tomatoes Cucumbers Squash Oranyes F Percent of Total Production cost 2.71 4.98 11 .og 2.43 3.99 9.32 14.4 78 4. 5. 6. 7. TABLE Crop Name Grapefruit Limes Lemons Tanger i nes Strawberries Avocadoes Bedding Plants Foliage Plants Carnations Floral Production I5 (Continued) Percent of Total Production 12.83 12.83 7.22 13.67 3.02 20.91 .66 6.22 3.58 5.04 An estimate was made of future agricultural trends in San Diego County, assuming that past trends in the agricultural sector will indicate future behaltior in the agricultural sector. This analysis showed that in real or inflation-adjusted dollars, that agricultural sales would increase by 12 percent between 1977 and 1980. The major crops contributing to this increase are milk, avocadoes, lemons, limes, and grapefruit. Major declines in real sales were forecast in tomatoes, gladiolus, valencia oranges, and bedding plants. These projections indicate that, given past trends, that the fruit crops (primarily avocadoes) wi 11 provide the major increases in agricultural activity in San Diego County for the next few years. However, vegetables and nursery/field flowers are likely to experience a decline in real production values, due to a projected trend in declining acreage under production. The table on the following page presents this information in greater detail. It must be emphasized, however, that the forecasting of agricultural sales is difficult due to the volatility of agricultural markets. Therefore, these figures represent rough estimates only. The table does not include all crop categories. - I The major strength in recent years in agricultural production has been the expansion in the production of avocadoes. Strong consumer demand coupled with the effective marketing strategies has contributed to this expanding section of the local agricultural economy. Vegetable production, which is dominated by tomatoes, is concentrated in two areas of the County -- North County Metropolitan and Otay Mesa where about 78 percent of this activity occurs in the County. Vegetable land is largely leased and vegetable production is highly sensitive to market conditions independent of the San Diego County Economy. San Piego County, while at a competitive disadvantage to other Counties in California with respect to water prices, does enjoy a distinct advantage in labor availability and costs. This is due, in large part, to undocumented workers employed in local agriculture. 79 TABLE 16** Agriculture Revenue Summary San Diego County -- Selected Crops (In 1977 Dollars) Crop by Category Livestock and Poultry: Mi lk Beef Cattle & Cull Dairy Cattle Chickens (fryers) Eggs Rabbits Feed Crops : Si lage Green Chop ti ay Nursery and Field Flowers: “71aciiolus ditrus E Subtropical Fruit Trees Ornamental Trees and Shrubs Bedding Plants Vegetables: lorna toes Celery Cau 1 i flower Cucumber Squash Fruit Crops: Avocadoes Grapefruit Lernrms L i-oe5 Strad!berries Valencias liave 1 s Tanger i nes E Tange 10s TOTAL REVENUE : - 1980 County 1977 County % I ncrease/ Revenue Project ion Revenue +: Decrease $ 88,169,535 30,918,175 4,778,314 673,605 51,312,296 487,145 1,058,474 523 , 398 252,486 282,590 20,863,000 1,657,074 4,149,319 11,796,048 3,261,518 60,066,994 50,850,258 3,222,996 1,618,620 2,699,160 1,675,960 131,765,242 89,008,930 2,219,400 8,799,622 1 ,734,250 9,428,900 16,768,000 1 ,749,300 2,056,790 301,924,204 $f33,576,000 24,701,000 5,825,000 704,000 51,408,000 939,000 1,236,000 326,000 262,000 648,000 23,298,000 2,306,000 4,246,000 12,375,000 4,371,000 72,153,000 63,332,000 2,889,000 1,210,000 3,230,000 1,492,000 89,429,500 50,058,000 1 ,556,000 6,364,000 1,640,000 7,721,000 2,293,000 1,967,000 269,692,500 17,830,000 + 5% +252 -188 - 48 - 1% -92% -17% +6 1% - 4% -56% -12% -28% - 2% - 5% - 38% -20% -20% +12% +3 4% - 16% +122 +47% +78% +43% +3 8% + 6% +22% - 37% -31% + 5% +12% ; 2ource: County of San Diego, Department of Weights and Measures, Agricultural Crop Report, 1977. ;kf:Total Crop Revenue was 335 million for 1977. . .0. 80 8. The vegetable and egg industries are highly integrated in San Diego; that I is, the grower of crops is likewise the shipperharketer. 9. Nursery crops are primarily grown on the coastal plains of San Diego County. Nursery farms are typically grower owned. 10. Agricultural parcel size is becoming smaller as agricultural land adjacent and within urban areas becomes developed. What this table illustrates is that the value of agricultural land is often less than what it would yield if sold for non-agricultural uses. For example, tomato land at an agri- cultural value of $3,700 per acre would sell for above this if sold for residential development in many areas of the County. That is, this table presents the theoretical calculated value of agricultural land for agri- cultural product ion only. All production units are acres except for bedding plants and nursery plants. These are stated in terms of 1,000 square feet. The following crops had a negative rate of return on capital investment and thus had a calculated agric1,lltural land value of zero: dairy, lemons, eggs, limes, green chop, foliage plants, cow/calf, chicken/fryers, celery, navel oranges, tangelos, carnations, grapefruit, valencia oranges, rabbits, alfalfa hay, and stocker cattle. TABLE 17 LAND VALUE PER PRODUCTION UNIT OF AGRICULTURAL LAND FOR AGRICULTURAL USES -- SAN DlEGO COUNTY Crop Name Value Avocado Cauliflower Bedding Plants Cherry Tomatoes Gladiolus Squash Strawberries Cucumbers Toma toe s Silage tiursery $ 6,000 2,500 12,300 7,500 3,300 2,100 3,400 2,000 3,700 200 12,300 81 CHAPTER 3 UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA EXTENSION SERVICE SUHHARY OF THE AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN SAN DIEGO COUNTY San Diego County is currently among the top twenty counties in the United States in agricultural production, as measured by personal income allocated to the region. In terms of dollar value of output, agriculture ranks as the fourth largest industry in San Diego County. As far as personal income, agriculture increased its share of regional personal income from 1.1 percent to 1.7 percent between 1971 and 1976. In summary, agriculture represents a sizable sector in San Diego County's economy. This chapter summarizes the interrelationships between this agricultural sector and other economic sectors in San Diego County, presents recent trends in the production of various crops, and examines the economic impact of replacing land under agricultura'l production with residential development. That is, this chapter will provide a broad overview of the importance of agriculture to San Diego County. The information is taken from a report prepared by the University of California Extension Service. The tables on the following pages summarize the most important information - presented in this report. Briefly described below is the information in these tab1 es: TABLE 18 Compares the percentage change in acreage under production and constant dollar sales for major crop categories in the County. This period of comparison is an average sales and acreage data for 1968-1970 and 1974-1976. TABLE 19 Indicates the dollar value of output and associated employment for major crop categories in San Diego County for 1975. TABLE 20 Provides a ranking of the sales "multiplier" effect of various agricultural subsectors. A sales multiplier of 2.0, for example, would indicate that for each $1.00 worth of agriculture sales an additional $1.00 is generated in other sales by local economic sectors. I TABLE 21 Presents the percent of sales by agricultural subsector which is allocated to local firms and households. The difference between these two numbers represents sales to local firms. 82 TRENDS IN AGRICULTURAL SALES AND ACREAGE UNDER PRODUCTION Flowers and Plants Avocadoes Field Crops Lemons, L imes, Grapef rui t Oranges, Tangerines Strawberries Toma toes Dairy Poultry and Eggs Ce 1 ery COUNTY ACREAGE CHANGE N/A 28 -5 63 54 37 25 -6 2 - -35 SALES CHANGE 112 100 68 . * 59 58 48 47 7 -7 - -30 d 23 46 TABLE 19 DOLLAR VALUE OFOUTPUT AND EMPLOYMENT BY AGRICULTURAL SUBSECTOR (OUTPUT IN MILLIONS. OF 1977. DOLLARS, EMeLOYMENT IN NUMBER OF FULL TIME EQUIVALENT JOBS) OUTPUT EMPLOYMENT Toma toes Pou 1 try and Eggs Potted Plants Avocadoes Dai ry Major Greenhouse Oranges and Tangerines Field Flowers Lemons, Limes, Grapefruit Strawberries Cattle Field Crops Celery $57.1 $55.5 $48.0 $42.0 $25.2 $22.0 $21.1 $14.0 $1 1.9 $ 8.5 $ 6.3 $ 4.4 $ 3.6 TAMLt: 20 MULTIPLIER EFFECT BY AGRICULTURAL SUBSECTOR Lemons, Limes, Grapefruit Toma toes Oranges and Tanger I nes Avocadoes Potted Plants Ce I ery Field Crops Major Greenhouse St rawbcrr ies Beef Eggs Flowers Mi Ik AGRICULTURAL AVERAGE AVERAGE NON-AGRICULTURE SECTORS 83 305 1 1114 1332 I506 390 699 553 324 482 387 52 143 147 2.4747 2.3479 2.3315 2.291 1 2 2664 2.2561 2.2180 2.2132 2.0137 1.9003 1.8123 1.7265 2 2797 2.164 1 0.990 . TABLE 21 PERCENT OF AGRICULTURAL SALES TO LOCAL ECONOMIC SECTORS Mi lk Potted Plants Beef Eggs Strawberries Oranges and Tangerines Lemons, Limes, Grapefruit Celery Toma toes Avoca doe s Flowers Greenhouse AVERAGE HOUSEHOLDS AND FIRMS 90.2 48.0 45.6 43.0 30.4 28.7 28.7 27.0 24.5 26.0 lQ.0 -65 35.5 HOUSEHOLDS ONLY 83.0 28.7 25.0 28.1 18.2 23.1 23.1 18.2 18.2 23.1 5.7 0 26.0 84 The following is a summary of the information contained in the University of California Extension Services study: 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. An Each dollar value of agricultural sales in San Diego County generates an additional $1.16 in local sales via the "multiplier" effect. Agri- culture yenerates a substantial amount of direct and indirect economic activity in the region, in fact, higher than most local industries. Recent information indicates a definite trend towards producing crops which have a high commodity value per acre, such as tomatoes, avocadoes, flowers, etc. This is reflective, in part, of the increasing value of agricultural land and thus the desire to obtain a high rate of return on this land. The major reason for agriculture increasing its share of personal income in the region from 1971-1976 has been the rapid expansion in avocado and, to a minor degree, flower production. Thirty-six percent of total sales in the agricultural industry is sold to local industriles and households. Sales to local households comprise 26 percent of total agricultural sales. Milk, eggs, and potted plants represent those crops which are predominantly purchased by local consumers, while avocadoes, flowers, tomatoes, and greenhouse plants are the highest export- oriented crops. 4 County agricultural sales represent 3.4 percent of total private sector sales in San Diego County. Given the high multiplier effect and labor intensivenesss of tomato production, any decline in this agricultural subsector should be of special concern. Compared to other economic sectors, agriculture ranks higher in "nwltiplier" effect than the average non-agricultural industries. However, there are ten economic sectors (out of the 44 classified in this study) which have hiyher- multipliers. In other words, agriculture is not a low multiplier sector and thus, does contribute substantially to local economic activity. - input-output table was utilized to derive most of the figures cited previously. An outfall of the construction of an input-output table is that it can be uti 1 ized to perform economic impact analysis. In order to give an indication of the effects of reducing the acreage under agricultural production in the San Deigo County area, four specific land use scenarios were analyzed using this analytic device. Described below are these scenarios and a summary of their results: SCENARIO 1. This measured the impact of the effects of constrained growth in the County via a limiting of agricultural land available for residential development. This scenario measures an extreme case of growth limitation and is probably not close to reality. It was assumed that 5,700 jobs in aircraft manufacturing, yeneral machine, and electrical machine would only be available in the region if 935 acres - /- of agricultural land was made available for hows. That is, ~11 1 ut these potential workers would be inmigrants filling all these jobs and needing homes in the region. The estimated impact of this was an addition of an annual 362 million dollars in local sales, 113 million dollars in personal income, and a total job addition of 8,520. SCENARIO II. This measured the impact on agricultural production of converting 20 to SO percent of the agricultural land in Otay Mesa, San Uieguito, Escondido, Fa1 lbrook', and Valley Cenier to single family residential use. It was estimated that a 20 percent loss in agricultural acreage (11,474 acres) would result in an annual loss of 71.3 million dollars in sales, 27.5 million dollars in income, and 2,517 jobs in the region. A fifty percent reduction was estimated to result in an annual 178 million dollar sales loss, a 68.9 million dollar loss in income, and a 6,294 loss in jobs. SCENARIO Ill. This scenario measured the impact on the County's agricultural production of converting all existing agricultural acreage in areas designated for urban development in the County's preliminary Growth Management Plan to residential use. The reduction in agricultural acreage would be approximately 11,735 acres resulting in an annual sales loss of 74.5 million dollars, 29.0 million dollars in lost income and 2,660 job reduction. SCENARIO IV. This final scenario measured the impact on agricultural production of a 20 and 50 percent reduction in acreage devoted to San Diego's five largest crop categories: tomatoes, avocadoes, field flowers, poultry, and nursery pro- ducts. /I A 20 percent reduction was estimated to result in a 71 million dollar annual loss in sales, 25.5 million dollar annual loss in income and a 2,329 total job reduction. A 50 percent reduction was projected to result in a 178 million annual dollar sales loss, a 63.7 million dollar annual income loss, and a 5,824 job reduction for the reg ion. What is important to note about these scenarios is that they represent a range of possibilities for reduction in agricultural production in San Diego County. It appears clear that agriculture is an important industry to San Diego County. The critical factor that will have to be watched in the future is the degree to which agricultural production losses are offset by net gains in other economic sectors. As the input-output is static in nature, i.t does not include feedback relationships inherent in a simultaneous equation econometric model. Therefore, potential interrelationships between agricultural production and non-agricultural production are not totally quantified in this one type of economic model. - 86 CHAPTER IV AN ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS OF AGRICULTURE IN SAN DIEGO COUNTY SUMMARY AND COt4CLUSI ONS The County of San Diego is currently engaged in preparing the Agricultural Element to the County's General Plan. A multitude of factors must be analyzed in designing this plan, including the importance of agriculture to the economy of San Diego County. Most of this economic analysis has been prepared by two consultants, Copley International and the University of California Extension Service. However, the County of San Diego currently has for its use a tool which could not be utilized by these consultants, the Demographic an'd Economic Forecasting Model (DEFM). Therefore, this chapter wi 11 analyze the relative importance of agriculture to San Oiego County using the DEFM. While detailed information will be provided, it should be viewed as a supplement to the consultants' reports. Based upon the analyses found in the following sections, contained below are the major conclusions of this analysis: 1. A substantial reduction in agricultural production and service related employment (1,000 jobs -- assumed for illustrative purposes only) with no permanent replacement employment (i.e., shift to wholesale and retail employment) would have a net negative economic impact on the region. It was estimated that a 1,000 job reduction in agricultural related employment would result in an additional 979 "indirect" jobs being reduced in the regicn. Likewise, this was estimated to result in an income loss of $229 million for an eleven year period. This simulated agricultural job reduc- tion of 1,000 represents about 8.6 percent of the persons currently employed in agricultural production and services. Assuming that there is a propor- tional relationship between agricultural sales and employment, an 8.6 percent reduction in agricultural production in the County commensurate with conversion to "one time" economic impact (specifically, low density residential construction) would probably have a net negative economic impact on the region. That is, the conversion of agricultural land to residential use could result in a net negative economic impact to the region if the long run "permanent" income of agricultural production is greater than the "one time" impact of residential construction. This is 1 ikely to be the case for law density residential development. - 2. An analysis of replacing 80 acres of tomato production with low density residential development was studied and it was found that greater long run personal income would accrue to the region if this land remained in agricultural production. This analysis assumed that 108 houses built on this land would be a net temporary addition to the County's housing stock in 1979. In other words, it was assumed that the development would have occurred elsewhere in the region over the long run. What the results indicate is that the building of low density residential homes on agri- cultural land generates "tern orari 1 about $2 mi 11 ion in income to the region (direct and indirect -"--yII, However, over the long run the region could effectively lose an annual $303,000 in personal income due to the elimina- tion of agricultural production. Hence, at the end of about seven years the residential "one time" gain in the regional income is offset by the loss in agricultural income. - I 87 Once again, what this exanlple indicates is that it is likely that the everltuclI long run displacement of certain types of high yield agriculture with low density residential development will result in a net negative economic impact upon the region. Two critical factors must be considered: 1) the degree to which such developments would have occurred elsewhere in the region, and 2) as a corollary, the amount of agricultural land which is needed for residential development in order to accommodate population growth. If overall growth is constrained by not developing agricultural land, it follows that there might be negative impacts on jobs and income in the region. Therefore, in terms of economic criteria, the critical question which must be asked is as follows: What effect does limiting residential development on agricultural land have upon the absolute level of growth of jobs and income to the region? 3. When comparing a 1,000 job reduction in agricultural related employment versus a 1,000 job increase in wholesale and retail services, agriculture has a higher permanent "mu1 tip1 ier" effect. However, agriculture's loss does not have as high a multiplier as non-durable manufacturing. This information backs up the data uncovered in the development of the input-output model constructed by the University of California Extension Agricultural Service. While not the highest multiplier industry, agriculture certainly rates relatively high in multiplier effect locally. DETAILED RESULTS OF THE ECONOMIC IMPACT RUNS The tables below summarize the results of the economic impact computer runs. Table 22 shows the net economic impact of a 1,000 job gain in non-durable manufacturing and wholesale and retail services beginning in 1985 and continuing through 1995. Table 23 indicates the net economic loss of a 1,000 job reduction in agricultural related employment. Table 24 summarizes the employment sectors which would be affected by such gains/losses. Table 24 presents a synopsis of key economic indicators -- personal income per employee, average annual civilian payroll per employee, and the employment multiplier. All payroll and income figures are in millions of 1977 dollars and include direct and indirect effects. Employment figures are in actual numbers. /I TABLE 22 WHOLESALE AND RETAIL SERVICES DURABLE MANUFACTURING Personal Income $230.2 $324.3 C ivi 1 ian Payroll $23 1.6 $323.1 Civilian Jobs 1,779 2,076 88 TABLE 23 CUMULATIVE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF A 1,000 JOB LOSS IN AGRICULTURAL SERVICES AND PRODUCTION EMPLOYMENT (1985 -- 1995) Persona 1 income Civilian Payroll Civilian Jobs AGRICULTURAL SERVICES AND PRODUCTION -$228.7 -$243.6 -1,979 TABLE 24 KEY ECONOMIC INDICATORS AGRICULTURAL WHOLESALE AND NON-DURABLE SERV ICES AND RETA I L SERV I CES MANUFACTURING PRODUCTION Average Annual 'Personal $20,900 $29,418 $20,790 Income Per Employee Average Annual Civilian $2 1 ,054 $29,372 $22,145 Payroll per Employee Employment Multiplier 1 779 2.076 1.979 Construction Du rab 1 e Goods Non-Du rabl e Goods Transportation, Commun i cation, Uti1 ities Wholesale and Ec Finance, Insurance, Services Local Government All Other* TABLE 25 INDIRECT EMPLOYMENT IMPACTS WHOLESALE AND NON-DURABLE RETA I L SERV ICES MANU FACTU R I NG 209 (26.8) 268 (24.9) Retai 1 Services 45 ( 5.8) 82 ( 7.6) Real Estate 190 (24.4) 300 (27.8) 71 88 ( 8.2) i-Prirrrari ly includes state and federal government employment. AGR I CULTURAL SERV I CES AND PRODUCT I ON 35 ( 3.6) 15 ( 1.5) 60 ( 6.1) 243 (24.8) 98 (10.0) Based upon the results of these economic impact computer runs the following observations can be made: 1. The reason agricultural production and service employment shows a higher multiplier effect than wholesale retail service employment is that the pay- roll per employee of agricultural services jobs is higher than most employ- ment categories in wholesale and retail trades. Also, payroll per employee of agricultural production workers is higher than three of nine SIC codes defined in wholesale/retail trades. 2. It can be clearly seen that an increase or decrease in all three of these employment sectors primarily affects the wholesale, retail, and service trades. This phenomenon is typical in an urbanized economy and is reflec- tive of the employment emphasis in our local serving econamy. /c 90 3. The displacement of agricultural land with industrial (i.e., non-durable manufacturing) and commercial activities (wholesale, retai 1, service) is likely to have a positive economic impact upon the region. 4. The critical factor which must be considered in reviewing the conversion of agriculture to residential use is the degree to which any capital gains on the sale of lands generates any net investment within the County. Only to the degree that there is a shortage of loanable funds will such gains contribute to local economic activity. That is, capital gains do not. contribute substantially to any private sector economic activity unless there is: a) a shortage of funds for local investment and b) adequate demand and incentives for such reinvestment in the County. In other words, if the gains on the sale of land are reinvested in the County and add to economic activity, then this could offset agricultural production losses. METHODOLOGY The basic approach taken in this study was to simulate the economic impact of a 1,000-job increase in the following major sectors: non-durable manufacturing, and wholesale and retail services. Also, a 1,000-job decrease in local agri- cultural employment was analyzed. Each sector's SIC code classifications were shifted upward or downward in the DEFM model depending upon the proportion of 1977 employment in that SIC code category to total employment in a major category. For example, lumber and wood products had a total employment of 1,800 and durable - manufacturing an employment of 55,100 in 1977. Therefore, the amount of lumber and wood employment shifted was (1,800 7 55,100) X 1,000 = 33. What these economic impact runs indicate is the general employment/income impacts of shifts from jobs from one sector to another in San Diego. Another economic impact run was utilized to analyze the importance of agriculture to San Diego County. This case analyzed the economic effects of removing 80 acres of tomato production in North County to 108 homes being built on this land. The focus on this analysis is on the specific economic alternative uses of current agricultural land. The argument may be made that residential development on a piece of land represents a net transfer of growth from other areas of the County and thus there would be no net impact upon the region. However, in order to analyze the impacts of alternative uses of land it is necessary to make this assumption. This assumption does not change the basic results which are necessary for the analyses. In order to simulate these impacts it was necessary to calculate the loss in personal income to the region from removing 80 acres of tomato production. As the DEFM model was not designed to analyze this type of question, analyses were done independently of the model. This loss in personal income was calculated as fol lows: 1. Tomato sales per acre in 1977: $10,184 2. Personal income to the region for agricultural producers 7 Sales of Agri- cultural Producers (94,197,000 7 289,756,000) = -325 r 3. Sales per acre ($10,184) X ratio of sales to personal income f.325 x number of acres (80)] Annual personal income loss to the region ($264,784) 4. Type 1 income multiplier for agricultural producers: 1.47 5. Type 1 multiplier x personal income loss to the region = total annual direct and indirect income loss to the region = 1.147 x 264,784 = $303,707 These personal income figures for agricultural production were then compared for the "one-shot" increase of residential development calculated by the model. The results of this are found in the following section. A COMPARISON OF LOW DENSITY RESIDENTIAL DEVELOPMENT ON LAND PRODUCING TOMATOES As stated in the methodology section, a comparison was made of economic activity associated with tomato production on 80 acres of land versus building 108 homes during one year. Contained below is a summary of a three year economic impact of this residential conversion, the length of the period for this activity to fully filter through the economy. The table below illustrates the net economic impact at the end of each year for a - three year period. Rea Rea Net TABLE 26 NET IMPACT RESIDENTIAL DEVELOPMENT (In 1977 Dollars) YEAR 1' YEAR 2 YEAR 3 1 Personal Income $732,000 $1,041,000 $177,000 1 Civilian Payroll $788,000 $1,052,000 $ 41,000 Employment Difference 49 In the Region 74 13 As stated above, after Year 3 the economic model indicates that this development would not contribute to local economic activity. In fact, if this development represents an "overbuild" in Year 1, =economic activity could decline over time until the vacancy rates adjust to an overbuilding period. What the esti- mated structural relationships in the DEFM model are indicating is that unless there is a commensurate increase in employment opportunities in the region, a net addition in building activity in any one year in the County will be mirrored by levels of "underbuilding" in subsequent years. This occurs as the vacancy rate returns to an equilibrium level. f- 92 The table below illustrates the relative patterns of cumulative personal income to the region under these two hypothesized land use scenarios. TABLE 27 CUMULATIVE PERSONAL INCOME TO THE REGION RESIDENTIAL VERSUS AGRICULTURAL USE YEAR - RESIDENTIAL 732,000 AGR ICULTURAL $ 303,707 1 7773,000 $ 607,414 1,995,000 $ 911,121 1,995,000 $1,214,828 7 $2,125,949 - What this chart once again illustrates is that if low density residential devel- opment occurs on land which was previously under agricultural production, it is likely that in the short run residential development represents a short run posi- tive economic impact. However, in the long run the conversion of high yield agricultural land to low density residential developments results in a net nega- tive econbaic impact to the region. This occurs by the seventh year in this case. 93 PART V METHODS OF PRESERVING AGRICULTURE 94 CHAPTER 1 COMPENSATORY PROGRAMS FOR PRESERVING AGRICULTURE This chapter includes discussions of several methods of providing compensation to property owners whose land is restricted to agricultural use. The methods discussed are as follows: 1. Preferential property tax assessment; 2. Transfer of development rights; and 3. Purchase and lease-back. Compensatory programs such as these are capable of providing positive incentives for using land for agricultural purposes. The provision of some form of compen- sation to owners of land restricted to agricultural use may also be desirable as a means of mitigating adverse economic effects of governmental regulatory decisions. PREFERENTIAL PROPERTY TAX ASSESSMENT: THE WILLIAMSON ACT Introduction - Nationwide, one of the most popular methods of providing compensation to owners of land restricted to agricultural use is preferential property tax assessment. Commonly, land so restricted is assessed based not on its market value but on its value for agricultural uses. According to a 1977 report 42 states have "use-value" assessment programs for agricultural or other open-space lands. California's program was enacted in 1965 as the California Land Conservation Act, or Williamson Act. By 1976, 47 of California's 58 counties participated in the program, making it one of the most important in the United States. The Williamson Act permits participating counties in California to enter into contracts with owners of agricultural or open space land. The contracts restrict the use of the land and limit its potential for subdivision in exchange for a reduction in property tax. The contracts run for a period of ten years and are renewed automatically each year. The amount of the tax redcction is based on the difference between the agricultural value of the property and va 1 ue. i The County of San Diego has been an active participant in the Will program since 1369. The following table shows the total dollar va ia./ed each ,year by those property owners with lands under contract ts market amson Act ue of taxes 95 TABLE 28 TAX YEAR TAX SAVINGS The goals of 1. 2. 3. 1969-70 $ 204,612 1970-7 1 270,745 197 1-72 425,175 1972-73 727,009 1973-74 1,025,045 1974-75 1,280,753 1975-76 1,443,599 1976-77 1,663,008 1977-78 1,732,376 TOTAL $8,772,322 the Williamson Act are expressed within the Act itself, as follows: That the preservation of a maximum amount of the limited supply of agricultural land is necessary to the conserva- tion of the state's economic resources, and is necessary not only to the maintenance of the agricultural economy of the state, but also for the assurance of adequate, healthful, and nutritious food for future residents -of this state and nation; That the discouragement of premature and unnecessary conversion of agricultural land to urban uses is a matter of public interest, and will be of benefit to urban dwellers themselves, in that it will discourage discontiguous urban development patterns which unneces- sarily increase the cost of community services to community residents; That in a rapidly urbanizing society, agricultural lands have a definite public value as open space, and the preservation in agricultural production of such lands, the use of which may be limited under the provisions of this chapter, constitutes an important physical, social, esthetic, and economic asset to existing or pending urban or metropolitan development (Section 51220, California Government Code). - r These statements make it clear that the State legislature intended that the Act would be used to further land use planning goals of preserving agricultural land and containing urban sprawl, while providing open space to be used for agricul- ture. Let us examine the relationship between these goals and the actual use of the Williamson Act program in San Diego County. First, has it helped cause the preservation of a maximum amount of the limited supply of agricultural land in the County? The answer to this question depends on what is meant by "agricultural land." While "agricultural land" is not defined in the Act," prime agricultural land" is defined as follows: All land which qualifies for rating as Class I or Class I1 in the Soil Conservation Service land use capability classi- fications; Land which qualifies for rating 80 through 100 in the Storie Index Rating. Land which supports livestock used for the production capacity equivalent to at least one animal unit per acre as defined by the United States Department of Agr i cu 1 ture. Land planted with fruit- or nut-bearing trees, vines, bushes or crops which have a nonbearing period of less than five years and which wi 11 normally return during the commercial bearing period on an annual basis from the production of unprocessed agricultural plant pro- duct ion not less than two hundred dol lars ($200) per acre. Land which has returned from the production of unprocessed agricultural plant products an annual gross value of not less than two hundred dollars ($200) per acre for three of the previous five years. According to one source there are 192,300 acres of "prime" land in the County. Of this acreage, 9.1 percent, or 17,433 acres were under contract during the 1975-76 tax year. More recently, the San Diego County Assessor has reported that, for the 1978-79 tax year, there are 20,807 acres of prime agricultural land under contract out of a total of 135,679 acres under contract. Thus, only I5 percent of the land in the County now under contract is prime agricultural 1 and. 97 Second, has the Will iamson Act program in San Dieyo County helped contain urban - sprawl? To answer this question one must analyze the spatial distribution of the lands under contract. A map showing the location of all contract lands reveals that most of the contract lands lie far to the east of the urbanized areas of San Diego County. The lands under contract lying within or near urban areas are relatively smaller and discontiguous in comparison to the vast tracts in the more remote areas. The overall effect of these contracts on the spatial characteristics of urban growth would appear to be minor. One reason for the present spatial distribution of lands under contract is the voluntary nature of the Williamson Act program. The law provides for the County to establish agricultural preserves for the purpose of identifying which lands should be eligible for contracts. However, the County has never attempted to establish agricultural preserves for the purpose of keeping agricultural land from being urbanized unless the owner desired to sign a Land Conservation Contract. In general, the County has only established preserves in response to the expressed desires of landowners to sign contracts. Cxceptions to this policy have occurred only in the more remote areas of the County. Thus almost all of the land within agricultural preserves but not under contract is located far from any urbanizing areas. The agricultural preserves that do exist near urban areas are generally coterminous with the boundaries of land under contract. Third, has the Williamson Act program served to foster agricultural production on agricultural lands? The answer to this question can be approached by analyz- ing what lands are under contract. This analysis wi 11 show who the beneficiaries are of the Williamson Act in San Diego County. Once the beneficiaries are known, - one can attempt to evaluate the extent to which the tax benefits of the Williamson Act appear to foster actual agricultural production. The following questions are asked as the basis for this analysis: 1. How many acres of land devoted to particular agricultural activities are under contract? 2. How much of the total annual tax savings under the County's Williamson Act program supports each agricultural activity? 3. What is the average percentage of tax savings by agricultural activity? The answer to the first of these questions is found in the table below, as reported by the San Diego County Assessor as of March 1, 1978. TABLE 29 AGRICULTURAL ACTIVITY ACREAGE % OF TOTAL Grazing and Dry Farwing 122,217 88.2 Tree Crops 10,127 7.3 I rrigated Crops 2,346 1.7 Flowers 1,108 .8 0 ther ( i nc 1 udes open space easements) 2,807 2.0 TOTAL 138,605 100.0 98 . Note that 88.2 percent of the total acreage under contract is classified as land for grazing or dry farming. The answers to the second and third questions appear in the next table, which provides an analysis by agricultural activity of the tax savings enjoyed by owners of land under contract during the tax year 1977-78. These figures are based on the County Auditor and Controller's Agricultural Preserve Inventory of November 22, 1977. TABLE 30 AVERAGE 2 AGRl CULTURAL TAX SAVING ACTIVITY TAX SAVING % OF TOTAL TO OWNER r Graz i ng $1,083,890 63% 80% Tree Crops 336,178 19% 42% Flowers 180,442 10% 61% Irrigated Crops 46,626 3% 7 4% Dry Farming 39,101 2% 63% Open Space Easements 21,835 1% 76% Dairies 19,302 1% 66% TOTAL $1,727,374 The answers to these three questions clearly show that by far the principal beneficiaries of the Williamson Act in San Diego County are the owners of grazing land. Grazing is the most predominant agricultural activity under contract; owners of grazing land receive 63 percent of the total tax savings in San Diego County from the Williamson Act program; grazing results in the highest percentage tax savings of all the agricultural activities. Thus it appears that, in San Diego County, the Williamson Act program has provided the strongest incentives for owners of grazing land to sign Land Conservation Contracts. This relative emphasis of the program on grazing would make more sense if livestock made up an important segment of this County's ayri- cultural production. However, as shown in the table below, out of a gross value of $335 million in agricultural sales in 1977, only $5.8 million was derived from cattle and calves. These figures are reported in the 1977 Agricultural Crop Report prepared by the County Department of Agriculture. 99 TABLE 31 CROP PERCENT OF DOLLAR VALUE TOTAL VALUE Toma toes Eggs Avocados Milk Valencia Oranges Strawberries Lemons Carnations (Standard) Cattle and Calves $63,332,000 51,408,000 24,701,000 7,721,000 6,634,000 5,824,000 50,058,000 17,830,000 5,854,000 18.9% 15.3 14.9 7.4 5.5 2.3 2.0 1.7 1.7 Cattle and calves were the ninth most valuable agricultural conmodity in 1977, comprising only 1.7 percent of the value of all agricultural comnlodities. Signi,ficant also is the fact that the signing of a Land Conservation Contract in no way obligates the owner to use any of his land for agricultural purposes. The owner may enjoy his tax break without producing an agricultural commodity. The contract provides disincentives and restrictions on nonagricultural uses, rather than positive incentives for agricultural use. The discussions above lead to the conclusion that, in San Diego County, the Williamson Act program does not appear to have been encouraging owners of land suitable for the production of the County's most important agricultural commodi- ties to sign Land Conservation Contracts. One might yet, however, conclude that the program has, in accordance with the third goal of the Williamson Act itself, fostered the agricultural use of open space land by discouraging nonagricultural use of grazing land. However, one could hardly argue that this has been the most efficient or productive use of the County's investment in the Williamson Act program. Effect of Proposition 13 on the Williamson Act Program It must also be noted that the Williamson Act program, like many others, will be significantly affected by Proposition 13, the Jarvis-Gann property tax initiative. As the discussion below demonstrates, the property tax savings incentive for signing or renewing a Willianlson Act contract will be greatly reduced by Proposi- tion 13. In some cases, the tax savings formerly attributable to the Wil liamson Act contract may now be exceeded by the savings attributable to Proposition 13 even if no contract is signed. 100 c This discussion will compare various examples to show the difference made by the passage of Proposition I3 on the tax savings resulting froti1 signing a Williatl~son Act contract. Each example below is computed on a per acre basis for a typical mature avocado orchard in Valley Center. Estimates of market values, restricted or agricultural .values, and tax rates were received from personnel from the County Assessor's Off ice. Market Value (typical) $7,500 $1 5,000 Restricted Value (typical) $6,000 $ 6,000 How taxes were computed before Proposition 13 -- Had Proposition 13 not passed, 1978 property taxes would have been computed by multiplying the tax rate times the assessed value of the property. In Examples 1 and 2 a typical tax rate for Valley Center was selected equal to $.lo28 per dollar of assessed value. In Example 1 the assessed value is equal to one-quarter of the "restricted" or agricultural use value of the land under Williamson Act contract. Example 1 -- 1978 tax per acre on land not under contract had Proposition 13 not passed : - r Tax = (Tax Rate) (Assessed Value) = = (Tax Rate) (Market Value) = 4 Example 2 -- I978 tax per acre on land under contract had Proposition 13 not passed : - Tax = (Tax Rate) (Restricted Assessed Value) = = (Tax Rate) (Restricted Value) = -4 = (. 1028) ($6 000) = $1 54.20/acre 4 How taxes are computed under Proposition 13 -- Under Proposition 13, property taxes shall be levied at no more than one percent of the full 1975 property value, adjusted annually by a two percent 'inflation rate, as shown below: 1978 property tax = .01 (1975 full value) (l.U2I3 F where .01 is the one percent tax rate and (1 .02)3 represents three years of inflation at a rate of two percent. 101 If ownership of the property has changed since 1375, the tax shall be no more than one percent of its full value at the time of sale, adjusted annually by the two percent inflation rate. Example 3 -- 1978 tax on land not under contract but according to Proposition 13: - Tax = (.01) (1975 Market Value) (2% inflation for 3 years) = (.01) ($7,500) (l.O2l3 = $79.59/acre . How taxes are computed under Proposition 13 for property under Williamson Act contract -- Property under Williamson Act (California Land Conservation Act) contract will be taxed based on its 1975 agricultural or "restricted" value, adjusted by the two percent inflation rate, as shown below: . 1978 property tax = .01 (1975 restricted value) (1.02) 3 For property now under contract but not under contract in 1975, the tax is computed based on the restricted value at the time of sale, adjusted for infla- t ion. Example 4 -- 1978 tax on land under contract according to Proposition 13: Tax = (-01) (1975 Restricted Value) (2% inflation for 3 years) = = (-01) ($6,000) (l.02)3 = $63.67/acre Summary of Examples -- 1978 tax per acre avocado land, if : 1. No Proposition 13 and no contract - $385.50 2. No Proposition 13 but under contract - $154.20 3. Proposition 13 but no contract - $79.59 4. Proposition 13 and under contract - $63.67 The most important effect on the Williamson Act program will be the apparent reduction in incentive for property-owners to enter into new contracts. The incentive will be reduced because the dollar value of tax savings resulting from the contract will be greatly reduced. The effect of Proposition 13 on, for example, acreage planted in avocados but not under contract would be to reduce taxes by as much as 80 percent. This savings is based on the approximately 60 percent reduction in tax rate coupled with the fact that 1975 property value may be only 50 percent of 1978 property value. Signiny a contract now should still result in a tax savings to the property owner. However, the dollar amount of that tax savings may seen1 insiynificant relative to that amount saved solely because of Proposition 13. 4 Another possible effect of Proposition 13 may be increased numbers of property Owners with lands now under contract deciding not to renew their contracts. When property owners decide not to renew, each year for ten years they pay an -. 102 increasing percentage of what would have been their taxes had their land not been under contract. Under Proposition 13, these yearly payments will be based on the full 1975 value, adjusted for inflation by only two percent per year. These payments will be considerably less than they would have been without Proposition 13 because the tax rate has been reduced by approximately 60 percent and the two percent inflation rate is far below the actual inflation rate for property value. A further possible effect of Proposition 13 on the Williamson Act proyram may be to increase the number of petitions for outright cancellation of contracts. The Board of Supervisors may cancel a contract at the owner's request and impose a cash penalty equal to 12-1/2 - 25 percent of the "full cash value of the land as though it were free of contractual restriction" (Section 51283, Government Code; see a 1 so Board of Supervisors Pol icy 1-30). Before Propos i t ion I3 was passed, this "full cash value" meant market value. Now it means 1975 market value adjusted at only a two percent inflation rate. Since market value has been increasing at a much higher rate than two percent, as each year goes by the maximum dollar value of the cancellation penalty becomes less and less an effective disincentive to petition the Board of Supervisors for a contract cancellation. Already since the passage of Proposition 13, one property owner has successfully petitioned the Board of Supervisors for a cancellation. Conclusion The following conclusions can be made from the above discussion: F- 1. In the last nine years, the Williamson Act has provided tax savings of over $8.7 million to owners of contract lands. 2. Only 15 percent of the land under contract meets the definitions of Prime agricultural land. 3. Contract lands are most likely to be located far from urban areas and suitable only for grazing, a relatively unimportant segment of our agricul- tura 1 economy. 4. The passage of Proposition 13 significantly reduces the incentive for entering into or continuing a Land Conservation Contract. Thus, it seems that the Williamson Act program in San Diego County has been of limited public value relative to the goals of the Act itself. The program has not been especially effective as a means of effecting the Act's land use planniny goals of preserving agricultural land or containing urban sprawl. The open space preserved through the program has, by and large, not been land suitable for highly productive agricultural use or subject to the pressures of urban growth. In the future, the program will probably be even less successful because the limitations on the property tax reduce the incentives to partici- pate in the program. It is likely that the program now provides highest incentives for owners of land unsuitable for any use at all to enter into or continue contracts which provide them with an 80 percent tax reduction. 1 03 TRANSFER OF DEVELOPMENT R I GHTS Another method of providing compensation to owners of land restricted to agri- cultural use is a proposed system known as "transfer of development rights,'' or TDR. The Frinciple on which TDR is based is that land ownership may be considered to consist of the title to various rights. One of the normal rights of ownership is the right to develop or improve property. Under TDR, this right is separated from the other rights of ownership and may be purchased by others. Under one type of development rights transfer, a governmental agency would purchase development rights of land the agency desired not to be developed. This kind of program is often called PDR, "purchase of development rights." Except for this case, TDR involves the establishment of a market for development rights to be sold by owners of land planned - not to be developed to Owners of land planned for development. Thus, governmental actions to restrict the development of certain lands would not necessarily have their usual effect of lowering the value of the owner's invest- ments in those lands. A portion of those investments would consist of the devel- opment rights, the sale of which would provide compensation to the owners of lands restricted from development. In order to set up a TDR program for the purpose of restricting certain lands to agricultural use, the governmental jurisdiction managing the program would designate sites for agricultural preservation and for development and would issue certificates of development rights. Each owner would receive certificates based on some equit- able principle of distribution. One system would be to issue certificates corres- - ponding to the maximum number of dwelling units each Owner might have been permitted prior to the adoption of the plan to be implemented by the TDR proposal. Then owners of developable land would be required to purchase development rights from the Owners of undevelopable land in order to develop their land at more than a minimum intensity. According to David L. Peterson, fiscal and economic consultant to the Regional Growth Ma~agement project, transfer of development rights has both advantages and disadvantages as a technique of plan implementation, as listed below: Advantages 1. Consistent with established constitutional princ 2. More politically acceptable than public acquisit without compensation. iples. ion or stringent zoning 3. Minor expenditure of public funds. 4. A1 leviates "windfalls" and "wipeouts"; promotes equity. 5. Flexibility; can protect any resource from market forces. Disadvantages 1. Too new and complex. 2. Will not work without proper economic conditions. 1 04 3- 4. 5. 6. 7. E. 9. He Would take years to study and implement. May not work unless adopted regionally. Requires significant political committment to be credible to would-be participants. Ends may be more efficiently accomplished through less complex mechanisms. May conflict with existing zoning and plans. Involves administrative and bookkeeping problems. Involves questions of property taxation of development rights. concludes his discussion of TDR as follows: TDR is a complex implementation technique which would not be easily under- stood by the general public, the development industry, and local decision- makers. TDR would require a significant administrative structure with associated costs. TDR shares, with density bonuses, the problem that it is relatively easy to identify areas from which to take rights, but it is more difficult to identify areas to which rights would be transferred. Further, such transfers could reduce the effectiveness of existing Community Plans as well as create problems in capital facilities and service delivery planning. . . .[E]xtensive use of the technique seems premature at this time. It would seem wiser to let others experiment, and to hold general use of TDR in reserve for possible future application. The Arroyo Group, consultant for the City of Riverside, California, recently prepared a document entitled "TDR: An Evaluation of the Potential for Utilizing the Transfer of Development Rights as a Means for Implementation of the Arlington Heights Plan and Growth Management Program." This report proposes that TDR be used in the Arlington Heights area for the following reasons: 1. To ensure greater equity for property owners by eliminating or minimizing windfalls and wipeouts, and 2. As a means of acquiring or preserving public open spaces and environmental resources. This consultant's proposal includes draft enabling legislation and a city ordinance. Enabling legislation may be necessary for a number of reasons, as listed below: 1. So that developnlent rights can be considered estates in real property which can be transfered, recorded, and insured; F 2. So that land will be assessed for tax purposes based on the density and type of use permitted after development rights transfer; 3. To permit local agencies to require the recordation of TDR certificates to evidence the existence and transfer of development rights. PURCHASE At4D LEASE-BACK The unincorporated area of San Diego County has approximately 113,000 acres of land in agricultural production. The bulk of this land lies in four areas: Fallbrook (14,003 - 13%), North County Metro and San Dieguito (25,593 - 23%), Valley Center (24,104 - 21%), and Otay (13,695 - 12%). Clearly, many of the lands in these areas will be subject to future urban development pressure and thus any attempt to preserve this agricultural land via purchase and lease-back, etc., would be quite costly. This paper will examine the financing methods and costs of preserving agricultural lands. Based upon post Proposition 13 revenue constraints and the methods available, the following is a summary of the feasi- bility of preserving agricultural land via its acquisition. 0 Essentially, given the revenue constraints at the Federal, State, and local level and the market price of agricultural land in San Diego County, it is highly impractical to attempt to preserve agricultural land in this County primarily via acquisition. 0 An estimate was made of the cost of purchasing agricultural land. The price tag of such a purchase could well exceed 600 mil lion dollars at today's market prices. Obviously, such an ambitious effort is beyond the scope of government. The point, however, is that =attempt to purchase agricultural land in San Diego County would involve a massive sum of money. As a corollary, this acquisition would entail foregoing other services and revenue (property taxes) by local governments. 0 The number and flexibility of financial mechanisms available to the County of San Diego to purchase agricultural land is very limited. There are no funds currently existing at the Federal and State level avai lable for direct purchase. At the local level, it appears that the purchase of agricultural land by a nonprofit corporation, leasing this land to the County, and in turn having the County sublease to the grower-tenant is the most practical method at this point in time. It is likely that under such a scheme that the County of San Diego would have to subsidize lease payments; the amount depending on which agricultural land was purchased. That is, the market value of existing agricultural land. and associated debt service costs are likely to be less than market rates. Any deficiency between revenues and costs are likely to be funded in the capital irnprovenlent budget. 1 06 0 The issuance of general ob1 igation and revenue bonds by The County of San Diego appears infeasible. General obligation bonds have been virtually eliminated as a result of Proposition 13. According to a financial consultant to the County (Terry Comerford, Blythe, Eastrnan, and Dillion), issuance of revenue bonds directly by County of San Diego is questionnable due to potential lease revenue being insufficient to cover debt services. Likewise a joint powers agreement is not viable, as these interjurisdictional contracts are designed for building or improvement oriented activities. A development fee for an "open space agricultural" fund is probably not legal'. This is due to the fact that fees must be directly tied to benefits to the development. Finally, a special assessment district approach (i.e., City of San Diego's open space requisition bonds) would be difficult in the era of post Proposi- tion 13 revenue constraints and, according to this municipal financial consultant, subject to legal challenges. 0 In summary, the large quantity of agricultural acreage coupled with the high market price of this land and the revenue constraints in the post Proposition 13 era make it virtually impossible to preserve agricultural land via its acquisition. At best, it appears that the use of a private nonprofit corporation approach may be feasible as a minor supplement to other more ambitious methods (density zoning, etc.). METHODOLOGY 7 Explained below is the method for calculating the market value of agricultural land in San Diego County. Admittedly, it is somewhat crude. However, to derive a "true" value of agricultural land in San Diego County would involve a farm by farm appraisal; a quite costly effort. The attempt in this study is to provide a rough value of agricultural land at today's market prices. This value, in many cases, is likely to be above what the land is worth for purely agricultural production. In other words, much of the agricultural land in San Dieyo County is valued for nonagricultural uses. This price of agricultural land by planning Subregion was computed via two steps. Step one was to "inflate" the most recent information on land infla- tion by the most current acreage market value data from the Assessor's property information system. The only information which could be discovered on the inflation rate of land was the average increase in the price of existing single family homes in I978 by those of 1977. This assumes, naturally, that land value is the sole cause for home price increases from 1977 to 1978. While not entirely true, it is a good "ballpark" estimate. Between 1978 and 1977 the average price of an existing single family home in San Diego County increased by 31% (May 1978, Chamber of Commerce Economic Bulletin). This 31% inflation rate was applied to the Assessor's estimate of average market value per acre for all land in a planning subregion in 1977. Clearly, this implies that land would be purchased at highest and best use value. In summary, acreage in production figures were multiplied by I977 Assessor's market value and in turn inflated at 31%. The following table summarizes this calcula- tion: - I TABLE 32 MARKET VALUE AGRICULTURAL LAND -_ PLANNING AREA Pendleton-DeLuz Fa 11 brook Bonsa 1 1 North County Metro San D iegu i to Pala Pauma Valley Center 0 tay P owa y Ramona Ra i n bow Lakes i de ACREAGE IN PRODUCT I ON 2280 14803 7829 20392 520 1 9205 241 04 13695 2592 8720 1715 1154 CURRENT MARKET VALUE (In Millions) $ 4.1 166.4 47.8 124.5 95.6 14.5 92.2 20.4 26.1 27.3 6.0 7.7 TOTAL 11 1690 632.6 Obviously, not all of the land in these areas would be even considered for preservation due to small lot sizes, etc. The point, however, is that such an effort would be quite costly. As can be seen, the total estimated market value of this agricultural land is in the neighborhood of 663 million dollars. This amounts to an average market value per acre of $5,664. As mentioned earlier, possibly revenue bonds could be issued by a private nonprofit corporation to purchase part of this agricultural land. In today's market such revenue bonds are issued typically for 25 years at 7 percent interest. Related to this approach, the table below illustrates the impact on County government of the following scenarios: O The purchase of 10 million dollars worth of agricultural land in 1979 at an overall average purchase price of $5,664 per acre (the computed average). This amounts to the purchase of 1,766 acres of agricultural acres in production; or 1.6 percent of the total acres in the County. It is assumed that the bonds are issued at 7 percent for 25 years. This amounts to an annual debt service of $858,100. O Lease rates begin at an annual $150 per acre and are escalated at 10% per year. The financing "scheme" is one in which a nonprofit corporation leases to the County of San Diego and in turn the County subleases to the grower- tenant. Any difference between debt service cost and lease reYenue is financed via the capital improvement budget. The term deficit refers to this capital fund figure. 108 YEAR 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 TOTAL - - TABLE 33 TEN FISCAL IMPACTS OF FINANCING AGRICULTURAL LAND VIA ACQUISITION 10 YEARS (IN ACTUAL NOMINAL DOLLARS) DEBT SERVICE COST $ 858, lOOh 858,100 858,100 858,100 858, I 00 858,100 858,100 585,100 858,100 858,100 $ 8,581,000 LEASE REVENUE $ 264,900 291,390 321,412 353,200 388,520 427,372 469,756 515,672 568,652 625,164 $4,226,038 DEFICIT $ 593,200 566,710 536,688 504,900 469,580 430,728 388,344 342,428 289,448 232,936 $4,354,962 The implication of the data and analysis in this section leads to the following conclusions: 1. 2. 3. .- Even under what appears to be the most feasible financial alternative, the private nonprofit corporation approach, the County of San Diego could end up "subsidizing" agricultural production. Bearing in mind that the table in this section amounts to less than a modest 2 percent purchase of agricultural lands in production, an even more ambitious approach would naturally incur substantial costs to County .JfJ'mrnfrlent arid would 1 ikely cause the elinlination of potential Capital improvermnt projects. In addition, the County would be el inlinating SOUI-C~S of property tax revenue. There are, however, two apparent advantages to such an approach. First of all, if the agricultural land is thought of as open space, then the County's nonprofit corporation could gain functional open space and, unlike most open space, receive revenue from it. Secondly, a substantial profit could pass to the County if future proceeds from the sale of the agricultural land reverted to the County. CHAPTER 2 REGULATORY METHODS FOR PRESERVING AGRICULTURE LARGE-LOT ZONING Large-lot zoning is probably the most common technique used in this country for the preservation of open space. Wherever land is not proposed for urban uses, that land is likely to be subject to large-lot zoning. This technique operates by directly affecting the process of dividing land. When land subject to large- lot zoning is subdivided, new lots can be made no smaller than some minimum size. How large this minimum standard must be for it to be considered "large-lot zoning" depends on the circumstances. In some situations, a 10,000 square foot lot size requirement may be considered "large." In another case, 600 acres may be the size of the large lots required. The theory behind the use of large-lot zoning is that the private land subject to it will be more likely to remain as open space if it is not divided into small lots. Where the desired open space use is agriculture, then larye-lot zoning is often imposed in the hope that either the land will not be subdivided at all or that new lots will be large enough for agricultural use. Theoretically, the imposition of large-lot zoning will, prevent the speculative value of land from rising so much above its agricultural value that agriculture can no longer be considered a permanent economic use. - Large-lot zoning is now the principal technique used in San Dieyo County to preserve land for agricultural use. It is now imposed by three different means -- by The Zoning Ordinance, by the General Plan, and by Williamson Act Contract. In the past, The County Zoning Ordinance contained four types of large-lot zones -- estate zones, agricultural zones, temporary zones, and the limited control zone. These zones provided for minimum lot sizes ranging from one-half acre to twenty acres. The newly adopted County Zoning Ordinance provides for the applica- tion of any minimum lot size standard desired. This may be accomplished by apply- ing the desired lot size designation at the time zoning is adopted or revised on a particular property. For example, under the old Zoning Ordinance the agricultural zones of the County provided a choice of only five different minimum lot sizes -- 1/2, 1, 2, 4, or 8 acres. Under the new Zoning Ordinance, the County has available the legal machinery needed to expand the range of possible minimum lot sizes from these few to any size desired. What this means is that the County need no longer create and adopt new zones in order to impose new and different lot size require- ments. The County General Plan, since 1975, has included minimum lot size standards over and above those required by The Zoning Ordinance. Land not planned for urban use may be subject to minimum lot sizes ranging from one to forty acres depending on slope, access, water availability, and other criteria. Land designated, for example, as "Intensive Agriculture" may have minimum lot size standards of 2, 4, or 8 acres depending on certain criteria. 110 The table on the following page shows the acres of land in agricultural use for each land use planning category of the County General Plan. Note that the three categories with the most acreage -- Rural Residential, Agricultural Estates - Medium, and Intensive Agriculture -- all permit lots as small as two acres. Together these three categories contain 52.5 percent of the land in the County in agricultural production. Other figures of note are that more than 11 percent of the land in agricultural use is now planned for urban use; almost 28 pe'rcent is planned in categories that permit lots as small as one acre; and almost 69 percent is planned in categories permitting lots as small as two acres. The significance of this analysis lies in the possible loss of agricultural production that may result from the implementation of the County General Plan. If the General Plan is implemented in a way such that land in the County is divided into the minimum-sized lots permitted in each land use category, then many areas now in agricultural use will be divided into lots of two acres or smaller. Dividing land into lots this small may result in reduced agricultural production. Owners of small lots may choose to take all or part of their land out of production in order to substitute residential uses or simply because not enough money can be made to make farming worthwhile. TABLE 34 P Board of Supervisors' Policy 1-38, "Agricultural Preserves,'' also contains minimum lot size standards for land under Land Conservation (Williamson Act) Contract. These minimums depend on the agricultural activity and have ranged from 8 to 600 acres. The largest minimum lot size standard now imposed by Policy 1-38 is 80 acres, as shown in the table below. Grazing Dry Farming Cattle Breeding Horse Breed i ng Pou 1 try Dairies Tree Crops Truck Crops Flowers (Field) Flowers (Hothouse) 80 acres 40 acres 40 acres 40 acres IO acres 20 acres 10 acres 10 acres 10 acres 10 acres Large-lot zoning has a number of important advantages over other methods of agri- cultural preservation. The most important of these is that it is a regulatory technique based solely on the police power of the state. Thus, it requires no direct expenditures by government other than the costs of administering the program. Aside from being inexpensive, the technique is easy to understand, relatively easy to administer, legally sound, and politically acceptable. Its legality and acceptability are, however, subject to the limitation that the standards imposed are reasonable. /I 111 I TABLE 35 MAX I MUM PERM I TTED ACRES OF LAND IN LAND USE CATEGORY DENSITY AGRICULTURAL USE % OF TOTAL Urban Categories Very Low Residential Medium Low Residential Low Residential Low Medium Residential Medium Residential High Medium Residential Medium High Residential High Residential Office Commercial Neighborhood Commercial General Commercial Heavy Industrial Nonurban Categories Rural Residential Agricultural Estates - Low Agricultural Estates - Med. Agricultural Estates - Rural Agricultural Preserves Intensive Agriculture Mountain Development Multiple Rural Use National Forest Other Categories Floodplain Open Space Public, Semipublic Greenbelt Special Planning Area TOTALS Urban Nonu r ban Other GRAND TOTAL 1 du/ac 2 du/ac 2.9 du/ac 4.3 du/ac 7.3 du/ac 10.9 du/ac 14.5 du/ac 29 du/ac - - - - 1 du/1,2,4 ac 1 du/4 ac 1 du/2 ac 1 du/2-4 ac 1 du/8 ac 1 du/2,4,8 ac 1 du/4,8,20 ac 1 du/4,8 ac 1 du/4,8,20 ac 1 du/4-8 ac 1 du/8 ac - - (various) 1-25 du/ac 1 du/l-20 ac (various) - 1,2 12 2,748 1,04 1 467 7,364 39 153 72 8 15 80 207 18,982 1,173 22,286 5,564 13,327 20,104 7,703 6,370 68 1 3,552 428 628 265 2,278 13,412 96,190 7,151 116,753 1.03 2.35 0.89 0.39 6.30 0.03 0. I3 0.06 0.07 0.01 0.06 0.17 16.25 1 .oo 19.08 4.76 11.41 17.21 6.59 5.45 0.58 - 3.04 0.36 0.53 0.22 1.95 11.48 82.38 6.12 112 c There are also a number of important disadvantages to the use of larye-lot zoning as,a means of preserving agricultural land. Probably the most important of these are the problems of establishing large enough minimum lot size standards and then maintaining them over time. Another disadvantage is that large-lot standards are difficult politically to impose when their effect will be to lower the value of private investments in land. Even when such standards are imposed, the rationale for their imposition may often be based on their temporary nature. For example, in this County, a minimum lot size standard of twenty acres was applied by Zoning Ordinance only when that ordinance was explicitly intended to be temporary. In addition, the imposition of large-lot zoning may have serious unintended economic effects when the land is owned by the same party who farms it. In some cases, the owner-farmer is able to continue his agriculfural acti- vities because of the rising value of his land investment. More stringent minimum lot size standards may lower this value, making it more difficult for the owner to obtain mortgage money that he may need to finance his agricultural pursuits. The ability to sell off small portions of the property may also provide the owner with an important source of capital he may need for continuing agricultural production. A further disadvantage of using large-lot zoning as a means of preserving agri- culture is that the mere threat of its imposition, whether real or imagined, may influence owners of agricultural land not to continue ayricultural uses. There is some evidence that this built-in disincentive for agriculture may - already be functioning in San Diego County. Landowners in at least one area have apparently stopped leasing their land for agricultural use because they fear that the evidence of such use will be a factor in the County's decisions to impose more stringent land use controls. Owners who would normally gain from the temporary agricultural use of their property have become willing to forgo that gain. This effect of the threat of large-lot zoning seems to have the most impact on our vegetable crops and field flowers. However, more permanent agri- cultural uses, such as orchards and greenhouses, may also have already been affected in this way. It should be noted that the present minimum lot size criteria for the "Intensive Agriculture" land use category of the County General Plan provides incentives for using land for agriculture. If land has been planted for the previous year in certain crops, and some other criteria are met, then the land may be considered for 2 rather than 4-acre lots. This offer of a smaller minimum lot size may serve as a counter-balance to the disincentive to agricultural use discussed a hove. "Poi n t s Sys tem" Zon i ne Tulare County in California has established a comprehensive program of large-lot zoning where any requests for smaller lot zoning are evaluated by a detailed rating system. The purpose of this rating system is to provide explicit guide- lines for decision-makers to use in considering making exceptions to the overall policy of preserving agriculture by means of large-lot zoning. Thus, Tulare County's large-lot zoning program includes criteria for flexibility. Where land smaller lot zoning may be granted. ,- is less suitable for long-term agriculture, then, if certain criteria are met, The Tulare County rating system works as follows. If land zoned for large lots is not within an agricultural preserve (Will iamson Act) and is sui table for an individual waste disposal system, then points are awarded based on to what extent the property meets thirteen different criteria. In all, thirty points may be awarded for such features as soil classification, parcel size, land use, proximity to certain uses, water availability, fire protection, road access, historical or archaeological value, wildlife habitats, unique natural features, and floodplains. The more points awarded, the more suitable the land is for agriculture. A low score, however, would provide the basis for deciding to rezone the property to permit smaller lot sizes. The most valuable feature of the Tulare County program is the explication of the factors to be considered in the decision-making process. Too often land use planning decisions are made on an arbitrary, inconsistent, or unclear basis. Getting a policy adopted which contains in great detail the criteria for decision- making would be a great step toward improving the credibility of the land use planning process. Explicit criteria, if adhered to, make planning regulations seem more objective and fair to the affected landowners. Another interesting feature of the Tulare County large-lot zoning program is the inverse relationship between suitability for agriculture and permitted minimum lot size. Ten-, 20-, 40-, and 80-acre minimum lot sizes are imposed for agricultural preservation. The most productive land is zoned for 10-acre minimums, the least, for 80-acre minimums. The rationale for this inverse relationship is that more land is needed to run a profitable agricultural enterprise on less productive land. There are some apparent, but possibly minor, drawbacks to the Tulare County "points" system. First, it would probably be difficult to prepare a compre- hensive rating system for San Diego County's agricultural lands that could work throughout the County. Our County seems much more diverse in character than does Tulare and, therefore, might require an even more complicated'rating system for it to be expected to work rationally. Second, any complicated rating system requires a certain amount of administrative effort to make it work. A system complex enough to be justifiable might be too complicated to administer effi- ciently. DENSITY ZONING Density zoning is a commonly-used alternative to standard large-lot zoning. The "quarter/quarter'' and "s1 iding scale'' techniques discussed below, are forms of density zoning. With density zoning, the regulations determine how many lots may be created out of a particular parcel. The emphasis is on the number of lots, not on their size. For example, a density zone of one lot per 10 acres, when applied to a 100 acre site, would result in 10 lots. For the purpose of preserving agriculture, it might be best if nine of these lots were 1-acre homesites, and the remaining 91-acre lot were kept in agricultural use. Under standard large-lot zoning, as used in this County, the 100-acre lot would be divided into ten, 10-acre lots. Where a particular agricultural enterprise on the 100-acre site requires more land than 10 acres to be profitable, it is likely that the division into I0-acre lots will result in a significant loss in production. Thus standard large-lot zoning may cause the subdivision of agricultural land into lots not large enough for continued agricultural production. 114 The following diagram shows thc difference in the ultilnatt' lot pat terns that may result from the subdivision of a 100-acre parcel into ten lots under standard large-lot zoning and under density zoning. The desirability of density zoning as an agricultural preservation technique is limited by the possibility that the creation of small lots, however few, for residential purposes will result in land use conflicts. Living next to a farm may seem idyllic to some, but pesticides, fertilizer, smudge pots, noisy machinery, flies, and noisy or smelly farm animals may prove to be unanticipated drawbacks. Complaints from rural residents may be an important factor in the farmer's decision to consider nonagricultural use of his land. Such complaints may include threatened legal action or result in investigations by County authorities. In addition, the encouragement of a land use pattern of non-farm residences as school bus transportation. 1 scattered throughout rural areas may result in a high public cost for such services Dens i ty Zoning wi th Open Space Easements Density zoning has been used in this County in some specialized situations: The most common of these has been in the granting of special use permits for Planned Residential Developments (PRD's). PRD's are condominium subdivisions, where small building lots are sold individually and one or more large lots are for all of them to own and enjoy. Condominium ownership arrangements have also been used in standard subdivisions to provide for the ownership of open space lots. Often these open space lots are created to protect very steep land from being developed. The open space lot is protected from resubdivision by an open space easement granted to the County by the original subdivider. Such an ease- ment, in effect, transfers the right to develop the property to the County. The owners of the residential lots then jointly own the open space lot. rc sold in common to the residents to provide open space and recreational areas Condominium ownership of an open space lot does not seem appropriate or necessary when such a lot is suitable for agricultural use. Even with a restrictive open space easement on the property, it could be retained by the original owner for continued agricultural use, or sold for this purpose. One problem this County has faced with open space lots has been the failure of owners to make mortgage payments or pay property taxes. Foreclosure can result in loss of the open space easement restrictions. Therefore any program to retain large lots in agricultural use by means of open space easements must be devised with this possible pitfall in mind. Another probleln to be solved regarding density zoning is how to encourage sub- dividers to use it. If the Owner has the choice, he may prefer the nwre standard approach of subdividing land into large lots of equal size, In order to assure the retention of a large lot reserved for agricultural purposes, it may be necessary to make this approach mandatory. Otherwise other inducements may have to be offered, such as a density bonus or eventual expiration of the open year or longer periods.) c space easement. (State law allows open space easements to be yranted for 20 Large-Lot Zoning Original 1 OO- Ac re Parce 1 IO New 1 O-Acre Lots Original 100-Acre Pa rce 1 Density Zoning New 9 1 -Acre Lot 9 New One-Acre Lots 116 - Quarter/Quarter Zoning Quarter/quarter zoning is a special kind of density zoning technique used in some counties in Minnesota. This technique permits a certain number of small lots to be located within each quarter of a quarter of a section of land. A quarter/quarter section is one-sixteenth of a section, or approximately forty acres. If any quarter/quarter section had already been divided into a number of lots equal to or greater than the number permitted, then no new lots would be a1 lowed within it. Quarter/quarter toning was proposed as a more flexible alternative to the standard large-lot zoning technique. Its purpose is to preserve agricultural land by keeping most of it in very large lots. In theory, the one or more small lots I permitted in each quarter/quarter section will not interfere materially with the long-term agricultural use of the property. The ability to sell off a limited number of small lots provides the owner with some income-earning potential over and above the agricultural value of his land. Another advantaye of the technique is its ease of administration by the land use control jurisdiction. All that is needed for administration is accurate legal lot information for all the land surveyed i n to sect ions. While quarter/quarter zoning offers a solution to some of the problems of standard large-lot zoning, its applicability to San Diego County may be limited because of the following factors: 1. Not all of the County's agricultural land is surveyed into sections. The /c- technique could not be used within the California ranchos. 2. Much of the County's agricultural land is already divided into parcels smaller than 40 acres. Quarter/quarter zoning does not work well unless the land is still in large tracts of 40 acres or, better yet, multiples of 40 acres. S1 iding Scale Zoning Another type of density zoning is the use of a "sliding scale'' for the determina- tion of minimum lot size. mitted in accordance with proposed for subdivision. density. The following table shows Maryland. Wiih this technique, the subdivision of land is per- The larger the original parcel, the lower the permitted a flexible standard based on the site of the parcel Area of Lot of Record at the Time of the Effective Date of this Ordinance how the sliding scale is used in Baltimore County, Less than 3 acres At least 3 but not more than 10 More than 10 but not more than 20 *- More than 20 but not more than 100 More than 100 Maxi nltm Number of Lots Permitted 1 2 3 4 5 lots plus one additional lot for each 25 acres in excess of 100 acres of the total tract area 117 Thus, in Baltimore County, the sl one dwelling unit per acre to one on the size of the original lot. The theory behind "s1 idins scale" iding scale would allow densities ranging from dwelling unit per twenty-five acres, depending zoning for agricultural preservation is that smaller lots are less 1 ikely to be important segments of the agricultural base of the area. This technique is designed to keep larger tracts in agricultural use while smaller parcels would be permitted to be divided for residential estates. The proponents of the "sliding scale" technique would also argue that large landholdings are more likely to be profitably engaged in agriculture; there- fore, owners of such land are less likely to need to subdivide their land to profit by their investments. "Sliding scale" zoning has a number of important advantages. First, it would appear to be an effective way of minimizing the subdivision of large landholdings and thereby preserving land for agricultural use. Second, it provides for a great deal of flexibility. Different "s1 iding scales" could be used in different areas to suit local conditions. As in quarter/quarter zoning, the landowner could be relied upon to decide on the size and location of the permitted new lots. Third, the technique would theoretically work in areas where quarter/quarter zoning would not be appropriate. Its use is not restricted to areas surveyed into sections where all lots are of any particular size. Fourth, it is not difficult to administer. The density permitted on any lot is determined by the size of that lot at the time specified in the ordinance implementing the sliding scale technique. " However,,the "sliding scale" technique also has some important drawbacks. It is not clear whether such an approach would be legal here in California. On the face of it, it seems to violate commonly held notions of equity. One might argue that Owners of larger tracts were being arbitrarily discriminated against. Even if such a legal challenge were not effective, it might be difficult to retain in the long run the necessary political support for such a program. Another drawback is that new owners of land that has already been subdivided in accordance with the "sliding scale" may not be properly informed about the development potential of their property prior to their purchase of it. It may be difficult for them to accept that their property cannot be resubdivided when some adjacent smaller property can be divided. 118 . PART VI SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS .SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS The six assumptions in Part I, "Introduction," were found to be generally accurate. The concern over the "loss" of agricultural lands is somewhat misplaced since the total amount of land in production has increased at least 26 percent since 1970. It is important to note, however, that the lands which are being taken out of production are, generally speaking, the best agricultural lands remaining in the County while the lands being brought into production are often unusable for anything but the planting of avocados. Our consultants' reports (summarized in Part IV) indicate that many of San Diego's crops are annually increasing their revenues. In fact, as an industry, the agricultural sector saw an increase in revenue of 46 percent (adjusted for inflation) since 1970. Urban and estate development has put pressures on agricultural operations throughout the urban fringe areas of the County. The areas directly east of metropolitan San Diego, which were in the past major production centers, have all but ceased agricultural activities. Similar pressures are now being brought to bear on the North County and Otay areas, which contain the majority of today's agricultural cropland. To a very real extent, the County through its land use powers can measurably affect the pressures being brought to bear on agri- cultural lands. In Part II, "Physical Resources,'' four basic points were made. First, over 90 coastal, and transitional areaclimates which include most of the western half of the County. Second, 86 percent of the production acreage in the County takes place on soi 1s rated "good or fair" by the Soils Survey. By and large, these soils are also all located in the western half of the County. Third, over 90 percent of the production value and acreage in the County occurs within the boundaries of the County Water Authority (CWA) which is wholly located in the western third of the County. As the availability of imported water is absolutely necessary for almost all commercial agriculture, and because the Metropolitan Water District has adopted a policy restricting the availability of water for agricultural purposes to areas within the CWA boundary of August, 1976, com- mercial agriculture in San Diego has been effectively restricted to the western third of the County. Fourth, of the 24 community and subregional planning areas in the County, only 14 (Pendleton-DeLuz, Fallbrook, Bonsall, North County Metro, San Dieguito, Pala-Pauma, Valley Center, Otay, Poway, Ramona, Rainbow, Lakeside, Crest-Dehesa, and Valle de Oro) contain appreciable quantities of land with the water, soil, and climatic resources necessary for production. - percent of both the value and acreage of production occurs in the maritime, While these 14 areas possess the basic resources for potential agricultural productiorl, only the first ten listed above contain a significant, percentage of the land in the County actually used for agriculture. These ten areas together comprise 81 percent of the approximately 116,000 acres of unincor- porated County land currently in production. Eighty percent of the land in production in these ten areas has non-urban land use designations (i.e., the minimum parcel size is 2 acres or larger), and the average overall parcel size is 16.4 acres, with the average agricultural parcel slightly larger at 21.0 stage of agricultural production. The first eight of these ten areas were judged by our consultants to possess the resources necessary for economically viable agricultural operations. - acres. On the average, 26.4 percent of the land in these 10 areas is in some 120 I While the issue of preserving agricultural land is conlplex and fraught wi tll a number of practical difficulties, it seems clear that the County should actively seek to protect and preserve its agricultural lands. There are many compelling reasons for the County to become more actively involved in this. issue. First, it appears certain that San Diego will continue to be subject to rapid growth pressures through the next sevyral years. The growth strategies of the Regional Growth Management program appear to be able to accommodate most of the projected population growth in existing urban areas with some major exceptions. These exceptions include some important agricultural lands in the coastal areas of North County and San Dieguito, the area between Vista and 5an Marcos, and possibly Otay Mesa. Second, in add i t ion to the problems of exiand ing urban areas, there is the possibility of non-urban development causing higher densities in rural agricultural areas. The reduction of parcel sizes from the County-wide average of just over 20 acres for agricultural parcels down toward the often-permitted 2-acre size would have a significant negative impact on the local agricultural industry. What is particularly insidious about this kind of development is that, once it has begun, there are increasing pressures for other surrounding parcels to be divided into smaller ones. Third, the County's efforts in agricultural preservation have, to date, been unclear, incohesive and unfocused. Although the County's land use regulations have affected agricultural uses for many years, there has never been a compre- hensive effort by the County to'ensure that these regulations worked toward the retention of agricultural uses. Thus, today we have "Intensive Agriculture" General Plan designations that may or may not designate areas where there are the resources necessary for production and may or may not show where agricultural uses are presently occurring. Similarly, the County has for years been partici- pating in the Williamson Act agriculture preservation program without focusing the program's benefits on our most productive cropland. Over 80 percent of the lands benefiting from the program are located in the eastern part of the County without the climate, soils or water necessary for significant commercial ' product ion. In the development of an Agriculture Element, the County will need to examine in some detail the compensatory and regulatory preservation techniques which are available. Any serious effort to preserve the agricultural lands in the County will best be served by an agriculture plan which offers a variety of preservation techniques. At this point in time only the "purchase and lease- back" technique appears to be beyond the capabi 1 ity of the County. The ecnonlic and fiscal impacts of the other techniques however will have to be further examined before any judgment can be made on their applicability. To summarize, a significant portion of the County's agricultural lands are certain to face both direct and indirect pressures to convert to other uses. The current preservation programs of the County seem incapable of dealing with this problem. An Agriculture Element could effectively help the County retain agricultural land uses by: 121 c ,- 1. Ensuring that the existing plans and policies are clear, coherent, and supportive of the local industry; 2. Introducing new concepts in agricultural preservation; and 3. Guiding development, both urban and non-urban, away from areas which have the best chanch for commercial, long-range production. 1 22 FOOTNOTES 1. 2. 3* 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 17. la. 13. 20. 21. Pg. 4, San Diego: An Introduction to the Region, Pryde. Pg. X-58, Conservation Element, San Diego County General Plan. HR 5882. a. Differential Assessment As Land Use Policy, AIP Journal, 11-75, Gustafson. b. California Landowners Adoption of A Use Value Assessment Program, LAND c. California's Use Value Assessment Program, 1977, Gustafson. Pp. 1-12, Climates of San Diego County: Agricultural Relationships, 1970, University of California. ECONOMICS, 8/77, Carmen. Pp. 13-20, IBID. Agriculture: San Diego County. Border Area Development Study, Southwest Border States Regional Action Commission, E.D.A. Grant #99-06-09588. Unpublished Report, Integrated Planning Office. Various estimates: see D.W.R., Assessor, Department of Agriculture, Integrated Planning Office Estimates. pg. 3, S 5120 Pg. 16 IBID. 1977 Crop Report, Department of Agriculture, San Diego County. 1 (C) Government Code. 1, Soils Survey, San Diego County Planning Department, 1377. Pg. 162, IBID. Integrated Planning Office Study. Pg. 18, "Agriculture," February, 1978, also "INFO" Py. 1, October, 1977, M.W.D. 3lst Annual Report, San Diego County Water Authority. 123 22. Pg. 19, IBID. 23. Pg. 50, IBID. ,F 24. Pg. 2, "INFO." 25. Pg. 9, Draft, "Regional Growth Management, Environmental lmapct Report," March, 1978. 26. Pp. 226-228, "Preliminary Regional Growth Management Plan,'' County of San Diego, also "Draft Environmental Impact Report." 27. M.W.D. Code, 301.9 and 312.2.4. 28. Table 10, 3lst Annual Report, County Water Authority. 29. Pg. 22, gist Annual Report, C.W.A. 30. Integrated Planning Office. 31. Pg. 26, 31st Annual Report, C.W.A. 32. Pg. 22, IBID. 33. Pg. 18, "Agriculture," February, 1378, Miner. .9" 34. Pg. 22, IBID. 35. Pp. 165-188, Water Pricing Study, Volume II, M.W.D., 1374. 36. Pg. 22, 31st Annual Report, C.W.A. 37. IBID. 38. Pp. 2-3, Water Pricing Study - 1377, M.W.D., March 1977. 39. Pg. 2, Letter (October 20, 1978), Griffi th (Metropol itan Water District) to Zucker (Integrated Planning Off ice). 40. Pg. 60, 31 st Annual Report, C.W.A. 41. Pg. 22, IBID. 42. Conversation with Linden Burzell. 43. Farm Advisorls Office, Menlo, June, 1977. 44. P. 26, Table VII, "Regional Growth Management, Environmental Impact Report." 45. Pg. 2-11-13, Areawide Water Quality Management Plan, Part II, March, 1978. 46. Pg. 62, Areawide Water Quality Management Plan, Summary, June, 1978. 47. Pg. 67, IBID. 48. Pp. 2.V.2 -- 2.V.3, Areawide Water Quality Management Plan, Part I I, March, 1978. 49. Pp. 2.V.II -- 2.V.21, IBID. 124 END OF REPORT ANOTHER DOCUMENT FOLLOWS " - .).. PRIME FARMLAND: INVENTORY, URBANIZATION IMPACTS MITIGATION MEASURES A section of the final environmental impact statement (EIS) on the .Modesto uasteuater facilities improvements. Approved by EPA RegionaZ Administrator NovemSer .1'6, 1979. Prepared Under Contract to: U. S. Environmental Protection Agency Region IX 215 Fremont Street San Francisco, CA 94105 . Principal Authors: .. Grue.n Gruen + Associates Socioeconomic and Land Use Consultailts 564 Howard Street San Francisco, CA 94105 and Houshang Esmaili & Associates Civil and Agricultural Engineers 2718 Telegraph Avenue Berkeley, CA 94705 Assisted bv: Jones & Stokes Associates Prime Contractor '2321 P Street Sacramento, CA 95816 and City of Modesto Planning and Community Development Department 801 Eleventh Street Modesto, CA 95354. 4 FORWARD This report is a portion of the environmental impact statement (EIS) on the Modesto Wastewater Facilities Plan prepared for the U. S. Environ- mental Protection Agency,.Region IX. ConsuItants contributing to the prime farmland chapter of the EIS were: - Jones L Stokes Associates, Prime Contractor . Gruen. Gruen + Associates, Socioeconomics and Land Use - Houshang Esmaili & Associates, Agronomy and Soils Science This chapter of the EIS serves several purposes. It establishes an overall perspective on the supply of prime farmland in the nation, in California and in Stanislaus County. Trends in land use change in these areas - particularly loss of prime farmland to urbanization - are explored. A detailed forecast of the possible effects of Modesto's wastewater facil- ities expansion on prime agricultural land resources in the area is presented. The major contribution of this stuhy to the understanding of prime farmland impacts and issues is its discussion of.mitigation measures. The consultants conducted a program of research which identified active and potential agricultural land retention programs throughout the United States. These programs were classified according to the'manner in which they address farmland retention objectives (for example, by affecting the amount of urban development) and each one is analyzed in terms of the theory underlying it, the implementing agency, how it is applied and its actual or likely effectiveness. The chapter concludes with an in-depth examination of .the specific agricultural land retention measures implemented by the City of Modesto and Stanislaus County, and presents a quantitative evaluation of their effectiveness. It also sets forth the additional measures Modesto has proposed to take in response to the prime agricultural land impacts of ~ future community growth, and presents an estimate of how these measures will further increase Modesto's effectiveness in preserving the agricultural I land resources of central Stanislaus County. I I The report represents the most extensive discussion of agricultural land retention programs currently available. Both the exhaustive explora- tion of the mitigation measures inventory (some 50 measures are discussed) and the detailed discussion of Modesto's programs are intended to provide the basis for action by other communities - in California and elsewhere - in strengthening local government commitment to ana effectiveness in con- serving prime farmland. In addition, supportive measures by federal and state agencies are identified. A summary of the mitigation measure evaluation is presented in matrix form an page 86. .' Table of Contents CHAPTER 5 - 'URBANIZATION OF PRIME FARMLAND Introduction Perspective on the Significance of Prime Farmland Prime Farmland in the United States . The Character of the Prime Farmland Estimates of the Amount of Prime Farmland Trends in Agricultural Land Conversion Rural Land Use Changes, 1967 to 1975 Cropland Acreage Change,' 1967 to 1975 Prime Farmland Conversion, 1967 to 1975 Economic Pressures on Agricultural The Importance of Prime Farmlands Preser- Resource Landowners vation The Environmental Case for Preserving Farmlands Watershed Protection Insulation of Environmentally Sensi- Provision of Wildli.fe Habitat Removal of Air Pollutants . tive Areas' from Incompatable Uses The Case for Preserving Prime Lands as Reserve Capacity for Food and Fiber Production Uncertainty About Future Increases Future Domesiic Needs for U. S. Food . Demand f.or Agricultural Exports ' in Crop Yields . and Fiber Products Prime Farmland Preservation: A Growing National Concern Prime Farmland in California Agriculture in California's Economy The Prime Farmland Inventory Potential Prime Farmland Trends in Agricultural Land Conversion Future Prospects for California Agriculture Impediments to Reclamation of Additional Projections of Future Agricultural Land Lands , Use Recognition of Prime Farmlands Preservation as a State Policy Prime Farmlands in Stanislaus County Agriculture in the Stanislaus County 'Economy Trends in Agricultural Land Conversion Future Prospects for Agriculture in Stani- slaus County 2 3 3 3 6 6 6 7 7 7 7 7 8 10 11 12 13 13 13 13 14 15 .15 16 16 16 16 19 20 i -. - Table of Contents, continued Recognition of Prime Farmlands Preservation as a County Issue Summary and Conclusions Future Conversion of Agricultural Land to Urban Use in the City of Modesto ~ The-Effects 'of Federal Actions on Prime Land Forecasting the Urbanization of Prime Farmland Impacts of Prime Agricultural Land Conversion Economic Impacts of Agricultural Land Fiscal Impacts of Agricultural Land Conversion Social Impacts of Agricultural Land Conversion Resources Conversion Mitigation of Agricultural Land Conversion Introduction. Adverse Impact on Prime Agricultural Land Urban Expansion in Agricultural Areas No EPA Funding if Prime Agricultural Identifying and Implementing Mitigation Requires Mitigation Land Impacts are not Mitigated Measures Land Conversion Strategies for Mitigating Prime Agricultural Determining Whether Prime Agricultural Concepts of Mitigating Agricultural Land .. Land Loss is a Mitigatable Impact Conversion Directing Urban Development vs. En- hancing Agriculture's Survival Potential .Regulations vs. Incentives' . Purpose'of the Mitigation Measures I nve.n tory Inventory is.Exhaustive Inventory is Evaluative Measures Discussed Vary in Net Inventory Does Not Consider Economic Effectiveness. costs Organization of the Inventory Mitigation Measures Inventory Affect the Amount pf Urban Development Rationale Measures to Limit the Amount of Urban Development Limit the Amount of Land' Zoned for Urban Limit the Number of Building Permits Issued Limit Industrial Growth Generators Development Affect the Dens'ity of Development Rationale Measures to Affect the Density of Development 'Low Minimum Lot Sizes in Urban Areas . ii 20 20 22 22 23 2 7. 27 31 32 33 33 33 33 33 33 34 34 35 35 35 36 36 36 36 33 37 38 38 33 38 39 40 41 41 41 41 313 Table of Contents, continued High Minimum Lot Sizes in Rural Areas Maximum Lot .Sizes in Urban Areas Minimum Neighborhood Densities in Urban Areas , Infill Development in Urban Areas Cluster Development in Urban Areas Cluster Development in Rural Areas Affect the Location of Urban Development Rationale Measures to Control the Location of Urban Growth On or Toward Non-prime Lands Prohibition of Subdivisions on Unin- Local Eligibility for Federal 'and State Eligibility for Community Development/ Development corporated Lands Housing Programs Redevelopment Aid and Intergovernmental Assistance New Towns or Satellite Towns Urban Strategy Measures for Maintaining Existing Agricul- tural Locations General Plans . Federal Review of General Plan Elements AGricultural Reserves State Regulation of Agricultural Land Federal Designation of Exclusive Agricul- ' Condemnation or Transfer of Development Compensable Regulation Outright Purchase of Agricultural Land ' Purchase of Remainder Interest Limit the Availability of Urban Infrastructure tural Districts Rights Rationale Measures to Limit the Availability of Urban Infrastructure . Establish an Urban Service Area for Establish an Urban Expansion Area for EPA Clean Water Grants Restrict State and Federal Highway Aid 'Federal Regional Councii Coordination Short-term Growth Long-term Growth Promote Agricultural Uses Rationale Measures to Promote Agricultural Uses Bring New Agricultural Lands into Put Purchased Agricultural Land to Agri-. Growth of Cooperatives New Merchandising Techniques Production cultural Use iii . .. 42 42 43 44 45 46 46 46 47 47 4% 49 50 50 51 52 52 53 54 55 57 57 59 60 61 62 62 62 .6 2 63 63 64 65 66 66 66 66 67 68 68 .- 'I .. - - Table of Contents, continued Intermediate Technology for Agricultural National Prime Agricultural Land Policy Assure-Adequacy of Future Water Supplies Use Tax Policy to Protect or Encourage Agricul- Production tural Activity Rationale Measures to Make Tax Policy Encourage Agri-. cultural Activity/Discourage Urban Use of ' Prime Land Differential Assessments for Property Tax Deferred Taxation of Agricultural Lands Apply Value Capture Technique to Lands Finance Agriculture with Capita-1 from Alter Tax Rules for Industrial Investments Restructure Formula for Distributing Purposes Bene'fiting from Public Investment Non-agricultural Sources Sales Tax Revenue Needed Studies Rationale Studies Needed for Additiona1,Consideration of Mitigation Measures .. tural Land Preservation Agricultural Land Retention Performance Standard for'Urban Growth in Prime Cost/Benefit Analysis of Prime Agricul- Comparative Inter-city Analysis of Prime Land Areas Rationale Measures to Implement Performance Standards " . . . ..~ Establish Threshold Standards of. Per- formance Relating to Density and Infill. formance Standard Establish a Conversion Coefficient Per- Conclusions Modesto's Agricultural Land Conversion Mitigation Program .. Modesto's Historical Performance Past Agricultural Land Absorption in Modesto Modesto's Performance Compared to Other Cities'in California's Principal Agricul- tural Areas Evolution of Modesto's Mitigation Package Mitigation a Grantee Responsibility Agricultural Land Retention Was Modesto Policy Before the Current Project Was. Proposed Mitigation via Land Development Regulation Zoning Reducing the Minim- Lot Size . iv 69 70 71 72 72 73 73 75 75 76 77 77 78 78 78 79 80 81 a1 82 82 a3 84 87 87 87 88 90 90 90 91 91 91 Table of Contents, continued Interpret the R-1 Zone as a Density Zone Establish a .Maximum Lot Size Duplexes on Corner Lots in New Sub- Use of P-D Zoning to Achieve Higher . Subdivision Controls . divisions Densities Building Code Review Multi-family Construction Standards Mitigation via Land Development Policy and Planning Urban Growth Policy Review .Monitoring Overall Urban Density Establishing Urban Density Objectives Encourage Infill Development Infrastructure Extension Policies Service Area Definitions Trunk Sewer Extension Priorities Prototype Neighborhood Concept Allow for a Mix.of Densities in Future Target Neighborhood Densities Monitoring the Density of New Development Mitigation Via Intergovernmental Cooperation Development Urbanization Requires Annexation Rural Development Controls Minimum Lot Size in Agricultural Areas Rural Residential Development Limited to Limit Nonresidential Development in . Non-prime Areas Unincorporated Areas ,. Implementation of the Williamson Act Limiting Parcel Division in Rural Areas Agricultural Element of County General Pian Implementation and Effectiveness of Mitigation Adequacy of Mitigation Measures National Impact of Comparable Actions by Other Measures Cities .. 92 93 93 93 94 94 94 94 94 9 4: 94 95 95 95 96 98 98 98 98 9 9- 99 99 99 99 99 100 '100 130 106 106 V ' Table Number 5-1 5-2 5-3 .. 5 -,4 5-5 5-6 5-7 5-8 5- 9 5-10 5-11 c LIST OF TABLES Title Land Utilization, United States, Selected Years 1910-1974 Projeoted Uses. of Land in the' Contiguous 48 States in 1980 and 2000 (with 1949 and. 1969 Historic Data) U.S. Cropland Needs in the Year 2000 Under Five Alternative Development Scenarios California Prime Farmland Inventory' Existing (1972)- and Projected Aggregated Water Supply and Demand and Acreage Under Irrigation .. Present and Potential Prime Farmland County, State and Nation Future Urban Land Absorption in EIS Socio- economic Study Area and in City of Modesto, 1979-2000 .. Modesto Urban Land Needs and Agricultural Land Conversion Estimates' Under the EIS ' Forecast and Two Alternative Growth Scenarios, 1979-2000 Estimated Economic Impacts of Modesto Agri- cultural Land Conversion: Point Estimates for 1990, 2000 and Iinpact Year Prime Agricultural Land.Mitigation Matrix Comparative Density Statist.ics: fifteen^ Largest Central Valley and Delta Cities - .- 5-12;. ':'Comparative Infill Data: Fifteen Largest ' Central Valley and Delta Cities 5-13 Mitigation of the Adverse Effects of the . .L) ,. Modesto Wastewa.ter Facilities Expansion on Prime Agricultural Land: New Measures Accepted by Modesto City Council 5- 14 Growth Accommodated by Priority Sewer Trunk Extensions 5-15 Modesto's Agricultural Land Mitigation . Program: Impact Summary and Timetable for Implementation . vi . Page 4 11 .ll 1 4- 18 22 25 26 29 86 89 89 92 96 102 LIST OF TABLES, continued .- E Table Number Title Page 5-16. Prime Agricuitural Acreage Retained Under 105 Modesto's Mitigation Program LIST OF FIGURES .Figure Number 5-1 Land Use ConVersions, 1967 to 1975 in the United States .. 5-2 Farm Output and U.S. Population 5-3 Crop Production per Acre and Cropland Used for Crops 5-4 Historica1,Conditions and Projected Irrigated 5 -.5 Prime and Nqn-prime Soils in the Modesto Area Land Area Requirements in California BIBLIOGRAPIIY and PARTICIPATING STAFF These sections will be published in the version printed by the Government Printing Office. 5 9 9 17 28 .' vii ERRATA Po 24 First paragraph.: comprehensive land use surveys (1971. and 1978) p. 26 Table 5-8, seventh row, seventh column: substitute 820 for 880 p. 29 Table 5-9: Change title to read: ESTIMATED ECONOMIC IMPACTS OF MODEST0 AGRI- CULTURAL LAND- CONVERSION: POINT ESTIMATES FOR YEAR OF CAPACITY USE AND 2000 p. 33 First paragraph: The Modesto wastewater facilities expansion would accommodate the conversion of an esti- mated 2,720 to 3,620 acres of prime agricultural land to urban use .. . . p. 106 First paragraph, third line: for mitigatec?. substitute unmitigated . . viii Chapter 5 URBANIZATION OF PRIME FARMLAND Introduction A major issue addressed by this EIS is the projected conversion of prime agricultural land or urban uses which will be made possible by the proposed expansion of the Modesto.wastewater facilities. The EIS is. required to consider this issue pursuant to the directive of the U. S. Council on Environmental Quality (CEQ) stating that ."highly productive farmlands" are among those "important historic cultural and natural aspects of our national heritage" which it is federal policy to preserve: .. "Efforts should be made to assure that such farmlands are not irreversibly converted to other uses unless other national interests override the importance of preservation or otherwise outweigh the environmental benefits . derived from their protection" (CEQ, 1976). Regulations of the U. S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA, 1975) implementing the National Environmental Policy Act of 1969 require preparation of an EIS when imple- mentation of a facilities plan may result in changes that would "adversely affect significant amounts of prime agri- cultural land or agricultural operations on this land". The implementation of th-e Modesto wastewater fac'ilities plan will allow conversion of prime agricultural lands in Modesto and the surrounding area.to urban uses. This chapter addresses the significance of that impact by evaluating the importance of prime farmlands from the national, state and local perspectives. -To this end, an overview is presented of the amount and character of prime farmland in the United States, in California and in Stanislaus County. Variations in the level of crop acreage and crop yield are discussed briefly and"data are presented on the conversion of farm- land to nonagricultural uses. The c.hapter ,concludes with an estimate of the projected conversion to urban use of prime farmland in and around Modesto. It then presents an inventory of agricultural land retention measures and a discussion of their application both in theory and in practice. Finally, the measures Modesto has adopted or plans to adopt to mitigate the con- version of prime agricultural land associated with the wastewater facilities expansion project are presented. '- 1 - ~. , Perspective on the Significance of.Prime Farmland Prime Farmland in the United States The Char.acter of the Prime Farmland Resource. Prime farmland is land suitable for'farming.or silviculture possessing attributes established by the Soil Conservation Service (SCS) of the United States Department of Agricul- ture (USDA) : "Soil quality, growing season, and moisture supply needed to economically produce sustained high yields of crops when treated and managed, including water manage- ment, according to acceptable farming methods" (Lee, 1978). Prime farmland - or, more technical-ly, prime agricul- .tural land - may be found in rural or in urban settings; it may be used for crops, for pasture or for other agri- cultural purposes; it may not even be farmed at a-given point in time but may instead be in forest use or encum- bered by buildings, roads or water impoundments. Basically, it includes all those lands - whatever their current uses - which have soil, climate and water availability character- istics that permit the production of "relatively more food with less erosion and with lower demand for fertilizer, energy and other resourcesn than nonprime land (CEQ, 1977). In this EIS, the SCS definition presented above is the .. applicable definition wherever the term "prime farmland" and "prime agriculturai land" are used except where data from sources using diFferent definitions are presented; in those cases, definitional differences are identified. It should be noted that prime farmland is Aot .the same * . as farmland, because some farmland is not prime; neither is it the same as rural land, because. not all rurai land meets the criteria of prime agricultural land (in fact, very little does). The term cropland includes land devoted to the cultivation of field crops, row crops, orchards and vineyards. While not all cropland is prime farmland, much of it is, because crop production depends much more -on soil, climate and water availability conditions than does . the production. of other kinds of agricultural products (such as 1ive.stock-and poultry). For this reason, a reduction in the amount of cropland is sometimes interpreted as indicating a decline in the amount .of prime farmland available for pro- duction. Estimates of the Amount of Prime Farmland. In 1975 the SCS inventoried 384 million acres of prime farmland in the U, S. Of this total, 250 million acres were in cropland, 77 million acres were in pasture and range, 43 million acres '- 2 - .' h were in forest land, and 14 million acres were in miscel- laneous other uses. (Dideriksen, 1977). The 1975 inventory updates an earlier (1967) inventory of SCS, which had ad- dressed the question of how much potential cropland existed in the U. S. - land not in crop production, but with high or medium potential for crop cultivation. The 1967 inven- tory counted 266 million acres of potential cropland, but the 1974 inventory reduced this estimate to 111 million acres, of which only 15 million acres can readily be brought into cultivation. Constraints that preclude bringing the remaining 96 million acres of high/medium potential crop- land into cultivation include dense forest cover, seasonal high water tables and high erosion factors (Dideriksen, -1977,). It should be noted that the potential cropland figures encompass both prime and nonprime lands which can be converted to cropland. The prime land component of these figures is already accounted for in the total national supply of 384 million acres of prime farmland. The current national supply of prime farmland in crop . , production is therefore about 250 million acres; another 15 million acres of prime agricultural land could be brought into immediate crop production without constraints and another 9 million with minimal constraints-. The remaining 87 million acres of prime and nonprime land with a high or medium potential for conversion to cropland represents a longer run reserve of cropland resources. Trends in Agricultural Land Conversion. National land use patterns have remained fairly stable in the decades since 1910, as Table 5-1 shows. As in 1950, cropland in 1974 still comprised approximately 1/5 of the total land u.se in the country. . RuraZ Land Use Changes, 1967 to 1975. Land use changes .'between 1967 and 1975 are presented in Figure 5-1. Total cropland and total pasture and rangeland both declined; forest land increased. The small circle at the lower left of Figure 5-1 represents land which had been in'rural use in 1967, but which by 1975 had either been inundated (for reservoirs) or converted to urban use. A. total of 24 million acres had passed out of the rural land supply into urban or water use in the 8-year period. Cropland Acreage Change, 1967 to 1975.. Approximately 78 million out of 431 million acres of cropland' (defined in the 1975 survey as land in tillage rotation, orchards, and land formerly in such uses) were converted to noncrop- land uses during. the 1967-75 period. Most of the converted cropland acreage was put to less intensive agricultural use -3- .. ” Table 5-1 . Major Land Uses. . . (millions of acres) Cropland Used for Crops’ Idle Cropland Cropland Used Only for Pasture Grassland Pasture Forest Land4 Special Uses’ Other Land . Total Land Area6 . NT = not tabulated. ’Preliminary. 1910 1-920‘ 1930 1940 1950 1959 1969. 1974’ 330 368 382 368 377 359 333 363 20 ”-,- __ 23 34 31 31 32 33 51 84 78 . 67 68 69 66 88 84 693 652 652 650 631 633 604 598 600 602 601 608 601 728 723 7 18 NT NT NT NT NT 147 174 184 19 4 3 05 291 297 1,904 1,904 1,904 1,904 1,904 2,271 2,264 2,264 174 170 ’ 171 179 ”””” ’Cropland harvested, crop failure, and cultivated summer’ fallow. . 4Excludes reserved forest land in parks and other special uses. Includes forested 3 Grassland and other nonforest pasture and range.. grazing land. ’Includes urban and transportation areas, Federal and State areas used primarily * fix recreation and wildlife purposes, military areas, farmsteads, farm roads and lanes, and misc. other uses. except for the major increase in 1959 when data for Alaska ahd Hawaii were added. 6Remeasurement ard increases in reservoirs account for changes in total land area . Source’: USDA , -19 77 . . .. -4- I m I FIGURE 5-1 . ,LAND' USE CONVERSIONS, 1967 TO 1975 IN THE UNITED STATES ' (MILL IONS OF ACRES) -LEGEND- 44- ACRES CHANGED TO ANOTHER LAND USE # IDLE LAND, RURAL RESIDENCE,ETC. BUILT UP SINCE 1967-24 1967-57 1975-70 REDRAWN FROM1 DIDERIKSEN, 1977 .. (pasture and range). Much of this change is attributed primarily to low soil fertility, erosion'and the existence of terrain unsuitable.for e€ficient use of agricultural machinery. 'On the other hand, 49 million acres of non- cropland were converted into cropland during the same phriod, most of that addition coming out of the pasture and rangeland category. There was a net loss of cropland to urban and water . uses between 1967 and 1975 amounting to more than 5 mil- lion acres. Conversion of actively farmed cropland to nonagricultural uses was estimated to have taken place at the rate of 700,000 acres pel; year (Congressional Research Service [CRS], 1978)-. -. : ' Prime FarmZand Conversion, 1967 to 1975. Of the over 5 million acres of cropland converted to urban and water - uses between 1967 and 1975, about 83 percent (4.5 million acres) was classified as prime farmland by SCS. Other irreversible conversion of prime farmland involved 2.9 million acres withdrawn from pasture and range, forests and other uses. T.otal conversion of prime. land to urban and water uses was 7.4 million acres over the 8-year period, or slightly less than a million acres a year. - -. Economic Pressures.on AgricuZt.uraZ Landowners. Rising prices for agricultural land can pose economic problems to farm owners because higher land values are generally reflected agricultural areas at the urban-rural fringe'the pressure' on the farmland owner may be particularly strong, as. land buyers' interest is in the land's future development poten- tial rather than its agricultural use value. The farmer. can often sell his land for far more than he could afford to pay for it to keep it in farming use. .in higher property taxes, an out-of-pocket expense. In This gap between the economic value of farmland in agri- cultural use vs. potential urban use can'cause diminishing productivity and premature idling of cropland near urban areas. Anticipating a sale, the farmer discontinues invest- ' ment in improvements and reduces-maintenance costs. The .farmer who decides not to.sel1 may face continually rising costs at the edge of urban expansion approaches. He be- comes increasingly adversely affected, not only by rising .. property taxes, but by other incidental impacts of urban development such as road congestion, air pollution and possibly limits on certain kinds of agricultural operations. Often, the farmer eventually chooses to sell the property and relocate (Snyder, 1976) . .The Importance of Prime Farmlands Preservation. The conversion of prime agricultural lana to urban use is, for all practical purposes, irreversible. The conversion of -6- c -. .. L prime lands to urban uses reduces the range of environ- mental benefits derived from the land, and represents a potential reduction in the n.ation's food,and fiber pro.- duction capahilities. . . The EnvironmentaZ Case for Preserving Farmlands. Given good farm management and soil conservation prac- . tices, a number of environmental benefits are inherent in the use of land for agricultural purposes. Some of the more readily identifiable benefits (EPA, 1978a) in- cluding the following: Watershed Protection. Open lands, such as farms, .help maintain local wa.ter supplies by absorbing precipi- tation and transferring it to the groundwater system; protect the hydrologic integrity of watersheds through the control of storm water runoff and sediment damage; protect aquifer recharge areas; and provide buffers for water supply and other natural areas. Insulation of EnvironmentaZZy Sensitive Areas from IncompatibZe Uses. Agricultural uses can provide both a buffer and an economically viable land us.e for areas sub- ject to environmental hazard conditions (i.e., flood- prone areas, subsidence areas, wildfire hazard areas, etc.). Ecologically sensitive areas can also be buffered by farmlands, although agricultural activities may them- selves pose a threat to some of these areas. .. Provision of 'WiZdZife Habitat. Agricultural areas . often contain important elements of wildlife habitat. ,In the eastern U. S., these habitat elements often involve remnants of original habitat types which have been largely. replaced by cultivated areas. In the more arid western U. S,, stock ponds and irrigation systems can provide ' important water sources'for wildlife. Fallow areas, orchards and unharvested grain crops.are also important to wildlife in many areas. But in a historical perspective, agriculture has been the major source of habitat destruc- tion, both in this country and elsewhere in the world. Modern farming practices provide very little wildlife habitat in areas of intensive cultivation (National Academy of Sciences, 19'70). Removal of Air PoZZutants. Agricultural activities '(cultivation, pesticide use, agricultural burning, etc.) contribute a variety of gaseous and particulate pollutants to the atmosphere. But uptake, absorption, and physical impaction on vegetation are major removal mechanisms for many air pollutants. Pafticulates, sulfur dioxide, nitro- gen dioxide and ozone are all subject to. significant removal rates when polluted air comes in contact with vegetation. Carbon monoxide and nitric oxide, on the other hand, are not removed by contact with vegetation. 4 Depending on pollutant concentration, the'process of pollutant removal by vegetation may lead to reduced plant growth or death of plant tissues (Hill, 1971; Bennett and Hill, 1973). The. Case for Preserving Prime Lands as Reserve Capacity for Food and Fiber Production, Each increment of this highly productive or potentially productive land which is urbanized diminishes our future agricultural resource base. ' The annual losses, accumulated over decades, can make a -size.able dent in the total supply, and this is happening .; at a time when at least some observers suggest that our future food and fiber needs, domestic and export, may well .exceed the production levels which a constant or declining agricultural land base can support. Future yields, future domestic agriculture needs, future export demands and the ability of American agriculture to weather inflation, land uncertainties the future holds. . speculation and other economic pressures are some of the Uncertainty About Future Increases in Crop YieZds. "Yield" is the amount of agricultural 0utpu.t which can be obtained from a given unit of land. Yields from U. S. ' agriculture have risen steadily over.time, more rapidly than domestic population growth as Figure 5-2 shows for the period since 1950. Technological advances have contributed to an increase in yicilds of about 60 percent and in total output by 160 percent from 1949 to 1975 (Figures 5-2 and.5-3). These incrtases took place during a period when the acreage of cropland used for crops decreased by.some 20 million acres (5 percent). A major source of this increased agricultural capacity has been the development and adoption of new techniques in.the production and pro- cessing of food and fiber, such as 2ynthetic fertilizers and hybrid plants. ._ There is considerable doubt that historical produc- tivity gains can continue indefinitely into the future. ' Constraints on the adoption of new technology such as restrictions on the.use of pesticides, higher energy and -energy-related input costs, as well as the necessity for .cultivation of less productive lands due to the loss of better lands to urban-and other uses, may restrict future yield increases (Skolds and Penn, 1977) . In balancing the environmental and economic costs against the impjlemen- tation of new technologies, it is expected that yields will increase, but at a slower rate than that experienced in the past two decades. I'n view of diminishing rates of increases in yields, the supply of land itself-reemerges as the most. important' variable in estimating potential future agricultural output. .. . 31 -8- FIGURE 5-2 FARM OUTPUT & U. S. POPULATION 1950' 1955 I960 1965 , I970 1975' 1980 YEAR * PRELIMINARY NOTE: INDEX OF FARM OUTPUT IS CALCULATED BI rHE CONSTANT PRICE- WEIGHT METHOD AND INCLUDES ALL SO STATES. COMPILED 'FROM COTNER, 1975 € FDA, 1977 FIGURE 5-3 CR3P PRODWGTiON PER. ACRE -& CROPLAND USED FOR CROPS 180 I60 I40 120 100 80 1 1 I I I 1 I977 19 50 1955 1960. I965 I970 * 1975 YEAR * FORECAST COWPILED FROM COTNER, 1975 e USDA, 1,077 I . .. , Future Domestic Needs for U. S. Food md Fiber Products. There is considerable disagreement among various forecasts of future cropland needs in the U. S. This can be illustrated by comparing the conclusions of two recent studies. The existing cropland base is in the range of 400 million acres (Table 5-1 shows 384 million acres in 1969 and 383 million acres in 1974; both of these figures include culti- vated and idle cropland). The Economic Research Service (ERS) of the USDA (Snyder, 1976) finds that cropland needs for the year 2000 will be far below that level (Table 5-2). Cropland used .for crops is projected to be about 298 million acres in the year 2000 for a net decrease of 35 million . acres (about 10 percent) from the 1969 level (USDA', 1974). .A strikingly different estimate of future cropland needs has been made by the Worldwatch Institute (WWI). The WWI study (Eckholm, 1976) sets forth estimates of the need for harvested cropland under five scenarios which re- flect alternative assumptions regarding U. s. population growth, economic growth and technology (Table 5-3). In all of the WWI Scenarios projected harvested cropland needs are much higher than the comparable values in the ERS study. The Worldwatch scenario most demanding of cropland - the scenario assuming high population growth, high economic , growth and low application,of technology - would require a total of 471 million acres of cropland in the year 2000, which is only 7 million-acres below the nation's long-term cropland capacity of 478 million acres (Lee, 1975). At the rate 02 increase in cropland-requirements implied by .the Worldwatch second scenario, all of the high potential cropland in the U. S. would be required for production by the year 2007. All of our prime agricultural land, in. other words, would be in use, and there would obviously be cause for concern as to the nation's ab'ility to meet' any additional food and fiber needs. - The divergent conclusions of-thes,e two studies illus- trate the uncertainties in the future of U. S. agriculture. Assumptions .about some of these uncertainties .- .domestid population, economic growth and technology - have been made - explicit in Worldwatch's scenarios. .ERS has not made its . ' assumptions>.as explicit, but has assumed that technological - innovation will continue to increase production and that export demand will not significantly alter. In view of such uncertainties, accurate estimation of future agricultural land needs is not possible. What is clear is that, under certain circumstances not wholly im- plausible, our supply of prime agricultural lands could be .. - 10 - . .- - . Table 5-2 PROJECTED USES OF LAND IN THE-CONTIGUOUS 48 STATES IN 1980 AND 2000 (,WITH 1949 AND 1969 HISTORIC DATA) Land Use 1949 19 69 . 1980 2000 . (millions of acres) Total cropland 387 333 320 29 8 Cropland harvested 35 2 286 292 2 72 Forest and woodland 601 603 591 578 Pasture, range, and other agricultural land 768 767 771 782 Urban and related 42 60 66 81 106 ' 134 149 158 ~ Other special uses and miscellaneous' uses Total land area 1,904* 1,897* 1,897 1,897 * Change due to remeasurement NOTE: Figures are for the contiguous 48 states; only the 1949 figures correspond. to those in Table 5-1 (for 1950) because the data in Table 5-1 include A1ask.a and Hawaii from 1959 on. Source : Snyder, 1976 Table- 5-3 U. S. CROPLAND NEEDS IN THE YEAR 2000 UNDER FIVE ALTERNATIVE 'DEVELOPMENT SCENARIOS Actual Year 2000 Scenario 1970 1 2 3 4 5 " - - - - - Assumptions Population (millions) 204 321 321 321 266 266 Economic growth "- High High ' Low High Low Technology . . High High Low Low High . Low Outcome Harvested cropland 344 391 438 436 359 390 (million acres) I. . . Cropland not harvested2 96 31 33 32 51 32 Total cropland 440 422 471 468 410 422 'Includes pasture in cropland. 21ncludes about 30 million acres required for failure and sur!uner fallow, the remainder being unused. . SOURCE: Eckholm, 1976 .. - 11 - e fully in use early in the 21st century; a backup supply of agricultural lands will exist, to be sure,.but of lesser qua.lity, involving. higher production costs, lower yields and rapidly rising'domestic food prices. Loss of prime lands to urbanization poses a problem-because such losses are irreversible and because the supply is finite. The cumulative effects of the alienation of these resources from agriculture may well pose a serious future problem . for the nation. .. Demand for Agricultural Exports. Thus far, the dis- cussion of agricultura(1 land requirements has focused on domestic food requirements; export levels have 'been assumed relatively stable. Significant increases in export demand 'would accelerate the. events described in Worldwatch's second scenario and would increase the cropland need estimated in both the studies cited. "Because the ERS estimate was published prior to the recent dramatic in- creases in U. s. agricultural exports, it probably does -not' fully reflect the potential- future worldwide demand .. . . for U. S. agricultural- products. Recent experience - the 1974 world food shortage, for example - shows the relationship between export demand and shortages raising international prices for agricultural commodities, the.federa1 government released almost all of the farmland retained under supply management programs (Cotner, 1975). But food prices nevertheJess rose sharply; between 1972 and 1974, food prices rose over 30 percent while prices of all items (including,food) rose less than 20 percent. With rising food prices, consumers.have been forced to spend an ever increasing percentage of their in- come on food. Policies designed to preserve the productive land base would help insulate domestic consumers from price increases due to increased export demand. . U. S. domestic food prices and production levels. With. -A growing farm export market has had a favorable effect on the nation's balance of trade. Acreage harvested for agridultural export increased from 69 million acres in 1967 to 100 million acres, or 30 percent of the total acreage. harvested, in 1975 (USDA, 1977). I-n 1977 the .country suffered a $27 billion trade deficit, but. agricul- ture had a 'net surplus of $10.6 billion (CRS, 1978) . As .. inflation and a growing trade deficit.erode the dollar's ,buying power, measures taken to preserve croplands will help ensure agriculture's ability to offset the increasing costs of imports. .a ..,.. . Prime Farmland Preservation: A Growing National Con- cern. The issue of farmland depletion and particularly the irreversible conversion of prirhe farmland to nonagri- cultural use has prompted federal legislation designed to protect our agricultural land resources. Legislation pro- posed.in the 95th Congress included the Agricultural Land I I i I ' Retention Act (H.R. 11122) and similar Senate Bills, S. 1616 and S. 2757 (CRS, 1978) . Essentially these bills would have provided funding' to..study agricultural land conversion and to make recommendations for possible modifications in fed- eral land use policies to prevent the depletion of the nation's prime farmland. None of these bills was acted upon by the 95th Congress. Prime Farmland in California * Agriculture in California's Economy. California's wide variety of quality soilsr unique climatic conditions and abundant irrigation water permit the commercial' cultivation .of over 200 crops. The state produces 25 percent of all table-food and 40 percent of.all fresh vegetables and fruit consumed in the nation (Reed, 1977). Agriculture is one of California's major industries: an estimated $8.6 bil- lion in cash receipts at .the farm level generated approxi- mately $45 billion or 24 percent of the state's aggregate output of $190 billion in 1975 (California Legislature, 1977a). Agricultural land use amounts .to 36.l million acres of the state's 100.1 million acres in 1975; howevec, most.of the cash return from crops was derived from produc- tion on the 3.7 million acres of irrigated land in the 1974) .. - state (California Department of Water Resources [DWR], , . The Prime Farmland Inventory. California developed and applied a definition of prime farmland prior to the more recent definition developed by SCS for the national . land inventory (see discussion earlier in this chapter of . the SCS definition, p. 90). The California definition is spelled out in the California Land Conservation Act of 1965, and is referred to in this chapter.as the "CLCA" definition. It is more inclusive than the SCS definition because it includes lands which return a gross revenue of $200 per acre, irrespective of their soil'quality, Table 5-4 sets forth estimates.of the amount of prime agricultural land in California under both CLCA and SCS definitions. The more restrictive SCS definition results in an inventory of 9 million acres, 3.6 million acres less .than the CLCA definition (Singer and Reganold, 1978). Potential Prime Farmland. Potential prime farmland, . is defined as that land which has the capacity to be made .prime (according to the CLCA definition) through normal agricultural. investment and practices (California Office ' of Planning and Research [OPR], 1974). OPR estimates that there are 8 million acres of potential prime land in the state. In contrast, SCS estimates only 4 million acres, based on the acreage of presently.hon.irrigated Class I and Class I1 soils. Most of these lands are located in the Mojave Desert and the Owens Vall'ey; the remainder are scattered in small parcels in coastal valleys. Only a - - 13 - ' small fraction of this acreage is found in' the major agri- cultural areas of the state. Table. 5-4 CALIFORNIA PRIME FAR~AND INVENTORY Potential Prime Prime Farmland Farmland Total i Qffice of Planning and Research (CLCA' classification) 12.6 . 7.98 20i58 .soil Conservation Service (LIM~ classification) . 9.0 4.003 13.003 "CLCA definition includes all lands meeting at least one of the following -criteria: (1) Class I and Class I1 soils as defined by SCS; (2) land 'that returned an annual gross value of not less than $200 per acre; (3) land qualifying for a rating of 80 to 100 in the Storie Index of Soil Classification; (4) land that supports livestock with an annual carry- ing capacity equivalent to at least one animal unit per acre, as defined by the USDA; (5) land planted in fruit or nut-bearing trees, vines, bushes or crops that have a nonbearing period of .less than 5 years, and that will normally return $200 per acre per year (Hanson and Schwartz, 1976) . 2U: S. Soil Conservation Service, 1977. ' 3~ontingent upon water availability. Source: Singer and Reganold, 1978 Trends in Agricultural Land Conversion. Past changes in California's agricultural land.use are well known in both technical and popular literature. The Santa Clara.Valley was a prime orchard area prior to 1950, yet from 1940 to 1970 over 40,000 acres of prime orchard land was taken out o'f production as population increased from 310,000 in 1950 to over 1 million in 1970 (Holloway, 1977). Since 1970, this trend has accelerated as approximately 24,000 acres of prime orchard land have: been .lost (Santa. C1ar.a County Depart- - ment of Agriculture, 1977). . ., .. San Diego County's unique Mediterranean climate and , , fertile soils have made'this area a leading producer of California specialty crops. But between 1950 and 1966, population pressure had forced the conversion of over 63,000 acres of prime farmland to urban .uses (San Diego County, 1968) and the area has lost its former leadership position in citrus and nut production. Generally, agricultural activities formerly located in the urban coastal counties have shifted.to the San Joaquin Valley, where vast acreages have been brought into intensive . 1 I -1 -J I Y FJ n - 14 - L ,- . . ,. -. cultivation through implementation of major irrigation pra- jects. It is estimated that about 55,000 acres per year of land are being reclaimed for intensive crop production (OPR., 1974). .. However, prime agricultural land' is also being absorbed by continuing urban expansion at the rate af 20,000 to 25,000 acres per year (DWR, 1974): Projections by OPR indicate that urbanization of prime farmland during the 1974-85 per- .iod will average 50,000 acres per year, and 80,000 acres :per year if potential prime land is also included. In view 65 the fact that DWR estimates of past prime farmland losses were about 25,000 acres per year, the OPR estimates of future .losses show a considerable acceleration of this trend. Future Prospects for California Agriculture. Impediments to Reczarnation of AdditionaZ Lands. The major impediment to the upgrading of.potentia1 prime land to prime land status is the lack of irrigation water supplies and a decrease in the amount of new water supplies available for agricultural use. Currently there is a gap between the supply of water and the demand, which agriculture is compen- sating for via groundwater overdrafting. New water projects would be needed to upgrade.potentia1 prime land to prime, - and current prospects for construction of such projects are not favorable. Less valuable agricultural lands - "marginal" lands - might also be brought into production if the long-term need . warranted and if water were available. However,.higher costs 'of production are incurred because these reclaimed marginal lands are less productive and require greater use of ferti- lizers, longer transport distances, and have lower yields over which to spread costs. Greater capital costs on these lands result from the need for more extensive water delivery systems, land and soil improvements and other fixed costs. High capital costs required for development of new crop- lands in California are illustrated by experience in the Westlands development project in Fresno County, where sub- sidies approaching $2.5 billion in the next 40 years may be needed to bring only 600,000 acres into production (Cali- fornia Legislature, 1977b). The primary reason for the decrease in return for new farmland is that the optimum conversion sites for agriculture purposes have been-used up, and the crop yields on marginal lands are not adequate to pay back the high construction costs of the needed water supply.projects. These factors indicate that the small reserve of prime agriculture land and the low economic viability of. new water projects reduces the feasibility of replacing lost prime land with lower quality marginal lands. .. - 15 - Projections of Future AgricuZturaZ Land Use. Projections by the,DWR in 1974 of future.water demands and the ability to meet these demands in the years 1990 and 2020 are summa- rized in Figure 5-4 and Table 5-5. High demand scenarios for irrigated land based on agricultural growth are repre- sented by Alternatives I and 11, and future agricultural water needs for these respective alternatives will exceed projected water supplies. If, however, either of the lower demand levels represented by Alternatives' I11 and IV is' .realized, projected water' supplies will be sufficient for qgricultural use. >::.*, : . In all four scenarios total water demand would exceed dependable water supplies. The deficit would have to be made 'up by groundwater overdrafts, providing that such a degree of overdraft is technically. and economically feasible. ' The outcomes of the four scenarios could'be significantly different from DWR's projections if urbanization expands at a faster rate or if new water supply facilities lag behind urban development more than expected. In fact, construction of a number of the water projects on which the DWR supply forecasts are based has been postponed, suspended or can- celled. The forecast of dependable water'supplies may con- . sequently be too high. .- . . .~ ". . . . . . . Recognition of Prime,Farmlands Preservation as a State Policy. Because of the uncertainties mentioned above, the Legislature has taken actions directed toward preserving California'a prime farmland. Several bills have been intro- -duced to'create an Agricultural .Resources Council at the ..state level to oversee the establishment of agriculture preserves. These bills would also require detailed mapping .'* of existing prime lands and development of local land use plans aimed at protection and preservation of these lands .(California Legislature., 1977a). However, no 'agricultural preservation bill has yet been enacted into law. -.,Prime - Farmlands in Stanislaus County . ~ ... . , ._ .. ,. . , .. . 4'. Agriculture in 'thk' Stanislaus County Economy. With a .. . .*- combination .of fertile alluvial soils, sufficient water - .I supplies, long growing season and favorable climate, Stani- . slaus County ranks sixth'among California counties in the value of agricultural production (Stanislaus County, 1977). As the most important local industry, agriculture directly or indirectiy supports over 75 percent of the county's .economic activity (Stanislaus Area Association of Govern- ments [SAAG], 1972). Approximately 78 percent, or 754,400 acres, of the county's total area of 967,000 acres are currently in agricultural uses (Stanislaus County, 1977) including about 308,400 acres in cropland.. About 300,000 acres in Stanislaus County are prime'agricultural lands (SCS definition), including an urban land area of approxi- mately 22,500 acres. A map of prime soils in eastern Stanislaus County'is enclosed in the map pocket at,the back of this report. .. - 16. - 3 1 FIGURE 5-4 HISTORICAL. CONDITIONS & PROJECTED IRRIGATED LAND AR.EA REQUIREMENTS IN CALIFORNIA .ir. .. -.i I I I I 0 .j -” 4 /-- II m Tp ”- ”0. 1930 ’ 1940 1950 1960 I970 1980 I990 2000 2010 2020 YE ARS . SOURCE: ‘DWR, 1974 1. -, i , Table 5-5 .. EXISTING (1972) AND PROJECTED AGGREGATED WATER SUPPLY n AND DEMAND AND ACREAGE UNDER IRRIGATION I Total Water Supplies . 30,700 3-0 36,400 -1 Alt'ernative Futures: I. Water demand (1,000 acre-feet) 1 total 37,400 46,200 55,300' I agricultural 31,700 37,900 41,900 all other uses 5,700 8,300 13,400 1 Acreage under irrigation (1,000 ac) 8,780 10,200 11,360 i 1972 19.90 2020 I .. - 11. Water demand (1,000 acre-feet) total 37,400 44,400 50,800 agricultural 31,700- 36,400 39,000 i all other uses 5,700 8,000 11,800 Acreage under irrigation (1,000 ac) 8,780 9,740 10,520 1 rf I 111. Water demand (1,000 acre-feet) total 37., 400 42,400 47,000 3 agricultural 31,700 34,600 36,100 1 all other uses .. 5', 700 7,800 10,900 Acreage under irrigation (1,000 ac) 8,780 9,380 9,850 1 total 37,400 41,100 42,900 agricultural 31,700 34,000 34,600 f all other uses 5,700 7,100 8;300 i IV. Water demand (1,000 acre-feet). c Acreage under irrigation (1,000 ac) 8,780 '9,190 '9,360 Source: DWR, 1974 .. . . " " . .. . . . . . . . . . " Agricultural production in Stanislaus County for. the years 1968-76 has been characterized by the consistent leader- ship of livestock and poultry products in production value. Furthermore, California's comparative advantage in the pro- duction of specialty crops is particularly evident in data i for the county: SAAG data (1976) show that Stanislaus is the state leader in the production of apricots, dry beans, boy- senberries, honeydew melons, green peas, red clover seed and chickens. .. Agricultural production requires inputs from many other ' industries and in turn provides inputs for transport, pro- cessing and marketing industries. The economic process by which agricultural production results in the generat'ion of income and employment in other industries is called the multiplier effect. Bas'ed on a multiplier of 2.2 (Goldman -18-. .. P ' and Strong, 1977) * the 1974 value of agricultural produc- tion of $500 million contributed a total $1.1 billion to Stanislaus County's economy.. .. Trends in Agricultural Land Conversion. Trends in agricultural land use become apparent upon examination of the changes in county land use over the past 20 years. Agri- cultural acreage declined from 882,446 acres in 1958 to 754,391 acres in 1977, a net decrease of 128,055 acres. This has been largely due to a change in status of rural lands from productive agricultural use as crop or range- land to .an idle or other unproductive status. At the same time, the county experienced an outward movement of ,orchards and vineyards. In many areas., orchards and vine- yards have been planted on lands used formerly for field crops., pasture or range. i. Some of the best agricultural lands in Stanislaus County are being irretrievably converted to urban and in- dustrial uses. SUG (1976) estimates that the Modesto- Ceres urban area occupied about 20,000 acres of mostly prime farmland (SCS definition) ih 1976, having absorbed about 500 acres of p'rime farmland annually between 1950 and 1975. Although not all of the areas zoned for urban uses in 1975 had actually been converted to those uses, their ihclusion within the boundaries of the urbanized area and the associated municipal obligation to provide them with urban services virtually assures their eventual conversion. . . The expansion of Stanislaus C.mnty's urban areas has . . displaced high value fruit and nut acreage and has had a ' detrimental effect on the countywide yield levels. for ' these crops. Although annual yields in the principal vegetable and field crop categories have increased sig- nificantly since 1960, yields in fruit and nut crops show a general decline during this period. In part, the decline may be attributable to the fact that. fruit and nut yields from young orchards are significantly lower during their first few years, before the trees reach full maturity. reflect the fact that many of the new orchards are on nonprime soils, and therefore yields are likely to be per- manently depressed, illustrating the price pai'd when best quality orchard and vineyard acreage is lost to urbaniza- tion. * However, declines in fruit and nut yields probably also . .. .. *SAAG, 1976 suggests a multiplier of 4. The Goldman and Strong data, gathered in 1974 but not publ'ished until 1977, show multipliers for agricultural commodities ranging from 1.5631 (milk production) to 2.3433 (onions); therefore, the use of the SAAG multiplier appears inappropriate. The multiplier of 2.2 used here is a weighted average combining the percentage distribution of local agricultural-lands (row crop, field crop. and pasture lands) by crop type (judgmental estimate by Armen V. Sarquis, County Director, U. S. Cooperative Extension). - - 19 - - - . .. -. , Prime farmland depletion is exacerbated, when leap- frogging or checker board urban development is allowed to take place. Under these conditions farm profitability is jeopardized both by increased taxes, as speculation raises land values, and hy cur'tailment of agricultural 'practices such .as fertilizer application and pest control to prevent the 'risk of hazards and nuisance to neighbor- hood *residents. The cost of expanded city services to these developed areas (sewer, police, fire and educational- facilities) may also have to be shared by the farmer. This scenario of urban growth and discontiguous develop- ment induces the farmer to intensi'fy farm practices to increase revenues,' to bear the cost of+..relocating, or t,o abandon farm operations altogether. Future Prospects for Agriculture in Stanislaus County. Projections of future prime farmland urbaniza- tion in Stanislaus County have been made by the state, and 20,800 acres are estimated to be subject to conver- sion between 1974 and 1985 (OPR, 1974). City of Modesto urban growth is forecast in this EIS to require 6,440 acres by the year 2000, resulting in the conversion of approximately 5,320 acres of prime.agricultura1 land. Urban growth elsewhere in Stanislaus would also result in agricultural land conversion. .. . There are about 24,800 acres in Stanislaus County with the potential for 'upgrading to prime (CLCA defini- tion) through normal zp-icultural investment and manage- ment practice (OPR, 1974). The amount of potential prime land under the SCS definition has net been estimated but would be lower, because SCS definition is more restrictive. ' There are no idle existing prime farmlands, as defined . by SCS, in Stanislaus County that could be used for' re- placement of lands lost to urbanization. Recognition of Prime Farmlands Preservation as a County- Issue. Stanislaus County has actively pursued a course of planning directed toward inhibiting the parceli- zation of rural lands and, their absorption by leapfrogging urban development since the"ear1y 1970!s.- More recently, the County Planning Department has initiated background studies for an agriculture element of the Stanislaus County General Plan.. The Stanislaus Area Association of Governments has prepared an agriculture data report (SAAG, 1976) as part of the Stanislaus Area Environmental Resources Management Element. Summary and Conclusions On the national, state and county levels, the con- tinuing reduction in the available supply of prime farm- land has aroused growing concern about future U. s. food and fiber production. - 20 - -1 1 3 -1. I -l 'I _. . On the national level, an irreversible. loss of approximately 1 million acres per year has been exper- ienced in recent times. Should this trend continue, the ability of the nation's agriculture to meet growing de-. mand - the world's popuXation.is expected to increase by over 50 percent to 6 billion by the year 2000 (United Nations, 1973) - may be in doubt. None of the future scenarios of the Worldwatch Institute presented earlier . in this chapter anticipate a need for less than 410 million acres of total cropland (10 million acres more than the current base) to meet domestic and export needs in the year 2000. With rising world demand for U. S. food products and increasing cropland losses, policy makers have be- come acutely aware of the nonrenewable nature of.agri- cultural land. This awareness has produced a drive to- ward federal legislation, exemplified in the Agricultural Land Retention Act, to prevent the unnecessary and irre- versible conversion of farmland to nonagricultural uses. Because of the considerable uncertainty over the future supply of productive cropland, future yields.and future demand for agricultural products, 'there is a .need to consider the costs and benefits of measure.s designed to preserve the prime agricultural land resources of the nation against continuing losses. At the state level, prime farmlands of the highest quality are currently being lost at. a rate of 25,000 to 55,000 acres per year. If this trend continues, up to 1,'2 million acres of prime land cotld possibly be absorbed . 'by urban and other types of development during the re-, mainder of this century. The uncertainties associated with potential shortages in future water supplies and the high cost of converting currently nonprime lands to irrigated cropland make unlikely at present the prospect of compensating for this prime land loss by reclamation of available reserve lands (OPR: 8 million acres; SCS: 4 million acres; most reclaimable Class I and I1 lands are in desert areas or scattered through coastal valleys). In Stanislaus County, there is a finite prime farm- land base of about 277,500 acres (SCS definition). Ur- banization of agricultural land in the Modesto-Ceres area has averaged about 500 acres annually over the last 20 years. No idle prime agricultural land (SCS definition) is available in the county to replace prime'acreage. Table 5-6 summarizes the present and potential supply of prime farmland in the county, state and nation. - 21 - . -i -. Table 5-6 PRESENT AND POTENTIAL PRIME FARMLAND COUNTY, STATE .AND NATION Stanislaus county California , United States Total prime farmland (acres) 277 , 500 9 , 000,000 384,000,0001 Prime farmland in cropland use 277,500 9,000,000 250,000,000 Land with immediate potential for upgrading to prime crop- O2 undetermined3 15,000,000 land status 'Land with long-run potential for upgrading to cropland a undetermined 4 , 000,000 96 , 000, 0005 status 5. 'This value includes all prime land resources in the county regardless of their present use. 2There is currently no idle farmland in Stanislaus County which meets the SCS definition of prime. 3Upgrading of nonprime lands to prime statns is contingent upon the con- struction of new water projects and irrigation water delivery systems, which'may be feasible on a long-run basis but not on a short-run basis. 4Soils in groups 2-4 as identified -in Appendix C could be reclaimed for orchards and vineyards but .they lack the 'broad.er versatility of lands on the valley floor. 5Both prime and nonprime lands with potential for conversion to cropland are included in this category. Source: Dideriksen,. 1977; Singer and Reganold, 1978; Houshang Esmaili Associates. Whichever geographical area-we'consider, the overall picture is similar: the prime agricultural land base is finite and the portion currently in production is diminish- ing. While lesser lands are available which. could be cul- tivated, impediments in terms of soil quality, water avail- - ability and access to public capital such as roads contribute to the cost associated with utilizing such- lands. For these reasons, preservation of prime agricultural lands has been advanced as a public objective. Future Conversion of Agricultural Land to Urban Use in the City of Modesto. The Effects of Federal Actions on Prime Land Resources ' Modesto shares with many other American cities the prospect of continued community growth anto agricultural lands. 'Past growth already has absorbea nearly 20,000 " 22 - 8 acres of farmland represented graphically on the map of the area's urbanization trends in the pocket at the back of this report. By 1950, the 'Modesto area (including Ceres, Salida*and Empire) occupied about 5,900 acres of what had been virtually all prime farmland. Another 4,200 acres were urbanized between 1950 and 1969, and an addi- tional 7,800 acres by 1975. Growth patterns, and the factors which encourage growth, are not all local in origin. Among federal actions in the past which have played a part in Modesto's growth are highway funding (rapid movement of goods up and down the Central Yalley on State Route 99 having -spurred food processors to serve western locations from Valley sites) and sewer funding. The Economic Develop- ment Administration, an agency of the U. S. Department of Commerce, provided 50% of the funding for planning and construction of Modesto's major sewer interceptor facili- ties in 1968-69. Federal government employment in the Mo- desto study area has increased dramatically. in recent years, more than doubling between 1970 and 1975. One of the purposes of this EIS was"to determine the extent to which the specific federal action currently contemplated - the funding of Modesto's wastewater facili- ties expansion - would contribute to the com.unity's con- tinued growth onto agricultural lands; and what the im- pacts of agricultural land conversion would be. The con- 'clusions were expected to provide guidance to.EPA, Mo- desto and other potential grantee communities as to the types and scale of impacts to.be expected from such EPA actions. The impacts disclosed by the analysis would, in turn, provide a yardstick against.which the adequacy of ' mitigation measures could be evaluated. Forecasting the Urbanization of Prime Farmland The conversion of agricultural lands to urban uses is a function of three factors: the amount of growth, the density of growth and the spatial distribution of growth. Each of these factors is, in principle, predict- able, although the availability of the kinds.of data needed to undertake a prediction varies among communities. Modesto together with Stanislaus County offers a recent history of strong local planning and of local data collection on land use patterns which greatly facilitated the analysis of urbanization trends. The city has had an urban growth policy since 1974; mandated annual reviews of this. policy patterns and issues; City Council review and discussion; and an'opportunity for participation and debate by the I I. involve technical reports -by city staff on growth trends, ! II "- - 23 - 'v \ i , general public. The reports prepared in connection with these policy reviews provide a wealth of information on community development patterns.. These reports are supple- ' mented by comprehensive land use surveys (1976 and 1978) and by special studies conducted by city staff. But al- thocgh Modesto's recent land development history .is un- usually well documented, most large cities (in excess of 25',000) in California's major agricultural areas appear to have basic land use and density statistics which would be applicable to comparable analyses. 1 The methodology applied in the case of 'Modesto in- volved preparation of a full forecast of population and .employment to the year.2000, these forecasts in turn serving as the basis for a forecast of land absorption by urban uses. The area delineated for forecas-ting pur- poses was larger than the City of Modesto - it had to be large enough to encompass all of the lands on which Modesto's current economic base is accommodated plus additional lands to be needed by residential and economic growth through the forecast period. Thus, the first out- put of the forecast .(which is presented in detail in Appendices A and B of the Draft EIS) was.a land use fore- cast for the Modesto socioeconomic study area. This fore- cast then served as the basis for the estimation of future land use change in the City of Modesto.2 Table' 5-7 pre- sents estimates of future urban land absorption in the socioeconomic study area and the City of Modesto to the year 2000. 'Gruen Gruen + Associates surveyed the 15 largest Central Valley and Delta Cities. Current basic density statistics can be calculated for a1.l 15 given existing data; residential density for 12. Vacant land estimates can be calculated for 13 and vacant residential land for 11. ,2While the overall forecast covered an area more extensive than the city, a city forecast was also needed both because the city is the focus of the project and because the City of Modesto is the agency directly responsible for both impacts and mitigation measures. The translation of impacts from the larger study area to the smaller city involved a number of interpretations'and assumptions as discussed in Appendix A of the 'Draft EIS (pp. A-55 to A-56). Among factors affecting city (as distinguished from study area) growth, the mokt important is probably annexation decisions. .- 24 - . e. L .. _. Table 5-7 I FUTURE URBAN LAND ABSORPTION IN' EIS SOCIOECONOMIC STUDY AREA-AND IN CITY OF MODEST0 . 1979-2000 Socio- economic Study Area 1990 - Total Popula- tion' 171,720 New Population' 21,300 Added Dwelling Units2 14,710 Land Absorption (gross acres) : Residential 3,040 Commercial 180 Industrial 325 Park/Public 325 Total 3,870 2000 202 , 670 52,250 28 , 090 5 800 440 800. 795 7,835 4 City of .Modesto At Project Capacity Initial Planned Construction Future . Capacity Const. Cap. 1990 2000' (1984) (1995) 129,100 162,300 112,750 145,000 20,900 48,100 10,100 25,950 6. 9,530 22 , 060 3,360.. 15 530 1,970 4 , 560 180 410 .I 320 740 320 . 7 30 2,790 6,440 695 90 155 15 5 1,095 3,210 305 555 545 4 , 615 'Limitations on the accuracy of city population forecasts are discussed in Appendix A of the Draft EIS , pp. A-55 and A-56. The same limitations apply to the land absorption forecasts. " 'Between January 1, 1979 and project capacity 'year. 3Average residential density used in the forecast is 4.84 dwelling units per gross acre. This is slightly lower #an the current density of 5.1 units per gross acre (6.8 units/net acre) reflecting (I) slowly rising real income and (2) the historical relationship between income levels and the mix of single- and multi-family units in the Modesto housing supply. . ~ ., .. . Source: Gruen Gruen + Associates The EIS forecast is presented in Table 5-7 as a point estimate. That estimate lies within a range, the extremes of which vary with alternative employment assumptions.* The EIS forecast being somewhat lower than prior growth projections *The lower end of the range represents the attainment of an unemployment rate - of 6% by the year 2000 and a.decline from 1.1 to :.OS in the number of employed local. residents per locally-employed local resident; the higher end represents a 10% unemployment rate and an increase in the ratio just described from 1.1 to 1.2. These assumptions are discussed in Appendix A of the Draft EIS, p. A-51.. -25" c -. . ,- : prepared for Modesto and the county, an alternative (higher) future population figure* is provided for comparative pur- poses, permitting an evaluation of the implications of greater growth than the EIS analysis forecast. Both of the'future growth estimates are translated into land ab- sorption estimates (Table 5-7 represents the EIS forecast, but not the alternative) and these land absorption estimates are in turn translated into estimates of the conversion of prime agricultural land to urban use between 1979 and 2000 (the Draft EIS contained similar estimates for 1976-2000). Table 5-8 presents three series of estimates of agri- cultural land conversion which reflect different magnitudes . of growth and different densities of future residential de- . velopment. Estimates are presented for the years in which .initial and planned future construction project capacities are .reached and for the year 2000. The latter 'are provided only for background and do not signify estimated impacts of the project. Table 5-8 MODESTO URBAN LAND NEEDS AND AGRICULTURAL AND TWO ALTERNATIVE GROWTH SCENARIOS, 1979-2000 LAND CONVERSION ESTIMATES UNDER THE EIS FORECAST (Low population, Scenario 1 high density) - 1984' 1995' Urban laand Needs "- Total Population 112,750 145,000 162,300 New Population 10,100 35,950 . 48.100 Added Dwelling Units 3,360 15,530 22,060 Residential Density' 7 du/gross acre Land Absorption (gross acres) 880 3,625 5,030 Agricultural Land Conversion , lnfill Development 880 3,625 4,000 On Ag Land (75%) 660 2,720 3,000 On Other Undeveloped Land (25%) 2 20 905 1,000 Othcr Development _, 0 0 1.030 On Ag Land (95%) Ii8 0 On Other Undeveloped 50 Land (5%) Total Agricultural Land Converted to 660 2,720 3,980 Urban Use EIS Forecast Scenarib 2 low density) low density) (Low population, (High population, 1984' 1995' E __ 1983' 1992' E 112,750 145,000 162,300 113,450 148.000 176,650 10.100 35,950 48,100 11,300 40,050 62,450 3,360 15,530 22,060 ' 3,630 16,670 27,480 4.84 du/gross acre 4.84 du/gross acre 1,095 4,615 6,440 1,090 4,650 7,560 c 1,095 4,000 4,000 1.090 4.000 4,000 820 3,000 3.000 880 3,000 3,000 275 1,000 1,000 210 1,000 1,000 0 615 2,440 0 650 3,560 585 2,320 .. ' , 620 ' 3,380 30 120 30 180 830 . 3,585 5,320 820 3,620 6.380 'The year io which planned future construction project capacity would be reached. 'The year in which initial construction project capacity would he reached. 'The low density estimate is explained in note 2 to Table 5-7. The higher denslty wuld represent a movement by Modesto toward more dense residential development in the.future. which is Current city policy. Source: Gruen Gruen t Associates .. *The basis of the alternative figure is an estimate by the California Department of Finance (DOF) of future Stanislaus County population given a 2.1 fertility rate and.an annual net inmigration of 150,000 persons to California. This E-150 county projection was adapted to the socio- economic study area and to the city by Grucn .Gruen + Associates a's described in Appendix A of the Draft EIS, pp. A-55 and A-.56. - 26 - The urban land absorption estimates' presented in Table 5-8 will not necessarily result in a one-for-one conversion of agricultural land. How much agricultural land will be converted will depend on the location of urban development: will'it take place on prime agricultural land or on lands less valuable from an agricultural use perspective? This question of spatial distribution 'is the third - major determinant of agricultural land loss. In Modesto, the question is somewhat easier to answer than it might be in other communities. That is because nearly 100 percent of the land surrounding Modesto is categorized as prime agricultural land (see Figure 5-5). However, land within 'the area that the city has com- mitted to short-term development (the current sewer service area, or CSSA), unless it is still in active agyicultural production, was not considered prime ag land in this analysis. Of the land the city has committed to long- term development (the ultimate sewer'service area, or USSA), 95 percent was assumed to be prime agricultural land. The agricultural land conversion estimates in Table 5-8 there- fore show urban development as taking place either at infill sites (within the CSSA) where 75 percent of the urban de- ve1,opment would result in ag land conversion, or at other sites (in the USSA) where the proportion would be 95 percent. Impacts of Prime Agricultural Land Conversion There -ire a number of possible consequences of agri- cultural land conversion which would vary in importance depending upon the context. Changes may take place in local microclimate, in groundwater recharge, in runoff, in air quality and in a variety of other areas typically classed as "environmental". In the specific case of Modesto, however., the most important effects-of agricultural land conversion were felt to be economic, fiscal and social, and each of these areas was considered in the analysis. Economic'1mpacts:of Agricultural Land Conversion. The economic impact of agricultural land conversion is measured .in terms of reduced. incomes and jobs .in the agriculture -sector, and the indirect effect of those reductions on the -rest of the local economy. The magnitude of impact depends on the number of current jobs and the amount of income associated with the acres predicted to be converted, which is a function principally of the type of agricultural use involved. Table 5-9 presents a rough estimate of the effect of forecast agricultural land conversion on,the local economy. This.estimate is based on the average value per acre of crop production in the immediate Modesto area, which was about $965 in 1977. .. . .- - 27 - -- . . .. I. .. Table 5-9 ' ESTIMATED ECONOMIC IMPACTS OF MODESTO AGRI~ULTURAL LAND CONVERSION: POINT ESTIMATES FOR 1990, 2000' AND IMPACT YEAR (all estimates except acreage in thousands) Scenario 1 EIS Forecast Scenario 2 . (Low population, (Low population, (High population, high density) low density) low density) 1984' 199S2. " 2000 . 1984' 1995' 2000 1983' 19922 . 2000 Acreage Converted 600 2,720 3,980 820 3,585 5,320 820 3,620 6,380 . Value of Displaced Crop.Production $640 $2,620 $3,840 '$790 $3,460 $5,130 $790 $3,490 $6,160 ($965/acre3) Indirect Income Loss (Multiplier $770 $3,140 $4,610 $950 $4,150 $6,160 $950 $4,190 $7,390 = 2.2'+) .. Total Annual LOSS $5,760 $8,450 $1,740 $7,610 $11,290 $1,740 $7,680 $13,550 'The point in time at which initial construction capacity would be reached. '2Tne point in time at which planned future construction project. capacity would be reached. .3This estimate is a weighted average combining the percentage distribution of agricul- tural lands by crop type (judgmental estimate by Armen.V. Sarquis, County Director, U. C. Cooperative Extension) and the average value of production per acre in each kind of agricultural use in 1977 (Stanislaus County, 1978): peaches, 25 percent ($1,700); grapes, 20 percent ($786); walnuts, 15 percent ($1,202); field crcqx, 15 percent ($321); almonds, 10 percent ($1,166); pasture,-10 percent ($95); rice, 5 percent ($540); over- all average per acre,.$965. 4University of Californin Cooperative Extension data collected in 1974 and published in 1977 show multipliers €or agricultural commodities in Stanislaus County ranging from 1.5631 (milk production) to 2.3433 (onions). The multiplier of 2.2 used here is a weighted average combining multipliers for the commodities indicated in the preceding note. Indirect effects are calculated by multiplying 1.2 times direct effects. - Source: Gruen Gruen + Associates Along with the income los's, the area would experience a reduction in agricultural employment. For the EIS study area as a whole, that. reduction has been forecast as 1,000 jobs between 1975 and 2000' (2;800 agricultural jobs in 1975; 1,800 agricultural jobs in the year .2000). The higher density development scenario (Scenario 1) would help preserve these jobs; the reduction would be cut from about 1,000 to about 750. Scenario 2 would increase ur- banization's toll on agricultural employment: upwards of 1,450 agricultural jobs migh.t be lost. These job losses in the agricultural sector would induce job losses in other sectors as well as via the multiplier effect. In all, economic impacts of the conversion of agricultural land associates with the project could range from $8.4 million - 29 - ,- , , ". to $10.9 million per year by the time ultimate capacity ' of the planned future construction is absorbed (the EIS forecast is $11.2 million) and from $11.8.million to $17.8 million by the year 2000 ($15..5 million .is the EIS fore- cast). The job loss described would not show up in economic statistics as an overall decline in area employment. The conversion of agricultural land to urban use would have . short-term economic impacts resulting from construction : .of the housing, commercial or industrial structures which .{: impacts in terms of expanding the number of permanent - positions in the growing sectors-of the economy. However, . whether specific indhiduals whose agricultural employ- ment opportunities are reduced by agricultural land con- version will find suitable employment in other 'economic sectors is not known. .- 'would replace agriculture. It would also have long term 6. Conversion of the agricultural land closest to Modesto is unlikely to halt the area's economic expansion. Even the food processing industry, which is the major industry most closely linked to local agricultural pro- duction, is not strongly dependent on Stanislaus County crop and livestock production. While about two-thirds -of the manufacturing employment in Stanislaus County is in the canned, cured and frozen foods and food processing industries (Califo?nia Employment Development Department, 1976), these industries are not dependent on local agri- ..culture alone. .In fact, only about 10 percent of total payments and purchases of these industries in Stanislaus. County went to agriculture within the county in 1974, while 39 percent went to purchases outside of the county and payments. to governments outside the county (Lee, 1975). These relationships indicate that Stanislaus County is an element of a larger regional economy, so that the interdependence of local industry and local agriculture is not as great as might be supposed. .. Pressures for urban growth throughout California's' Central Valley may have begun to result in declining agri-, cultural production such that in the long run (i.e., beyond related industries and services in the Modesto area may no longer thrive. Such a change would be analogous to the . decline in agriculture-related industry in Los Angeles in the middle third of the twentieth century and the more recent decline of agriculture-related industry in the Santa Clara Valley. But, in neither Los Angeles nor San Jose has agriculture-related industry disappeared; the lag is very long. The analysis undertaken for this EIS does not forecast-the demise of the food processing industry .in Modesto during the '25-year period ending in 2000. If .the year 2000) food processing and other agriculture- .' - 30 L - ~ ~ "_ ~ ~~-~ ~ , the preservation of a strong agricultural'base and associated industries is to be accomplished in the long run, then reduc- tion in the amount of agriculturally-productive lands must be minimized. However, this study has not identified a. of agriculture. in the San Joaquin Valley is irretrievably lost. , "threshold of no return"'beyond which the long term viability Fiscal Impacts of Agricultural Land Conversion. Agri- cultural land is widely believed to be a fiscal asset to local government: . it is thought to generate an excess of public revenues (primarily property taxes) over costs (public service requirements). This belief has frequently been supported by studies which compare the costs and revenues associated with a particular agricultural acreage to those resulting from resident-ial development which takes place on that acreage. One such study in the Modesto area (Uni- versity of California, Davis, 1973) found that agricultural land use was more "profitable" to local public agencies than the same acreage of residential and neighborhood com- mercial use. The conclusions of such studies are gene.rally limited to the specific parcels of land being studied; the off-site implications of agricultural vs. residential uses are often ignored. For example, in considering the fiscal impact of agriculture one should. consider the co-sts of servicing the employees, owners and their dependents associated with agri- culture and the land their residences occupy, less the rever?ues they contribute, in addition to the costs and revenues associated with the agrimltural land itself. The same principle holds when assessing the fiscal'impact of residential land use. Residential development is generally associated with industrial and commercial (and agricultural) employment and land use;.therefore, the costs and revenues associated with these activities should be included in the I i proper proportions along with the cos.ts and costs and revenues I directly associated with residential development. (The Goldman and Strong analysis cited previously includes some commercial land use associated with residential development, but not in proportion to actual urban nonresidential land use in the Modesto area. ) The development of an individual land use, whatever the use involved, does not take place in a vacuum. Just as new industrial development implies added housing elsewhere in a community for those who will be employed at the new plant, so the construction of residences in one part of an economic subregion implies that new industrial and commercial land uses are being developed elsewhere in the area. - 31 - , In a specific local area - a rural school district, for example - urban development in the form of residences housing school-age children.may well be a fiscal burden compared to the orchards t-hey replace, when seen from the narrow local perspective. If the impact of new develop- ment were viewed regionally, what we would rn0s.t likely see is that one public agency is getting the highly- . concentrated costs of new development, while the benefits (sale tax revenues, for example) are going elsewhere. Each new development in a Modesto rural school district ' illuminates again the problems created when the costs and revenues of development are un.equally distributed among jurisdictions. However, this problem is an arti- fact of local government finance: it does not "prove" that ' agriculture is always a more fiscally-benefici-a1 use than housing. There is no standard answer to that. question; each case would have to be considered for itself. The only generalization possible in this post-Proposition 13 period is that neither agriculture nor urban land use generates as much property tax revenue as it used to. - Social Impacts of Agricultural Land Conversion. One of the effects of asricultural 1and.conversion in and around Modesto is the continued diminution in the number of small family farms. .Average farm size in .the .Sari Joaquin Valley has risen steadily in receilt years, and larger farms are generally agreed to be more efficient economically. Thus, as small farms are eliminated, they are unlikely to be replaced. Many of the impediments to *the establishment of small farms have been identified in a a recent California study (California Employment Develop- ment Department, 1977). Loss of rural values and the rural lifestyle are. accompanied, as cities like Modesto grow onto agricultural land, by changes in the character of the urban community. Opportunities to participate in civic affairs may be re- duced as city size increases. There may 'be an increasing sense of imper.sonality, and even a decreasing confidence in personal secu-rity as LaLcity growsr While growth may also.-bring new opportunities -'culturai as well as economic the changes may not be attractive to everyone. Many of these implications of' growth were discussed in one of the Modesto Alternative Futures Symposia (January 16, 1978). - 32 .- Mitigation of Agricultural Land Conversion Introduction The Modes.to wastewater facilities expansion would accpmmodate the conversion of an estimated 3,945. to 5,290 acres of prime agricultural land to urban use if no additional measures are taken to mitigate such con- version. Mitigation of prime agricultural land conver- sion is the subject of the remainder of this chapter. Adverse Impact on Prime Agricultural Land Requires Mitigation. Loss of prime agricultural land to urban uses is a frequently-observed indirect impact of public facili- 'ties investments in agricultural areas. It is EPA'S intention to minimize the impact of its programs in re- ducing the mount of prime agricultural land. 'The policy of the agency is to protect, through the administration and implementation of its programs and regulations, the nation's environmentally-significant agricultural land from irreversible conversion to uses which result in its loss as an environmental or essential food production resource. .. Urban Expansion in AgricuZturaZ Areas. For many reasons, cities have tended to be established in agri- cultural regions. As urban areas have grown, they have expanded onto lands formerly in agricultural production. Because Modesto is surrounded by agricultural land, the city's expansion would result in cjditional loss of prime . agricultural lands to industrial, public, commercial and especially residential development. Other cities.in agricultural areas may be less hemmed in by high-quality or unique agricultural lands, and may, correspondingly, have greater flexibility in direct.ing growth so as to . minimize agricultural land impacts. No EPA Funding if Prime Agricultura 2 Land Impacts Are Not Mitigated. EPA's funding of facilities providing Modesto with additional wastewater treatment capacity would .allow growth to occur, and that growth would take place largely on prime agricultural land. EPA requires that-no funding be awarded for projects which would enable ''new habitations or other establishments" to be located on prime agricultural lands unless mitigated to the maxi- mum extent possible. Identifving and ImpZementing Mitigation Measures. To implement its prime agricultural land policy, EPA re- views municipal waste treatment grant applications to search for methods of mitigating the effects of agency- assisted activities on significant agricultural lands. EPA may propose types of local mitigation measures which could be taken, and the Draft EIS presented an inventory of possible measures for consideration. - 33 - . The responsibility for selecting a mitigation program rests with the grantee. In this case, the City of Modesto proposed a package of mitigation measures to EPA (to be presented in the last section of this chapter) which the city believes represents the maximum effort currently fehsible to respect prime agricultural land retention ob- jectives while permitting the orderly growth of the com- muni ty . Local implementation measures, in Modesto or elsewhere, :should be locally enforceable, with little or no ongoing -partic.ipation by EPA. But local measures'need to be sup- plemented by actions at the state and federal levels as .well. It is importaqt to recognize that agricultural land conservation is a regional and national problem; local agencies, even with the best intentions and the most sound planning approaches, cannot unilat&"rally effect farmland retention. State and federal agencies need to develop their awareness of the agricultural land conver- sion phenomenon and work, both separately and together, ,,to develop positive strategies for dealing.with it. Some nonlocal measures which might be taken on the state and federal levels are described in this section .. of the EIS. Strategies for Mitigating Prime Agricultural Land Conversion. Mitigation .is the alleviation of .a condition which has exceeded a threshold of tolerability. Determining Whether Prime AgricuZturaZ Land Loss is a MitigatcbZe Irnoact. The threshold of tolerability of . adverse impacts may be established at different levels 'by different observers. In .the case of the air.pollutant sulfur dioxide, for example, the federal government and the State of California have established different standards. Those standards effectively represent thresholds at which the two governments respectively consider that the impact of air pollution has become so adverse (severe) as to necessitate reduction (mitigation). The amount of sulfur dioxide in an air basin could potentially be reduced enough to comply with federal standards - thereby achieving 100% mitigation - while eliminating only part of the pollution required to comply with state standards. Some impacts may, either by their nature or with reference to a standard, be non-mitigatable. The elimina- tion of a wildlife species, for cxamp1e;is a non-mitigatable impact: it cannot be reduced, ameliorated or neutralized except by preventing the impact. Or, to look again' at air pollution from sulfur dioxide, if the clean air standard were set such that the pollutant-free quality of a particular - 34 .- -. basin must be maintained, then the discharge of any sulfur dioxide into that basin would constitute a- non-mitigatable adverse impact. The documented loss of prime agricultural land and the'irreversibility of that loss has stimulated the federal government to require mitigation of future losses where federal funds are involved. Neither EPA nor the Departme-nt of Agriculture (USDA) has at present determined that agri- cultural l.and conversion is a nan-mitigatable impact (al- though in a crisis situation both government and popular thinking would probably support that view)'. Instead, the federal government's current approach is to acknowledge that there are alternative ways of completing a project and . that those alternatives may have different effects on the environment. r. With regard to the direct impacts of a wastewater treatment facility, a key question might be whether the site chosen is on prime agricultural land or would adversely affect agricultural operations on nearby lands. With regard to indirect impacts, a key question would be whether the grantee municipality can demonstrate.,that it is taking all possible measures to reduce the conversion of agricul- tural land resulting from the growth accompodated by a wastewater treatment- facility expansion. Concepts of Mitigating Agricultural Land Conversion. Mitigation measur,es responding to agricultural land conver- sion may be classified according Lo two major.criteria: Directing Urban Development vs. Enhancing Agricuzture 's Survival PotentiaZ. The latter type of measure would make agricultural uses economically more competitive with urban ones, thereby assisting farmland owners in resisting pressures for conversion. The former type of measure would reduce the ability of urban uses. to demand conversion/absorption of prime agricultural land. Regulations us. Incentives. Regulations either direct that an action occur or prohibit' it from occurring, subject to penalties. Incentives, in contrast, offer rewards for specified.-types of behavior or actions, but do not impose penalties for noncompliance. The reservation of a resource for the encouraged use is one kind of incentive. In general, mitigation measures are either urban- or agriculture-oriented and are either regulations or incentives. Most of the measures inventoried in this chapter are directed toward guiding urban'expansion; those designed to enhance agriculture's resistance to conversion constitute about - 35 - .. 1 one-fourth of measures discussed. About half a.f the measures presented are regulatory in approach, while the other half are incentives. The matrix of. mitigation. measures (Table 5-10, p. 86) classifies all the measures discussed according to approach. Purpose of the Mitigation Measures Invenkorg. The miti- gation measures inventory presented in this EIS is intended to be a comprehensive compilation of approaches to agricul- tural...land retention at all levels of government. An exten- sive literature review and interviews with .agricultural land experts in government, research and the-private sector sup- , plied most of the measures on the list; additional measures were suggested by the EIS consulting team and EPA staff. Inventory is Exhaustive. An effort was made to include in the inventory all the classes of mitigation measures known to exist or to have been proposed, regardless of their poli- tical feasibility, likely effectiveness or cost. Inventory is EvaZuative. Each type of measure is dis- cussed in terms of its likely effectiveness in addressing 'agricultural land retention objectives. I,deally, such a discussion would be able to draw upon sound research into the effects of specific measures in the contexts in which they have been implemented-, providing 'longitudinal and/or cross-sectional comparisons leading to valid conclusions concerning the degree to which agricultural land retention is attributable specifically to a given regulation, policy or' other measure. Unfortunately, research of this kind on ' . . farmland preservation has been practically nonex:stent;. even programs for which the most vigorous claims of success have been asserted-generally have not been subjected to a thorough- going impact analysis. For this reason, the effectiveness evaluations presented here are based primarily on the analytical perspective of land economics rather than on field research. . Measures Discussed Vary in Net Effectiveness. The direct ' effect of a mitigation measure may be to preserve land in agricultural use in a given area. However, that benefit may be offset if the regulation or policy which produces it also locations. Presumably, the governing objective is total agricultural land retention. If it were found that the effect of Modesto's mitigation measures was to shift development to other prime agricultural lands in Stanislaus County,, the net effectiveness of such measures would be doubtful. Where such a shift - locally described as "spillover" - transfers development from a more restrictive (e.g., higher density requirements) to a less restrictive development environment, the outcome may well be less desirable than what would have 'results in a displacement of development pressures to other - 36 - resulted if the measure causing the shift had not been imple- mented. In .general, the more extreme a unilateral munici- pal measure, the more likely'that spillover development will re- sult. Those mitigation measures which appear strongest may have a poor net effectiveness if implemented in only one citi; their effectiveness would be greatly increased if imple- mented on a regional basis. Inventory Does Not Consider Economic Costs. Mitigation of prime agricultural land conversion is not a cost-free policy. Incentive measures may be readily.seen to have costs associated with them; for example, if the farmland owner .pays lower taxes, other taxpayers will have to pay more. Regulatory measures a130 have cost effects. For-example, .if a city limits the supply of buildable land by zoning most undeveloped land for agriculture, the price of'remaining land will rise sharply and be reflected in higher housinq prices. In general, the costs involved are direct monetary costs: higher taxes and higher prices for housing and other land-related goods. It has been pointed out that the effectiveness of many of the measures inventoried has not been'adequately field- tested. The same observation can be made about the costs of agricultural land retention measures: the magnitude and incidence of costs imposed and benefits conferred have rarely been estimated. The preparation of a full cost/benefit analysis of agricultural land retention and of alternative implementation measures is one of the recommendations of . decisionmaking relating to farmland at all levels of govern- men t. .. this EIS. Such an analysis would be a helpful guide to .. The inventory does not address the question of economic costs. The reader should keep in mind the fact that agri- cultural land retention would impose costs, and the benefits of any given measure would have to be evaluated in relation- ship to the specific costs associated with it. Organization of the Inventory. Mitigati,on measures have been grouped into eight major categories. Each of the groups of. measures is presented in-the same format: .the rationale of the whole class of measures is first described, and then each individual measure is discussed separately. Each discussion is organized under 'four headings: theory , which describes the basis for proposing a given approach; impzementing agency, which may be local, state or federal government or some combination; application, which describes the specific means of implementation; and effectiveness, which discusses how and the extent to which the measure would affect the net amount of farmland retained. '. Table 5-10 (p. 96) " 37 -. - - .. , .. provides a summary and indicates the page numbers on which each of the measures is discussed. The mit.igation measures are numbered within each major category to facilitate refer- ence to them. Mitiaation Measures Inventorv * . Each subsection below addresses a family of mitigation measures; lettered headings indicate the major thrust of the measures in that family. A. 'Affect. the Amount of Urban Development Rationale. Development of prime agricultural lands into urban uses is a major cause of diminution of the prime agri- cultural land resource. Limiting the amount of urban develop- ment permitted would limit agricultural land losses. 1. Limit the Amount of Land Zoned for Urban DeveZopment. 1 Theory 1 Land becomes a potential location for urban development county or city in which it is located. That entitlement - the authorization to be de.veloped into a specified use - is generally contained in the zoning ordinance, and the zoning cateqory to which the land is assigned iden- tifies the types of uses which may be developed on it. Land not zoned for urban uses must obtain such zoning prior to development. . when it receives an entitlement for urban use from the [ ImpZementing Agency 1 -. Local general purpose government. Limit the amount of land classified in zoning categories which permit urban uses (such as residential,-commercial, industrial). Assign the remaining land to zoning cate- gories which permit only agricultural or open space uses. Many observers of ,rural land use change believe that rural residential development is one of the greatest threats to agricultural land resources. Zoning provisions limiting urban uses to urban areas can. be very effective in addressing this problem. In Stanislaus County, the county's commitment to maintaining exclusive agricultural zoning on unincorporated lands has virtually halted rural - 30 - . .. .. . . .. .. .. ., I_ subdivision activity. Developers wishing to subdivide rural land near Modesto must annex to Modesto and comply with the city's development regulations, which limit available locations for urban uses. , It is possible that-strict observance of agricultural zoning in.one jurisdiction will displace rural residential .development to less strict neighboring jurisdictions. To avoid this kind of spillover, adjacent counties should coordinate their rural residential development policies. Counties can also make provisions for rural residential development in non-agricultural areas. From the cities' perspective, it is important that urban zoning allow sufficient land for development to prevent significant displacement to nearby communities or to rural areas. Urba'n zoning which falls short of the effective dernand for land for urban development will cause displacement, which would be counter-productive lands in ..other areas. .. -. , -if the displaced uses are located on prime agricultural 2. Limit the Number of Building Permits Issued. -1 -More than the proper zoning is required to entitle urban development. The jurisdiction in which the land is loca- allows construction on the property in question (and without which no construction is allowed). * ted has the power. to issue a'building permit, which I Imp Zementing AqeneyA Local general purpose government. 1 Application 1 Issue only a limited number of building permits per year. To limit the amount of development, the number of permits issued would have to be lower than the number requested. Permits need not be issued on a ,first-come, first-served basis; rather, the city could review all development proposed within a spec.ified time period according to a given set of criteria and award permits to those which best satisfy the criteria. ['Effectiveness ] This measure operates by controlling directly the amount of development. Its direct effects in retaining agricul- tural land can be very strong, depending on the location and size of sites for which building permits are issued. Many cities have implemented this approach in order to limit the pace of.population growth. Petaluma, California was one of the first cities to implement a plan for limiting the number o,f building permits issued each year. . The so-called Petaluma Plan limits the number of new - 39 - dwellings in developments of, more than €our units to 500 per year. The permits are not issued on a first- come, first-served basis: rather, the proposed develop- ments are reviewed by the city for design and other quality-related criteria, and the developments gaining the most-points are awarded the permits. The discretionary authority of the city to select the development plans with greatest merit could be used to encourage develop- ments which least interf.ere with agricultural land use. . Building permit limitations are effective in encouraging .' the quality or characteristics of development desired in proportion to the degree that development demand ex- ceeds the permit quota. To the same degree, however, they also encourage spillover by shifting development pressures to less restrictive locations. 3. Limit Industria2 Growth Generators. .r pzZGj-1 The major generator of urban growth is expansion of the employment base. Those who come.to fill new jobs seek housing and other urban uses near their.'jobs. If in- dustrial growth were limited, then other urban growth would be abated. I Implementing AgeEcp 1 Lodal general purpose government. I AvpZication 1 For arehs with zoning, reassign land currently zoned for industrial use to other land use categories, thereby limiting potential sites for new industries.. . Other approaches include: , (a) restructuring the schedufe of business' license fees - e. g. , charge according to' the number of employees - to penalize industries which employ many workers or ' , .. (b) use city payro1,l. taxes to discourage industries with many employees from; choosing local sites. - .. I Effectiveness j *.. Discouraging employment growth as a means of inhibiting urban population growth is an indirect approach to re- ducing the amount' of prime agricultural land ultimately converted. Effectiveness therefore depends on a chain of events; farmland retention would not be achieved if new industrial development continued on currently- underutilized parcels or if business and payroll taxes were not high enough to neutralize the other advantages of a local site;'if industries located on nearby, i ! '/ ! ! I. 4 . ,. . -. unrestricted sites and their employees chose to live in local residences: or if the fewer'resulting local employees, finding less competition and consequent . lower prices for homesites, occupied more land per household than they' would have in the absence of deterrents to local growth. B. Affect the Density of Development Rationale. The amount of land absorbed by urban de- velopment depends not only on the amount of growth to be -accomplished but also on the density of the development. If the density at which urban development takes place .were increased, the amount of agricultural land lost would be 'reduced. "A There are three major density situations affecting farmland,-two urban and one rural. One kind of low-density urban development pattern is continuous large lots: be- cause each. lot occupies so much space, few lots can fit in a given area. The compensation for this type of low density development is to allow or mandate higher densities. *. A second kind of low density urban development occurs where smaller-sized or average-sized lots are scattered through a large area. The existing development extends over much land without actually occupying some of it; the un- occupied portions, however, may become unfit for agricul- tural use because they are surr.ounded by urban uses. The remedy for this type of low density development is infilling . , the vacant parcels. .. Finally, rural areas often are subject to inefficient residential development patterns. The remedy for that 'situation is a change in approach-to regulating the loca- tion and density of rural development. Measures to Affect the Density of Development. 1. Low Minimum Lot Sizes in Urban Areas. Zoning controls not only the use which may be established on a.given parcel of land but also the physical character- istics of that use. Among the physical characteristics commonly governed by zoning are size of lot;-height, bulk and placement of buildings; and number of parking spaces. These characteristics can be regulated in ways that will-increase urban densities. LrnpZementinq Agency Local general purpose government. 1 AppZication Reduce the minimum lot size allowed in residential zones. - 41 - Reduction of lot sizes allows developers to fit more dwelling units in a given amount of area or, conversely, to accommodate a given number of dwelling units in a smaller area. Be,cause smaller lots are only allowed and not mandated, however, ef.fectiveness depends on the public's willingness to accept .smaller lots. 2. High Minimum Lot Sizes in Rural Areas. . [-J Just as harmful to agricultural uses of prime lands as their replacement by urban uses is the parcelization of rural lands. Parcelization - the division of larger rural parcels into plots which are too small to be farmed economically - is encouraged.when large-lot rural homesites are feasible alternativ*es to in-town residential sites. Scattered rural residential de- velopment may absorb or render unsuitable for agri- culture more land per housing unit than concentrated urban development. f Implementing Aqeney 1 Local general purpose government with jurisdiction over rural lands. .. [ Application 1 Establish minimum lot sizes in rural areas which are too large to be affordable for single-family homes. L EffectzGness 1 Where minimum lot. sizes are large enough., they will make the-price of a-single-family house and lot sig- nificantly higher than that asked for the most desirable homes in the existing ur5an area, which will discourage rural parcelization for residential use. For maximum effectiveness, large minimum lots must be required in all prime land areas near enough to the employment base for feasible commuting. .. . .. 3. Maximum Lot Sizes in Urban Areas. - , .. Zoning regulations typically specify minimum lot sizes but'rarely establish maximum lot sizes. Establishment of a maximum lot size would help prevent very low den- sity development. 1 Implementing Aqencq I mcai general purpose government. - 42 - . .- , Specify in the zoning ordinance maximum allowable lot sizes 'in urban areas in addition to minimum sizes, setting the maximum at a level which will allow for size variations demanded by market forces as well as those necessitated by'subdivision design features such as cul-de-sacs, curves and corner lots. I'Effectiueness \ By establishing and enforcing a maximum land area for individual lots smaller than what would otherwise be built, the zoning ordinance would limit the amount of ' land which could be occupied by any individual resi- dence and thus will increase overall urban density. .Consumers seeking large lots may, however, purchase ranchettes or 10-acre parcels in rural areas in out- lying- jurisdictions or larger Lots - potentially on prime.land - in neighboring urban areas; these spill- over effects would reduce the effectiveness of this measure. 4. Minimum Neighborhood Densities in Urban Areas. -1 Increases in urban residential densities can be achieved not.only on a lot-by-lot basis but also on a larger area - for instance, a neighborhood - basis. The 1atter.approach would allow for variation in individual housing arrangements while still achieving -an overall increase in density. [ Implementing Aaencg f - Local general purpose government. . AppZication ] Use the zoning ordinance, the general plan or neighbor- hood prototype plans to specify minimum. densities.for each neighborhood. Allow .the, minimums to' be achieved through a combination of lot sizes and single-family/ multiple-family confi.gurations; The zoning districts. should be defined as density districts, so that the owner.of a double lot developed for a single unit per- manently retains the right to develop a second unit on the site,. The same principle applies to higher-density districts which may initially be developed at lower- than-permitted densities. [ Effectiveness J ;. Neighborhoods' would be composed of a number of residential developments, and homogeneity of. housing type could be maintained within individual developments if desired, while varying among developments within a given neighborhood .to both meet density. objectives and offer - 43 - sufficient variety in the housing st0c.k to satisfy differing consumer needs and preferences. A minimum neighborhood density helps assure that overall city .density objectives will be considered as each resi- dential development project comes up for approval. This approach is most effective €or newly-developing areas rather than existing neighborhoods, where infill strategies are more suitable. 5. InfiZZ DeveZovment in Urban Areas. pGziJ _, :. .. . . Discontinuous small lot 'development leaves vacant land amid the pockets of development. It may be remedied underutilized sites in already-developed areas. . by directing new development to available vacant or [ Implementing Agency 1 *. Local -general purpose government .... . [ AppZication 1 Identify potential sites for infill development, and encourage infill through: (a) restrictions, such'as refusing to zone additional other lands for urban use or refusing to provide urban services (such as sewers, water, police and fire protection) to new areas; or (b) incentives, such as allowing high densities or waiving development fees. ] Ef-fectiveness ] Parcels in an urban are'a which remain vacant while the land around them develops often have'been bypassed for a reason, which may be physical (topography, soil conditions, water table level, flood plain), social (ownership dispute or encumbrance, "hobby" use) or institutional (zoned use is infeasible at that loca- ' tion.)'.: Whatever the obstacle to development, -it 2s .- 'not.removed by limitations on development at other . sites. - :* If infill development is promoted via restrictions on other building.sites and previous obstacles to develop- ment are overcome, housing costs (prices and rents) in the infill area are likely to be significantly higher than prices have been when development sites were unlimited. The reason for the increase is that owners of infill sites will have been awarded a monopoly position: because they hold !he only potential - 44 - .. development sites, they will charge whatever they think the market will bear for the use of those sites. Their ' incentive to sell or develop in the short term may be reduced, because the longer they hold the sites the more they hope to be able to charge for them. This dynamic may provide an incentive for developers to seek sites in other communities, outside the residen- tial area, thus counteracting the benefits of infill. An incentive approach is likely to be more effective because it is less likely to cause spillover. 6. Cluster DeueZopment in Urban Areas. The conventional style of single-family residential each lot and allots each house its private yard, uses more.'land per unit than does clustered housing. In the latter, side yards are eliminated and private yards are reduced and replaced by community open space. ' development, which produces one detached house on 1 Implementing Agemy 1 Local general purpose government. 1 Application 1 Amend the zoning ordinance to allow clustered arrange- men.ts of single-f.amily dwelling units. Such an amend- ment would have to eliminate the types of lot size requlrements designed for 'detached single-family devel- opment and substitute requirements which allow common walls or smaller side yards and shared recreation/ outdoor relaxation areas and facilities. Clustered housing is often-allowed in Planned Develop-. ment (PD) or Planned Unit Development (PUD) zones, some of which also provide for planning agency review of site plans and architectural designs to assure that development will be v-isually satisfying and will assure privacy to each unit. Cluster housing developments are generally subject to much.closer scrutiny by local planning agencies than are traditional single-family detached projects. Cluster developments have generally appealed primarily to specific market segments (usually singles-or couples without children). Whether cluster developments built with less city review would also be acceptable and whether cluster developments in general will satisfy the needs of'families with children is' not known. The , effectiveness of clustered urban development patterns in preserving 'farmland is strictly a function of its higher density. .. ?' . : . -45- - - .. I, 7. Cluster Development in RuraZ Areas. -1 Development that occurs in rural areas, when a farm owner sells part of the'f.arm, can disrupt the agricul- tural use of the land sold. 1n.areas where the mini- mum lot size is 10 acres, for example, the owner of homesites must divide the 40 acres into three parcels: one 20-acre parcel and two 10-acre parcels. If it were possible to cluster the desired development, the ' 40 acres wishing to build two houses or sell two . - disruption of the farm use would be much reduced. I ImpZementing Agency 1 .. Local general purpose government with jurisdiction over rural land. AppZication 1 ." Adopt a zoning provision for agricultural areas which provides that residential development on prime land be clustered on smaller parcels than permitted under conventional rural zoning. For example, the afore- mentioned farmer could divide his property into two one-acre lots.(.for two houses) and one ,38-acre parcel . (the remainder); such an arrangement.would leave most of the original ownership and use intact. I Effeckiveness 1 - The major problcm with land divisions is that when the smaller parcels are transferred to different , . owners the likelihood that the original agricultural use will be continued is reduced. Cluster develop- ment allows for the maintenance of larger,'single.- ownership parcels which a're more'amenable to continued agricultural use, even when sold. Rural cluster development mus't be closely regulated, however, to assure that more lots than were originally allowed are not split off from the original major parcel. Ln -the example above, this regulation would : ,.,' ,' be used to make sure that no more than three one-acre parcels were split off from the 40-acre parcel. C... Affect the Location of Urban Development "- Rationale. The goal of this series of mitigation measures is to protect prime agricultural lands by consider- ing the suitability of land for agricultural purposes as the principal criterion in determining where urban develop- ment will be permitted. The two focuses of affecting de- velopment location - (l).restricting new locations on prime land for urban development and strictly limiting urban . - 46 - .. , development on prime land and cultural uses on prime land - (2) protecting existing agri- will be discussed separately. Measures-to Control the Location of Urban Development. 1. Growth On or Toward Non-prime Lands. [TGZj-l To minimize or eliminate the absorption of prime lands by urban uses, locations which are not on prime land should be identified and development should be directed to those locations. If there are no non-prime soils adjoining the urban area but there are some in the vicinity, development should be allowed on the lands 'most directly between the urbanized area and the closest non-prime land. ** [ Implementing Agene2 1 Local general purpose government. I Application I . As new lands are required for urban development, grant entitlement (the right to develop) 'to those lands which are either (I) non-prime or (2) most directly between the existing urban area. and the nearest substantial area of non-prime soil. The City of,Visalia, California and Tulare County, California (in which Visaliz is located). have both adopted programs which encourage growth on or toward' non-prime lands by applying ranking systems for .agri- cultural/potential agricultural lands. The'se systems effectively broaden the defining criteria for prime. land to include factors other than soil characte,ristics and then direct growth toward the newly-defined non- prime lands. For example, under the Tulare County Rural Valley Lands Plan, points are awarded to designated parcels based on soil capability (as defined by USDA); size; current or potential agricultural use; if currently in agri- cultural use, the sizes of surrounding -parcels; uses of adjacent parcels; nearby uses which are considered incompatible with urban uses; level of the groundwater table; proximate agricultural preserves; distance from the nearest fire station; access to a paved road; historical, archaeological or unique characteristics; location in a flood plain; and availability of water. The categories-ar'e weighted to yield a maximum assign- ment of 30 points. Parcels assigned 17 or more points are automatically.retained in agriculture and those assigned 11 or less are Considered for nonagricultural - 47 - - - . .. d, uses; parcels awarded 12 to 16 points are evaluated further based on additional criteria. . Thus, the Tulare system extends the definition of non-prime to consider the availability of urban infrastructure, the use of adjacent lands and the existence of unique or .cultura.lly-valued features in addition to the charac- teristics of the soil. The Visalia system is similar to but not as complex a's that adopted by Tulare County. Lands are assigned to one of four categories depending on their USDA soil ' classifications and availability.of water for irriga- "tion. One class of lands is ass.med to have no cur- rent or immediate potential for agriculture; the other three are assumed to ,have agricultural use or potential, but exclusions from them may be made based on examina- tion of water supply and ownership. .. 1 Effectiveness 1 Because this measure involves the designation of specific lands on which development may occur, the potential of monopoly pricing for developable land is a possibility. To the extent that,landowners, recognizing the lack of competition in land sales, raise their prices, they may prompt developers to seek other sites in nearby but less-regulated juris- dictions. If a community has no non-prime lands nearby, this measure would nearly e'liminate growth. Displacement effects (spillover) might result. 2. Pr 2hibition of Subdivisions on Unincopporated Lands. . mJ Most.,of the land surrounding many communities located in agricultural areas is prime agricultural land. One way to limit the prime land locations available to new incorporated areas and limit lot splits. ' urban development is to prohibit subdivisions in un- I Implementing Aaency I Local general purpos-e- government with jurisdiction . '. . over rural land. [ Application 1 Prohibit subdivisions in rural areas and prohibit divisio'n of existing parcels. !.Effectiveness I The price of large-sized parcels currently used for agriculture is 1ikely.to deter households from pur- chasing 'them. for exclusively residential use; consc- quently, this measure greatly reduces the' possibility - 48 - of additional urban-oriented residential development in rural areas. It may be circumvented, however, if there are rural areas within commuting distance of the.loca1 employment base which do not have similar restrictions. The measure would be most effective if implemented on a regional (multi-county) basis. 3. Local EZigibility' for Federal and State Housing' Programs. ... ._ ._ .. .. It is the existence of federal and state housing pro- grams such as Federal Housing Administration (FHA) . mortgage insurance, Veterans' Administration (VA) and California Veterans' Administration (Cal-Vet) mortgage guarantees, Farmers' Home Administration ..(FmHA) guar- antees and subsidies and government-related mortgage purchase (secondary market) operations which have made homeownership a reality for most households who own single family homes. Without those programs, the purchase of a house would be beyond the reach of most families. If those programs were eliminated or their use restricted, effective demand would decrease. The decrease in effective demand would, .in turn, slow down the amount of residential construction. Therefore, if these programs were unavailable to purchasers of new homes built on prime agricultural lands, builders would be much less likely to select prime land sites for housing development. - Implementing Agency 1 Federal and state governments (various program- administering agencies). I AppZication ] - Make homes built on prime agricultural lands ineligible for participation in federal programs - such as those administered by FHA, VA and FmHA - or their state- sponsored equivalents, or in secondary mortgage mar- ket operations (FNMA, GNMA, FHLMC). [ Effectiveness .. The indirect penalties imposed by this measure depend for .effectiveness on the continued reliance of housing consumers on the types of programs named above. To the extent that private mortgage insurance opportuni- ties displace FHA or that down payments are large enough (20%) to obviate the necessity of mortgage insurance, it will not discourage the location of homes on prtme land. A prohibition on secondary . mortgage market participation would likely be a . . ! .. , - 49 - , stronger deterrent, as lending institcitions rely on those operations to maintain their supplies of loan- able funds and keep their lending costs down. .4. Eliqibility for Commun<ty DeveZopment/RedeveZopment Aid and Intergovernmental' Assistance.. [mJ Cities depend on assistance from the state and federal governments for a large portion of community develop- . ment and redevelopment funds. These funds are used to or recondition urban uses, including especially residential and commercial development. If those funds were awarded on the condition that they not be used for any projects located 'on prime agricultural lands, that tential locations for publicly-funded development. 'condition would serve to eliminate those lands as po- I Implementing Agency 1 Federai and state governments (grant-awarding agencies). I Application 1 Establish as a condition of federal grant awards that no projects funded with those gr.ants be located on prime agricultural lands. I Effectiveness 1 This measure would be effective in eliminating new federally-assisted or state-assisted development on prime agricultural land. However, such projects probably constitute only a very small portion of total development. 5. New Towns or Satellite Towns. . . .. pzzqq If the majority of the land ar;>und one or more exist- ing communities is prime, new development should take the..form of a completely new community on nearby non- prime lands. . This comp-letely new community would . .,, accommo'date a'il new development - industrial, commer- cial and residential - which would have occurred in and around, .the existing city in 'the absence of efforts to protect prime agricultural lands. I Implementing Ageney 'I State or federal government. 1 Application 1 The non-local agency would allocate funds to build urban infrastructure capable of attracting and support- ing a-11 types of urban development '(residential, commercial, industrial and public .facilities) in locations on non-prime iands. A public information -. 50 - program to alert households and firms of the develop- ment of the new town and locational incentives may be . necessary 'to.attract development. I Effectiveness ] A new town must attract a balanced mix of urban uses if it is to be a true-urban community rather than another bedroom suburb whose residents commute long' distances to existing employment 'centers (thereby contributing to such other environmental problems as air pollution and excessive energy consumption). Industriai locations with access to road and rail transportation reasonably close to major existing trade routes as well as an ample labor supply are .essential in drawing industries to the new town. Success of this measure depends, therefore, on the willingness of employers and households t6 locate in established, to limit its urban spread to non-prime success has been limited. .. the new town and th.e ability of the new.town, once ' lands. New towns are very expensive to develop, and 6. Urban -Strategg. California's Office of Planning and Research (OPR) has developed an Urban Strategy which coqtains three major policies for state policy relating to urban areas: (1) the maintenance of existing urban areas: (2) infill of vacant urban land; and (3) urbar, growth onto contiguous land when expansion is necessary. The implementation of the urban strategy would thus focus new urban development in existing urban loca- tions and minimize its spread onto prime agricultural lands. The Urban Strategy ais0 advocates non-contiguous land. . urban growth if all contiguous lands are prime farm- I Implementing A~~~CZJ 1' State government: legislature, governor and depart- ments responsible for administering various programs. I AppZication 1 Implementation of the Urban Strategy must be accomplishe'd through the adoption of legislat-ion which would put.its policies into effect. Such legislation'might include requiring cities asking for state financial aid to meet the standards indicated above by requiring them to adopt five-year capital improvements programs (CIP's) and. requiring review of the CIP's by local planning departments; requiring CZP's for all service districts providing growth-inducing services:, requiring Local Agency Formation Commissions' (LAFCO's) regulatory .. .. - 51 - .. I, actions to be consistent with their designated spheres of influence: requiring cities and counties to desig- nate urban service areas; and requiring the assessment of regiona.1 needs for major metropolitan areas in the state. It would also require that the state's own public works projects conform to the Urban Strategy. " I Effectiveness 1 The legislative requirements outlined above would limit the urbanization of prime lands only if they were designed with that specific purpose in mind. It may be observed that some communities already have local policies and development- regulations consistent with the three key urban policies, but that their location within a prime land area nevertheless results in the conversion of prime agricultural lands if and when they . grow. .- . .. r. Measures for Maintaining Existinq Agricultural Locations. 6. Potential measures for maintaining agricultural land at existing locations all involve regulation of those loca- tions. The types of regulations fall into two groups: regulation without compensation and regulation with compen- .sation. Both types are discussed below. 7. General PZans -1 In addition to zoning ordinances, many parts of' the ' country allow or mandate the adoption of general, or comprehensive, plans to govern land. use. General plans are less specific than zoning ordinances,'setting guide- lines €or land use patterns, transportation/circulation routes and.'other aspects of the urban environment.. The distinction between general plans and zoning may best be . explained by an example: the land use element of the general plan may designate that an area be devoted to commercial uses; the zoning. ordi-nance would specify which specific types of commercial uses (dry cleaning store, shopping center, automobile dealership, office building) and whae ..minimum lot size, bui.lding setback' requirements , height limit, parking and loading provisions and other physical characteristics will be permitted. . In many ways, zoqing is considered a means of implementing the general plan.. . General plans may (and in some cases must) be organized into elements, each of which addresses a different topic. Elements dealing with agriculture, open space and conser- vation or natural resources (or some combination of these) could be developed to govern the use of prime agricultural'land resources. - 52 - -1 3 3 13 .. , 1 ImpZementing Agency 1 . Local general purpose government with jurisdiction over agricultural land. 1 AppZication 1 Adopt an agricu1ture;open space, conservation or natural resources element of the general plan. In-. cluded in the element would be identification of prime and other valuable agricultural lands and establishment of goals and policies to control their use. These goals 'and policies would be directed toward protecting and preserving' the identified lands. Lands could not be removed .from the protection of.the element except by the general plan amendment process. California law now requires"that zoning be consistent general plan more power to direct.everyday land use decisions, and means that changes in allowable land. use must be reviewed twice - for a general plan ' with the general plan. This requirement gives the . amendment and then for a zone change : before they. can be implemented. . .. The consistency requirement strengthens- the effective-. ness of the general plan. Historically, such plans have often been shelved and urban or rural development allowed to proceed without regard to their standards. However, the most ambitious general plan can be no stronger than the local commitment to its .goals and policies. A local general plan-is highly susceptible to local political pressure. Because of.this susceptibility it is not clear whether an element of the local gen- eral plan setting forth agricultural land policy wo'uld be effective in maintaining the.existing agri- cultural locations. Farmers who wanted to sell and developers wh'o wanted to buy could organize an effective pressure system to -get the general plan changed. Review of proposed changes by'other govern- ment agencies, however, could serve to discourage non-essential general plan amendments. Implementing Agency 1 EPA, USDA or other interested federal agency. Con- tingent on local adoption of B general plan element addressing agricultural land retention. - 53 - [ Application I .. Any proposed change in a general plan.element which controls use. of agricultural lands would be subject to review by EPA and/or the U. S. Department of Agriculture (USDA). EPA could relate NPDES permit ' issuance to the jurisdiction's record in conforming to EPA's recommendations or to its record in main- taining agricultural lands. (See p. 84 for a descrip- tion of the NPDES system.) 1 Effectiveness 1 Strong, if the federal .agencies can assume approval, incentive or reward powers such as influence over role - limited to review and comment on agricultural elements - would help assure that local agencies take national interests into account when making decisions relating to prime agricultural land. . NPDES permit issuance. Even a more modest federal .. 9. AqricuZturaZ Reserves. . -1 . One reason that maintenance of existing agricultural locations is difficult is that urban 'and public uses intrude on them, either directly or proximately. Ad- jacent residents complai'n about crop-dusting activity, air pollution from nearby autos affects the health of plants and animals, and public roads and other im- provements occupy -former farmland. In addition, the proximity of urban uses raises farm land values (in antic:pation of future urbanization) , thereby making agricultural use less profitable with respect to the value of the investment. Protection of farmlands from urban intrusion would help to maintain existing agricul- tural locations. f ImpZementing Agene9 J - State government. 1 AppZication 1 .. ,. .. , Adopt a state law, similar to the New York..law, author- ~. izing the creation of agricultural reserves. The New York law provides for the creation of a reserve at the. initiative of a group'of landowners who have at least the designated minimum amount of land. If the reserve is granted by the state, the landowners gain a number of protections: limited liability for assessments by special d.istricts, protection from public agencies' baking of district lands (e.g., for roads) , eligibility of most lands within. the district for agricultural value assessment and minimal state/local interference in farming activities. The New Yoxk agricultural re- serves.are initially approved for eight years; they -are reviewed and .may. be modified or terminated at that time. . .. 1 Effectiveness I Unknown; dependent on willingness of agricultural landowners to commit to the minimum period (in New York, eight years) of agricultural use. Could be only a short-term measure if landowners are not will- ing to renew the districts. Could be strengthened by the state's requiring that all prime land areas of a designated minimum size become agricultural reserves. The measure offers the advantage of assuring that a critical mass of agriculkural activity4s maintained, rather than just scattered farms. 10. State Regulation of Agricultural Land -1 .. Regulation of agricultural lands is argued to be most effective when imposed at the state level because it is then removed from local political pressures. I Implementing Agency I State government: legislature, governor and admin- . istering agency. 1 AppZicahion 1 Adopt state legislation which prohibits. urban d.evelop- ment on identified prime agricultural lands. The legislation should contain criteria and procedures for identifying prime lands, specify which lands' (if any) are exempt from regulation. and control uses on the remaining land. Some states (in addition to New York) have already adopted or are studying measures to limit urban de- velopment on agricultural lands.* Oregon has a state level Land Conservation and. Development Commission (LCDC), which has the power to establish land use guidelines to which local governments must conform. LCDC has established agricultural land retention as a .statewide goal, and the commission calls on local governments to place agricultural lands in exclusive farm use zones. Land placed in such zones is taxed at farm use value .(rather than fair market value) and accepted farming practices on it may not be interfered with. In addition, non-farming uses within the zones are restricted and proposed subdivision of 'parcels into less than ten acres is subject to review by the locql government to test its consistency with the state's agriculture policy. *This discussion draws heavily on Fletcher, 1978. - 55 - - .- .L <, Wisconsin has adopted what is apparently a more volun- tary approach. Until September 1982, qualifying farm- ers may sign contracts with the state'in which they agree not to develop their land; in return, their land is assessed at agricultural use value. After September 1982, urban counties must have zoning ordinances in effect with a category for exclusive agricultural use in order for farmers to be eligible for the reduced assessments; rural counties may have either exclusive agricultural zoning or a farmland preservation plan. Counties are not required to have such zoning ordinances or plans, but farmland. owners in counties which do not meet the requirements of .the program wilL.not be eli- gible to receive the benefits described after 1982. Three bills which would'have established state regula- tory control over the use of prime agricultural land were introduced into California state legislature in the 1977-78 session. The three, two of which were later consolidated, contained different.definitions of prime agricultural land and proposed different regu- latory structures. What they had 'in common, though, was a prog-ram which included (1) the identi5ication' of prime agricultural lands according to the criteria presented, (2) a procedure for exempting certain prime lands from regulation, (3) a state role in assuring that agricultural land identification and preservation programs - whether developed by the sta'te or by local. entities - would be consistent with the objectives of the bill, and (4) the restriction of prime agricultural lands to agricultural uses. The identifi'ed effects of these bills would have been to remove certain prime agricultural lands from the potential urban land supply and to alleviate some local political pressure related to that removal by establishing state review/appeal authority over the. original location actions. None of the bills was passed by the legislature. 1 Effectiueness 1 . Unknown;-depends not only on-.the.characteristics of the plans which are developed, but also on how well their provisions are enforced. The exemption of prime agricultural lands needed for short-term community growth could'vitiate the effectiveness of the preser- vation program over time. Inclusion of non-prime lands among agricultural land subject to protection does not relate to the objective of retaining prime lands. - 56 - The Coastal Zone. Management Act. establishes a precedent purpose of protecting scarce land resources'. The fed- eral government could also become involved in protect- ing prime agricultural land from urbanization by enact- in.g new legislation similar to the state legislation described above. I ImpZementing Aqenev 1 . for federal involvement in land use planning for the U. S. government: congress, president and administering agencies (presumably USDA and/or EPA) . 1 AppZication 1 *. Enact a law providing for federal protection/regulation of prime agricultural land. The law would designate a responsible agency (presumably USDA or EPA) to carry out its provisions. These provisions would, like the state legislation, include the establishment of criteria and procedures' for identifying prime farmlands, specifi- cation of which lands would be exempt from regulation and methods for protecting/regulating the remaining prime lands. I Effectiveness 1 Unknown; dependent on exceptions to regulation and effectiveness of enforcement. 62. Condemnation or Transfer of DeveZovment Rights. 1 Pheopy ] The entitlement (right to develop) conferred by zoning. on a specific parcel of land is a powerful economic force, because the use permitted determines the value of the land. For example, land zone,d for apartments is more valuable than land zoned for single family homes because apartments potentially produce more in- -come for the land owner. Similarly, land zoned for virtually any urban use is more valuable than land zoned for agricultural use because the potential re- tuns from urban uses are greater. The viability of agricultural use is.tied in part to the zoning on the land, because the land value is one factor in determining economic viability. Simply put, if the land has a high value - which could result from urban zoning - then the low financial returns from agricultural use would not justify maintaining the use at that location. ,If, however,.the land has low value - e-g., there is no use other than agriculture to which it.may be put - then the economic return frpm agri- cultural use .is a higher proportion of the lqd value ana may justify maintaining agricultural use. - 57 - The zoning ordinance, which allots entitlement to designated locations, is not necessarily effective in maintaining land in agricultural use, because it .may be changed at any time. A potentially more effective measure is.one which establishes conditions under which the entitlement for a specific location may be sold or transferred to another property. This concept, known as transfer of development rights, would both (1) provide that the landowner be compen- sated for the foregone value of whatever urban use would ultimately have been allowed and (2) remove all potential for future urban development on the land by withdrawing the entitlement to develop it. .Development rights pertaining to a given parcel of land can be either transferred or condemned. Trans- fer of development rights includes all mecLanisms for removing the development right from one property and assigning it to another. Condemnation of de- velopment rights involves their acquisition by the government rather than by a private party. The con- demned development rights may later be'resold to another private landowner or may simply be retired by the governmental agency which'purchases them rather than being assigned to another parcel of land. Con- demnation also implies a mandatory .action rather than a voluntary one; it would therefore be a stronger measure. j ImpZementiqg Agency 1 State government and local general purpose government. 1 Application 1 Enact a law establishing the rules for transfer or condemnation of development, Gights, including (1) eligibility for participation,'(2) method of deter- mining the value of development rights at various locations and (3) administration of the system. Admi.nistration would most likely involve both the . state and local government. Compensation- for the condemned development rights would be provided by the state while the local jurisd.iction would have to'be involved,in allocation of transferred rights. Some states have already begun to examine the feasi- bility of development rights purchase programs for retention'of agricultural land. Maryland has enacted a law which combines the agricultural district and development.rights transfer approaches. Under that law, landowners may petition the state to form agri- cultural districts; if the districts are approved, the owners agree to continue farming for five years -L 58 - in return for protection of the farm .uses. The law also provides that a farmer may sell .an easement on land within .an established district to the state Agricultural Land Preservation Foundation. With sale of the easement, the farmer gives up the right ' to subdivide the land for development purposes other than for dwellings of the owner.and family members. Easements are intended to be permanent but may be repurchased after 25 years by the landowner. (No money has yet been made available to the Foundation for the purchase of easements.) New Jersey has undertaken a two-year demonstration program (approved in 1976) involving the purchase of development rights in Burlington County, in the southwestern part of'.the state. Eligible farmers ' interested in selling their development rights sub- mitted non-binding bids to the state; the'state, in ' turn, had the properties appraised to determine the difference between the farm'value and the fair market value of the land (that difference is the amount the state would pay for the development right). As of April 1978 the state had identified t,he lands whose development rights it was interested in buying but had not decided to proceed with-the purchase al- though funds were available. Response to the pro- gram, though, indicated a high level of farmer in- terest, suggesting that such a program would in fact - be effective. Massachusetts has also funded a pilot program for the purchase of development rights. Because the program is so new, however - funding was appro- priated in 1978 - not much information about the program is yet available. a I Effectiueness ] - For condemnation, effectiveness is strong because future development options are eliminated on pro- perties whose development rights have been con- demned. For transfers,' effectiveness is .unknown; it depends on the presence of a market to induce owners to sell or trade the development rights. 13. CompensabZe Regulation. 1-1 One reason agricultural landowners are so resistant to use restrictions on their land is precisely be- cause those restricti.ons lower the potential sales price of the land by limiting the uses to which it may be put. 1s that price decrease.could be offset, - 59 -. . .- they would be less resistant to regulation which . mandates use restrictions. I ImpZementing AgencG 1 State government: legislature, governor and admin- istering agency. * I AppZication 1 Enact legislation providing for compensation to agri- cultural landowners whose lands are restricted to agricultural use. This compensation would be awarded at the time of sale 'of the land (which is the only time the actual value loss would be realized) and would be equivalent to the difference between the actual sales price and fhe price which could have been obtained if the use were not restrictc-d. I Effectiveness 1 -. Strong if coupled with a strong prime agricultural land identification program. 14. Outright Pu22chase of ApriculturaZ Land.. pEKJ All the other measures to preserve prime agricultural land discussed in this section depend upon - and some mandate - cooperation of agricultural landowners and complicated administrative procedures. For many of them, it would take years to complete the background studies needed for implementation. A much simpler, though obviously costly, alternative is for the state to purchase the land outright. 1 Implementing Agency 1 State government: .legislature, governor and admin- istering agency. AppZication 1 .. Enact legislation allocating state funds for purchase of' identified prime "agricultural lands. The legisla- tion would have to contain provisions for identifying the lands to be covered. The legislation could pro- vide either for purchase as funds become available .the property is put up for sale. ... . ' .- '"' (condemnation) or the right of first refusal when Generally, this measure would be implemented by state government; local governments typically lack the fiscal resources required to implement an acquisition program. One exception is the City of Boulder, Colo- rado, which has embarked on a.land acquisition program - 60 - as part of a growth management measure, with the pur- chased land to provide a greenbelt around the city. A 1% sales tax was originally (1967) used to provide .funds for municipal land purchases. At an election in November 19'71, voters approved a measure to accel- erate the acquisition program by using the proceeds of revenue bonds, with the sales tax money earmarked to retire the bonds. I Effectiveness ] Outright purchase gives the public agency complete control of the use of the land. 15. Purchase of Remainder Interest. It may be argued that there is no immediate crisis in the availability of prime agricultural land. President Carter's statement that the 'farmland set- aside program would be "highly likely" to' be con- .tinued in 1979 as part of the ongoing price support system for some farm products (especially feed grains, such as corn) would appear to lend'weight to this . argument. However, irre'spective of the situation . now, there may evolve a scarcity of prime agricul- tural land as-the world's population grows (from 4 . billion in 1977 to .6.7 billion in 2000) and more and more prime land is absorbed by other,uses. . Therefore, a reasonable approach to insuring that existing agricultural locations will be available when they are needed, sometime in the future, is to reserve the future right to them now. State or federal government. [ Application 1 .. Enact legislation to allocate a remainder interest in prime -i funds for purchase of agricultural land. Purchase of remainder interest by the government means -that the government pays now to take over the ownership of the land at some specified time in the future (say, 40 years from now). The future price is discounted to present value, representing 'a sig- nificant price- savings over the outright purchase option. The seller (current owner) retains the right to use the land as he pleases (consistent with local regulations) until the specified date at which ownership changes. At that date, the new owner (the state) assumes ownership and control over the land and whatever land uses are in existence; the state ultimately returns the land to agricultural use. The legislation would have to describe means for iden- tifying prime agricultural land and for administering both the purchase program and, in the future, the land. - 61 - I Effectiveness I Depends-upon the Scale .of the program. For lands upon which development takes place between the time the remainder interest is acquired by the public and the time title is transferred, effectiveness also depends on the technical feasibility of restoring the land to its original prime character. -b. Limit the Availability of Urban Infrastructure Ratisnale. Zoning for urban use, which grants the entitlement for develppment on a given property, is a necessary but not a sufficient condition for urbanization. An industrial establishment could not, for exa*mple, be 'built in the middle of a cornfield: there would be no roads leading to it, no sewer or water service, no elec- tricity or telephone; fire and police protection would probably be inadequate for an industrial plant. These kinds of services, both physical and social, are collective- ly known as urban infrastructure'. Because ,they are re- quired for urban development, limiting i,nfrastructure availability is one way of controlling urban expansion. Measures to Limit the Availabi1,ity of Urban Infra- structure. 3. Establish an Urban Service Area for Short-term .Growth. [Theory] A city may delineate the geographic area within which urban infrastructure will be, provided. That area would encompass existing urban development plus a vacant land supply sufficient to accommodate short-term growth. Urban growth would be. channeled to loca- tions within the urban service area because urban infrastructure would not be available outside the 'tiguous development. -. area. ' This policy would encourage infill and con- I Implementing Agene2 1. Local general purpose government and special purpose districts. 1 AppZication I Establish service areas for major urban capital facil- ities (particularly sewers and water supply lines); refuse to extend these services beyond the defined service areas. - 62 - L 1 Effectiveness 1 Highly effective .in encouraging infill and contiguous development, increasing the efficiency of urban land use. Not a long-term agricultural land retention measure because the service area can be expanded over time in response to growth pressures. If the short- term supply of buildable land in the urban service 'area is too limited, spillover development may result. 2. EstabZish an Urban Expansion Area for Long-term Growth. -1 A city may delineate the geographic area within which ' it expects to accommodate its long-term growth. Lands lying outside that perimeter would not be subject to urbanization, even in the long run. Thus, those lands would not experience land value appreciation in anticipation of eventual urbanization, and land speculation would therefore be reduced. Under these circumstances., agriculture would be better able to survive. .. 1 Implementinp Aqency 1 Local general purpose government and special purpose districts. Policy coordination with the local agency .. . formation commission would be necessary. * I Application ] A typical method is the delineation of a.long-run (20+ years) water supply or sewer service area.' 1 Effectiveness 1 Can be effective in reducing land value appreciation attributable to anticipation of urban development in the area lying outside the defined growth area. An excespively large long-term growth area (encompassing more land than would be needed for 20 to 25 years of ,growth) prematurely corninits agricultural lands to development. 3, BPA CZetrn Water Grants. EPA i-s one of the major providers of funds for new infrastructure through its Clean Water Construction Grants program which provides funds to cities for ex- pansion and/or upgrading of their wastewater treatment facilities. Refusal to grant funds in prime agricul- urban infraskructure, in the form of sewage treatment ~ tural areas would severely restrict the provision of - 63 - , ,. capacity, and consequently.limit future growth. More stringent EPA requirements for project sizing, siting and phasing in prime land areas could also help re- duce agricultural land conversion. ImpZementing Agency 1 EPA. [Application 1 (a) Adopt as a mandatory condition of the Clean Water 7. . -.:Construction Grant program that no grants be made to :. communiti'es located on prime agricultural land or to communities whose future growth is likely to occupy prime agricultural land; or . (b) for grantees in prime agricultural land areas, establish shorter staging periods for faciJity construc- tion and require careful planning with regard to the -- amount of reserve capacity in major units of the wastewater system (such as interceptors); or (c) specify land development controls to be adopted by grantees in prime agricultural land. areas to assure that absorption of agricultural land resources by urban uses is minimized.. I Effectiveness 1 EPA requires mitigation of adverse impacts on (in- cluding urbanization of) prime agricultural lands, but does not ,prohibit the award of grants to communi- ties iocated in prime agricultural areas.. No special set of regulations with regard to general issues of sizing and staging or to land development regulations has been developed for application specifically to prime land areas. The effectiveness of such meas'ures depends first on EPA's ability to attach them to grants and to enforce such stipulations once made. It also depends on the extent .to which local agencies can .fund their own . projects, which they would attempt to do .if EPA's conditions are. too stringent. Local funding would relieve grantee agencies from any EPA-mandated obli- gation to protect prime farmland reso'urces. 4. Restrict State and Federa2 fliqhway Aid. -1 - . .. 1 The construction of roads through prime agricultural lands affects the agricultural use of those lands in several ways: (1) it uses up land which.could be 4 .. " - .. - 1 . >I farmed; (2) it often divides farms 'into inefficiently- sized or -shaped parcels; (3) it raises land values, making the agricultural.uses less profitable in rela- tion to the value of -the inputs;. and (4) it poten- tially "opens upIi the land to urban or suburban de- - velopment by both.prouiding access and increasing land value beyond that supportable by agriculture. Much of the road construction which occurs in agri- ' cultural areas is funded with state gas tax money or . federal h-ighway aid. If restrictions wGre placed on these funds, to discourage or prohibit their use in aqricultural areas, they would cease to provide infra- Unknown; depends on whether the existing road system has already.effectively opened up agricultural lands for urban development and whether local jurisdictions. are able to tap alternative'sources of funds for road construction and maintenance. (Alternative. soulfces of funds would increase property taxes, bond issues, special assessments and user fees .such as tolls ...) .... -- 5. Federal Regionnl Council Coordination. 1-1 ~ .. ' .. j. A Federal Regional Counci-l -(FRC) has been established _. in each .region of the .United States whose rnenbers are drawn from the federal agency offices in that' region. The function of ,the FRC is to coordinate the policies and actions of federal agencies in that region. Be- cause- this g-roup has -a unique .overview of ail federal ~ governmental activities, it is in a good position to monitor those activities with respect to their impli- cations for prime agricultural lands. ". -. - - [ Implementing Agency 1 +- Federal government. '. - 65 - . ...... .- .. . & a. . , ,/ 1 App Zication 1 Adopt a policy to discourage or discontinue federal agency actions which would adversely affect the con- tinued agricultural use of prime farmlands. Adverse effects may be anticipated particularly when a federal action would provide new infrastructure usable for - urban development. I Effectiveness 1 -Depends on the direction given to the Federal Regional .- Councils by the administration and on the direction ' givenbto participating agencies by the.ir heads. E. Promote Aaricultural Uses Rationale. Thusfar, the discussion of agricultural land retention measures has focused on ways of discouraging urban expansion onto agricultural lands. Another approach to farmland protection recognizes that agricultural uses are difficult to maintain because of competition for re- sources and because of problems with their own economic viability. The measures discussed below suggest actions which could be taken to strengthen the competitive position of agriculture with respect to resources and to help it gain a better economic return. ' Measures to Promote Agricultural Uses. I. Brinc New AgrieuZturaZ Lax& ilzto Production. The most vital agricultural resource, and the one for which agriculture uses seem least able to compete, is the land itself. One way to offset the loss of agri- cultural. land to urban uses is to require those con- verting existing prime land to urban use to "replace" it by bringing new agricultural land into production. [ IrnpZementinp Agene3 .. .. .X , State government. . .. : .. I AppZieation f -. .. .. @ Enact'legislation establishing a state-administered, il' . developer-financed reclamation program for 'agricultural lands. This proqram would involve (1) identification of lands to be reclaimed, (2) condemnation of those . .. .- ' lands, (3) purchase of the lands at their present values and (4) development of a reclamation plan. Purchase and reclamation as well as administration of the program would be funded by mandatory developer contributions assessed on a per acre (of developed land) basis when new developments a.re undertaken on prime agricultural land. The effect of this program .and funding ar,rangement would be to provide a "bank" of land reclaimable for agricultural use, with'new - 66 - . .. d, acreages put into use as existing agricultural lands are removed to urban use. . A state-administered program offers considerable ad- vantages over a similar approach administered at the 'county level, among which may be mentioned lower initial' land cost, assurance of provision of a critical mass of new agricultural land, more efficient soil reclamation practices and uniform state-wide regula- ' tions and procedures. .. :[-Effectiveness Strong. Proper implementation and administration would assure replacement of lost prime lands on a one-for-one basis. It is not clear, however, (1) whether reclaimed soils would have the same versatility and resilience 'as prime soils or (2) how large the supply of reclaim- able soils really is. *. 2. Put Purchased Agricultural Land to Agricultural Use. ITheorT] . One of the mitigation measures suggested above was the outright purchase of prime agricultural lands by the state. These lands could continue to be used for agri- culture after their purchase under a variety of arrange- ments. I ImpZernentinG Agene3 State- government. I Application 1 (a) The state agency- with jurisdiction over. the pur- chased land could lease it back to bona fide farmers at lower-than-market rents. This type of program wculd both reduce the effective COSY of lands to' the state (because it would make them income-producing properties rather than idle open space) and reduce the expense of farming, thereby making it more profitable. (b) The state could use' the purchased prime' agricultural land for such purposes as training farmers or conducting agricultural experiments and demonstration projects. 1 Effectiveness I A leaseback program would be effective in making land available to'those wishing to farm it and in generating income to offset the costs of a public land purchase program. The effectiveness of alternative uses, such as measure (b) described above, in promoting agriculture is unknown. .. - 1 .. L . , 4, 3. Growth of Cooperatives. pGzJ ' Uncertainty regarding the availability and size of mar- kets is one factor reducing the economic viability of .agricultural enterprises. Commercial canneries are less.and less frequently willing to make advance commit- ments to growers relating to the'amount of produce they will buy in any given year. Because farmers compete, with each other for sales, all run the risk of over- planting the crops they perceive to be in demand and , being stuck with surplus crops. Further, because of canning expense and uncertainties regarding future demand for canned goods, canneries are often not will- ing to pay the prices required to make agriculture a competitive land use: Farmers would be in a better .economic position - and therefore better able to con- tinue to farm - if they could eliminate the- private .cannery's intermediate role in food production. The private cannery could be replaced by growers' co- operatives. operation of cooperatives would help make agriculture more viable by (1) enabling the coop to assign (or agree to) established amounts of specific crops, thereby reducing or eliminating the risk of overplanting, and (2) distribute' net profits directly to members rather than having to pay an outside inter- mediary (the private canner). I ImpZementing Agency j Federal to state government. .[ Application I Provide financial and technical assistance'to groups of farmers to encourage the growth of cooperatives. Technical assistance would i.nclude education related to business organization, economics - and operation. I Effectiveness 1 Private canneries are currently only marginally profit- able operations; the distribution of their profits .to farmers. would not be likely greatly to alter the farmers' economic position. However, certainty of a market for production would be of.considerable assistance to growers who have flexibility in determining their' mix of crops. Coops have been established in a number of product lines. 4. New Merchandising Techniques. -. 1-1 Canning is a low-profit operation. Canned fruits and veget-ables represent a declining share of the processed .- 68 - , food.market. The development of an alternative pack- aging form which would find acceptability in more pro- fitable markets would allow processors to make more money on their output and pass some of the accompanying .benefits - a portion of that profit and/or reliable de- mand .commitments - on to the producers. These benefits would act in the same manner as cooperatives to reduce uncertainty and to make agriculture more viable. 1 Implementing Ageney ] State or federal government; both have agricultural research programs. /.Application I Provide economic support, technical assistance and re- .search efforts to assist in the development of new pro- cessing and merchandising methods for agricultural pro- -ducts. An example of the kind of useful results such efforts can yield is provided by a 1979 announcement of a new canning process developed by University of Califor- nia, Davis, researchers, which permits canning with a higher fruit-to-fluid ratio and a marked improvement in. f 1 avor . 1 Effectiveness I Unknown; depends upon consumers' reactions to new pro- cessing and packaging methods. It is questionable, too, whether consumers are likely to be willing to pay enough more for food products, even with new methods, to support prices at a level which would make agriculture a significantly more viable endeavor. 5. Intermediate TeehnoZogg for Agricultural' Production. pGEj-j Efficiency of farm production in the United States has inc'reased greatly over the yeark as new and better machinery has been developed to assist farmers in all phases of production. This machinery has generally been designed for large farms. Agriculture in many areas of the county is characterized by small farms. ' A problem of operating a small farm at ' a profit is the relative lack of technology (such as machinery) suitable to small farms. This void could be filled by the 'development of farm machinery designed for small farms; such machinery would reduce lab-or costs and improve productivity . 1 Implementing Agency Federal or state government. - 69 - Provide economic and technical support'for the develop- ment of machinery designed for and affordable by small farms. Some .observers (for example, California Employment Development Department, 1977) have noted a systematic bias in university and cooperative extension research* and service programs toward the interests and needs of large farms, and have advocated a re-orientation of '; these programs to provide more effective assistance to smaller and/or family-operated farms. 1. Effectiveness 1 Unknown. 6. NationaZ Prime AgriculturaZ Land PoZicy,. 1-1 One ongoing problem in the attempt to preserve prime agriculfural land is that preservation does not have an identifiable constituency. Farmers,, who have his- torically counted on being able to sell portions of their land when money was scarce .or they wanted to retire, have generally opposed regulation of their lands. Conservation groups, lacking adequate resources . to. address all issues, have focused.on the more visible ones. One result of this lack of a constituency, though, is that legislators and executive government officers have .had no motivation to take actions to halt the conversion of prime lands to urban uses. ~ The situation could change if an interested 'federal agency were to implement a Prime Agricultural Land Policy designed to stem conversion. The adoption of . such a policy would help to .crystallize the agricul- tural land retention issue and hake it explicit to legislators, their constituents and the federal and state agencies which administer programs which affect or potentially affect prime. agricultural land. . ._ . A Prime Agricul.tura1 Land Policy which focuses on reten- "'+ tion of those lands wouXd presumably have to be based ' .. on a finding that the benefits of retention outweigh its costs. A study which would be required to assess costs and benefits of retention is discussed subsequently. [ Implementing Agency J One or more federal agencies with interest in agricul- tural land. The Department of Agriculture (USDA), the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) and.the Council on Environmentai Quality (CEQ) all have such interests. .' - 70 - ,. . L 4, . .. Adopt a Prime Agricultural Land Policy which recognizes .the importance of preserving prime agricultural lands and identifies actions which if taken, will aid in pre- serving such lands. These actions could include: (a) The assumption by.a federal agency of the role o'f advocate for prime lands. This role would be carried out in the Federal Regional Council and other interagency and intergovernmental arenas; (b) Expansion of environmental reviews to include state and local documents as well as federal EIS's; (d) Consideration of the effects on prime farmlands of all funded programs and activities, accompanied by efforts to minimize those effects in all cases; and (e) Mounting of a program to enhance public awareness of the costs and benefits of preser.ving prime agricul- tural land. Effectiveness I Agricultural land policies have been articulated by three federal agencies with an interest in agricultural and land resource issues: USDA in 1976 and.1978; CEQ in 1976 and EPA in 1978. These policies generally cover a wide variety of productive-lands - including range and forest lands - not.al1 of which are prime or poten- tially prime farmlands. Mechanisms for policy imple- mentation are in evolution. The effectiveness of the policies depends on the strength of the implementing actions and the degree to which'compliance standards are adhered. to and enforced. Effectiveness of 'a prime agricultural land policy may also be difficult to dis- tinguish from the effect on prime land retention of discontinuing other policies which have adverse effects on prime lands. 7. Assure Adequacy of Future Water SuppZies. - One resource constraint which is predicted to affect agriculture in upcoming years is the supply of water. As urban population grows and the water supply remains 'the same, states relying on water supply projects for j. .- 71 - . , . ',, d, irrigation water can expect to have access to less and less of the total amount of.water. With a shrinking supply, agriculture will become more expensive and less economically viable. [ Implementing Agency I State.and federal governments. 1 AppZication 1 To assist in retaining agriculture's current viability wherever production depends on irrigation, programs are These programs would include conservation, reclamation tion programs would include (1) developing new, more efficient methods of i.rrigation, (2) ceasing to irrigate pasture lands and other non-prime lands, (3) developing crop strains which require less water than qurrently- grown strains and (4) growing less water-consumptive crops. Reclamation programs might include treatment of wastewater to a quality at which it could be reused for domestic and/or agricultural purposes. Provision of new water supplies might include (1) the allocation of rights to new groundwater supplies to agricultural users, (2) the allocation of water from new state or federal water projects to agriculture and (3) the reprogramming for construction of state water projects previously planned but now set aside because of other undesirable impacts, primarily environmental and economic. .. ; needed to assure agriculture's future water supply. . - and development of new supplies. Examples of conserva- I Effectiveness I Unknown. In general, constant or increased availability of water could be expected to maintain but not enhance the current viability 'of agriculture. Where 'irrigation is being newly-applied in certain areas (as is currently the case in the Corn Belt states), assuring a reliable long-run water supply would improve agriculture's stay- ._ ing' power. - - F.-Use Tax Policy to Protect or Encourage Agricultural Activity ... . "Rationale. Tax.policy can be used to alter the feas- ibility of investment in any. given activity through the application of credits, deductions or penalties for such investment. . For example, the federal government encourages long-term investments by taxing the profits on them as capital gains rather than ordinary income and encourages investment in o.i1 resources through the oil depletion allowance. California encourages investments in solar energy equipment by allowing a substantial percentage of - 72 - . its costs to be taken as a credit against .tax liability. Property tax rules encourage homeownership by allowing owner- occupants a deduction from the assessed valuation of their homes when the tax is computed. These types of incentives could be used to encourage agricultural uses and/or dis- courage urban uses on prime agricultural lands. Measures to Make Tax Policy Encourage Agricultural ' Activity/Discourage Urban Use of Prime Land. . One of the cost factors in agricultural production is property taxation. One reason that property taxes 'have historically been problematic for farmers is that their properties have been assessed accordi'ng to the '"highest and best use" - that is, the use which would allow the greatest return - rather than the actual agri- cultural use. Because the highest and best use in areas where urban growth pressures exist is of ten urban, taxes have been high enough to be the "straw;that breaks the farmers' backs". There have been documented cases of farmers who found it more profitable to pull out their orchards than produce fruit because the revenues from the crop would not exceed their costs when trees were assessed as improvements and the land assessed at highest and best use value. I Implementing Agency I State government. AppZication 1 Generally, it is the responsibility of state govern- ment to establish assessment 'standards and'practices, which are then implemented at the local level. Changes in assessed value to market value rates or distinctions among types of land uses with regard to valuation methods would have to be authorized by legislation. . Among possible approaches are the following: (a) Assess farm properties at their agricultural use value instead of highest and best use value. (b) Assess farm properties at a lower percentage of full market value than applies to non-farm properties. Variations of these approaches have been implemented in several states. In general, the tax break offered to farmland owne.rs is tied to a commitment. on the property owner 's part to maintain the agricultural use, generally by .placing it, under' contract, in a farmland preserve. -. 73 - .. - . ), . A <, California's Williamson Act (the California Land Con- servation Act, 1965) permits, but does not require, counties to establish procedures under .which farmland may be assessed at agricultural use value. These procedures call for the signing of a contract between the county and the landowner; in return for the lower assessment, the owner. agrees not to develop the land during the 10-year period of the contract. If the land is developed, the contract is considered broken . and the taxes which would have been assessed had the contract never been signed become due. The State of California provides a property tax reim- bursement to local governments whose revenues are ad- versely affected as a result of the Williamson Act. However, state reimbursement is estimated to cover only about half of the tax loss. The local cost of this kind of differential assessment program ,has,-prevented some of California'a major agricultural counties (e.g., Merced) from implementing the measure. This problem- is likely to be encounter.ed in agricultural areas where the property tax is the principal source of locai revenue. . I Effectiveness 1 Slight. Experience with.Williamson Act, contracts has not proven that they are an effective method of preserving agricultural land. One reason is that the contracts are voluntary; because not all owners choose to enter into them, they do not prevent scatteration of urban development throughout rural areas ("buckshot", "leapfrogging" or "checkerboard" development patterns). Another reason is that the urban price of the land, when sold, will more than cover any tax penalties which may be assessed. Finally, Proposition 13, by reducing all property tax rates in California, has' greatly reduced the in- centive for farmers to enter Williamson Act contracts by providing equivalent or better tax relief with' no accompanying restrictions on land use. -.. The Wi1l.iamson Act also applies to a wide variety of .. lands, including non-prime agricultural land and in- ... cluding nonagricultxal .uses (such as resource uses like forests). Differential taxation systems, if they are to work -as a prime agricultural land reten- tion measure, would hwe to be confined in their 'application to lands meeting the definition of prime. Such systems would also be most cost-effective if limited to areas actually facing significant develop- ment pressures. Final.ly, penalties for breaking contracts would have to be high enough to.function as a deterrent to urban conversion. .A differential taxation' system with these features would have to offer irresistable incentives in order to attract farmland owners to participate on a voluntary basis. - 74 - I -1 :I '1 1. L_ "I I] F] i !J 1 If lower taxes, such as may be provided under differen- tial assessment measures (Measure F-1, preceding), are favorable to farmers, then no taxes at all would ' be even better. If payment of property taxes on agricultural lands were completely deferred until the lands were sold, then I(1) the farmers' cash flow situations would be improved as long as the land was held and (2) the prospect of paying accumu-, lated taxes upon sale could act to deter farmers from selling their lands. Implementing Ageney I State of California. '[ Application ] - ,.Enact legislation which provides that property taxes on agricultural land be deferred until the.property is sold. The legislation would have to allow for state reimbursement.of foregone revenues- by counties, with the accumulated deferred tax payments to be re- paid later to the state. Unknown. Depends on whether (1) economic viability would be enhanced enough to encourage farmers to con- tinue agricultural, use; (2) the prospect of paying accumulated taxes would discourage sales; and (3) the propensity of landowners to circumvent sales while allowing urban development of their lands (e.g., through leasehold arrangements). There may be situations in which the value of the agricultural land, when sold, is not high enough to pay the de- ferred taxes, which would mean a net loss in property tax revenues to the state. 3. AppZy VaZue Capture 'Technique to Lands Benefiting from PubZic Investment. .. When public funds are expended 'to construct a public facility, one common result is an increase in the value of abutting lands, which is often called a "windfall". In the case of wastewater facilities, the construction of a new interceptor or collection system opens the land to urban development, thereby . generally increasing the price a buyer is willing to pay for it. The return to the public treasury of part or all of the windfall gain resulting from a public investment is what is involved in a value capture policy. [ ImpZenrenting Ageney J State government: enabling lekislation would be re- quired in most states to permit implementation by local agencies. - 75 - [ Application 1 I .. .- Because of res "ictions placed on the sai. of land which passes into public ownership via condemnation, capture technique. Some of those which have been implemented include: (1) purchase by a public agency ' of more land th.an the proposed public improvement will require; the agency later declares the .land surplus and sells it at a profit (capturing the windfall); (2) establishment of special benefit assessment districts around the public improvement to tax away part of the windfall; and (3) direct participation of the public ' agency in land development (such as transit agency development near a transit stop or port agency develop- lating to wastewater. facilities came to light in a literature search on this subject. , it can be difficult to establish a legally-viable value ' ment at a p,ort site). No cases of value capture re- I Effectiveness 1 - Legal and administrative problems may be difficult to overcome. Even if they can be overcome, the effect of the measure would not necessarily benefit agricul- , ture. Its direct effects would fall on all landowners adjacent to the new facility, who are as likely 'to be farmers as speculators. The taxing away,of their windfall gain does not necessarily encourage a con-. tinuation of the land in agricultural use, and may discourage agriculture if the farmland owner is fi- nancing farming operations in part by borrowing aga'inst his equity in the land, because the taxing away of appreciation in value reduces his borrowing power. .. . 4. Finance Agriculture with Capital from Non- agricultural Sources pzZJ Federal income tax rules could..be revised to favor . investment in agriculture. For example, giving non- -; agricultural corporations a tax break - in the form -. of a credit or a deduction - for investment in agri- cultural land and operations would give them an in- centive not only to invest in agriculture but also to .,retain agricultural lands in agricultural .use (rather than allowing them to be converted to urban use). 1 Implementing Agency 1 %Federal government. 1 Application I 'Alter federal income tax rules .to provide corporate income tax credits to corporations which invest in agricu1,tural lands and/or operations. '1 Effectiveness ] Unknown. Depends on corporations' needs for tax shelters and the acceptability o.f agricultural invest- ment to their directors and shareholders. A possible adverse side effect of this measure is the potential deterioration o.f farmland quality. Agricultural land owned by non-agricultural corporations would be likely - 76 - to be operated by"professiona1 farm' operators. If these non-owner operators do not observe the same careful cultural practices as owner operators are presumed to observe, land quality could deteriorate more rapidly than it would otherwise. 5. Alter Tax Rules for Industrial Investment. pZZFiT1 Federal income tax rules are currently structured to encourage private investment in the.development and maintenance of industrial activities. When these activities are located on prime agricultural land, the tax structure has acted to encourage'conversion of that land. Alteration of the tax rules to penalize . investors in industries which locate on prime agri- cultural land could act to discourage the selection of such sites in favor of sites in already urbanized .:>- - areas or on non-prime soils. [ Implementing Agerzey 1 Federal government. Also state governments which impose income taxes on corporations. 1 Application 1 Alter tax rules to penalize industries which establish new facilities on prime agricultural land. Penalties could be assessed as a tax surcharge or in some other. form. 1 Effectiveness 1 Depends on the magnitude of the penalty. 6. Restruc2ure FormuZa for Distributing SaZes Tax Revenue. - [TLzJ Local governments often try to attract commercial de- velopment in order 'to increase local revenues from the sales tax. If such revenues were subject to a redistribution on some basis other than the point of sale of the taxable goods, cities surrounded by agri- cultural land would not be driven to'seek commercial deve.lopment. [ Implementing Agency 1 State government. I Application 1 Establish a formula for distributing sales tax revenue that is unrelated to the amount of commercial use in h - 77 - I I " .. d. , .. a jurisdiction. Alternative bases for distribution might be number of residents, number of households with below poverty level incomes or density of urban uses. I Effectiveness 1 ' . Unknown. This is a very indirect method of promoting agricultural land development. It operates.via a disincentive to retail development. Most of the di-, rect competition for agricultural land resources comes . from residential development. G. Needed Studies Rationale. The choice .and/or assignment of the miti- gation measures for pa'rticular situations would benefit from broader knowledge of existing conditions in- the areas affected and the potential trade-offs involved'in mitiga- tion. The need for further study has been explicitly men- tioned in the discussions of several of the measures..pre- sented; it has been implicitly suggested wherever the direct effect of a mitigation measure would be offset by undesirable indirect effects, such as spillover development. The results of further studies would include both increasing our' knowledge with regard to prime agricultural land and its benefits and a- more complete framework for analyzing and projecting the implications of measures actually imple- mented. Studies Needed for Additional'Consideration of Mitigation , Measures. 1. .Cost/Benefit Analysis of Prime AqricuZturaZ Land Preservation. 1-1 .. The adoption of a national prime agricultural land policy proposed above (Measure E-6) was predicated on a finding that the benefits or'prime agricultural land retention outweigh the costs of retention. The-preceding discussion of mitigation measures makes it abundantly clear that prime agricultural land pre- costs of implementing the measures described have not been presented, they have been estimated in some cases and are fairly readily ascertainable in most others. Much less information is available on the benefit side of the calculation, both with regard to quantification of benefits (the first prerequisite of benefit estimation). and with regard to the assignment . servation would ndt be a- cost-free policy. While . - 78 - of probabilities to future levels of need for prime agricultural land (the second prerequisite of benefit estimation). Therefore, in order to .examine a complete picture of both costs a.nd benefits,, an in-depth study of prime agricultural land preservation and its effects would be helpful.. I Implementing Agency ] Federal government. AppZication 1 -1 Structure and fund an in-depth study of the costs and benefits of preserving prime agricultural land. The cost analysis portion of the study would include consideration of.not only the adverse side effects identified in the foregoing discussions but also in- direct costs, such as higher prices for 1Snd and housing, mentioned in the introduction to the mitigation measures portion of this chapter. The benefit of preserving prime agricultural land can be described from an economic perspective as the dif- ference between what consumers pay for.food and fiber . products with and without the preservation. Benefits are difficult to quantify for a number of reasons. Increases in yields are possible (overseas as well as in the Uni.ted States.): continued increases' in yields would reduce the effective benefit of a preservation policy. If food shortages develop - and prices rise in response to shortages in supply - currently idle lands might be brought into cultivation (thereby re- ducing the apparent benefit of a preservation policy), but the timing of future .shortages is difficult to forecast, and prices are likely to be influenced by . government action. The benefits of preservation could be estimated in terms of replacement cost: the level of investment required to develop a new prime agri- cultural land resource. Replacement is currently being impeded in part by reluctance to undertake new water projects, which is in part due to the recognition of their environmental costs. Food and fiber supply and price are not the only factors to be considered in benefit estimation. There are environmental benefits as well which require con- sideration in a cost/benefit analysis. These benefits mental resources; aesthetic, scenic and cultural. re- source protection; and air quality amelioration among others. All these factors would have to be estimated in order to arrive at a quantification of the benefits of a prime agricultural land preservation policy. ' include protection of watersheds and other environ- - 79 - The second prerequisite of benefit analysis is the assignment of probabilities to future .levels of need for prime agricultural lands. Probability coefficients would have to be determined reflecting the likeli- hood that shortages of food and fiber might arise ' from. a .failure to preserve our agricultural land. Development of reasonable probability coefficients faces many of the same problems as the estimation of benefits. However,.a prime agricultural land preservation policy is difficult to defend without a benefit calculation, particularly when those aware of its costs. ' affected .by such a policy are likely to be well Effectiveness I , Very effective for identifying the trade-offs in- herent in an agricultural lands preservation policy and serving as a basis for either pursuing"or re- jecting such a policy, depending on its findings. 2. Comvarative Inter-city AnaZysis of Prime Agri- cuZturaZ LaMd Retention. Modesto is one of many cities throughout the United States surrounded by prime agricultural land. These cities share the predicament of inevitably converting prime agricultural lands to urban use whenever any new development is. undertaken. Develcping a program for mitigating prime.agricultura1 land conversion would be facilitated if a comprehensive comparative evaluation of the performance of these cities with regard to agricultural land absorption were available. Historic performance in prime agri- cultural land retention may bell vary widely even among cities in similar contexts. The cities which have been more successful in retaining prime agricul- tural land provide a standard of performance for those less successful. I Implementing? Agency I I .. .. -. . Federal governinent. . -. ,. . Application Structure and fund studies to develop a data base re- levant to the development of prime agricultural land retention- performance standards for American cities and counties. Relevant data items would include but not be limited to (1) overall .density, (2) inf,ill opportunities within -the urbanized area, (3) proportion of prime - 80 - .' -. agricultural land in the surrounding area, and (4) optimal minimum conversion coefficient (that is, the best performance that could reasonably be re- quired in minimizing the acreage converted per amount of population added). The emphasis on quantitative measures of performance is vital to an accurate evaluation of the effective- ness of prime agricultural land retention programs. While a great many such programs have been imple- mented, very few have be.en analyzed for effective- ness using accepted land economics research tech- niques. The success claimed by many of them re- lates more to political and administrative issues "(interesting elective bodies in the issue and per- suading them to act) than to performance i,n the field. Relevant questions are, (1) have the pro- grams made a measurable difference in the rate or . amount of agricultural land loss due to urbaniza- tion? and (2) what local circumstances - organiza- tional, economic, resource-related - have been impli- cated in a program's success? Context is h5ghly relevant to such an .analysis of . local farmland retention programs. "Success" in. a rural county not experiencing -any development pressures is unremarkable and irrelevank. On the 'r. other hand, conversion of thousands of acres at the perimeter of a rapidly-growing city does not. necessarily indicate failure. In fact, it could meet the criterion of success iy conversion is markedZy Zess than it wouZd have been in the absence of the specific local programs being evaluated. Would provide the basis for. the .development of per- formance standards for cities and counties in pro- tecting prime agricultural land resources. H. Performance Standard for Urban Growth in Prime Land Areas. Rationale'. The mitigation measures described above all focus either on regulating some aspect of urbanization or agricultural use of land or on altering the relative costs and benefits of urban versus agricultural .land uses. An alternative approach, known as a performance standard, focuses instead on the effects a land use or a pattern of land development would have on its environment. This approach is very 'flexible and may be adapted to apply to local governments in many different types of situations. - 81 - 6 .I a, . .. .. . I. A well known application of the performance standard concept is that which assigns zoning based on the effects of a proposed land use in a specific setting, establishing the level of effect that is considered acceptable (may . ' not be exceeded if the use is. to be approved). * With regard to prime agricultural land retention, the performance standard would test the land utilization effi: ciency of a city by establishing a minimum collective den- sity of new development on prime agricultural land over time, thereby ensuring that prime agricultural land not be developed in a wasteful manner. A suita.ble indicator of land utilization efficiency is the coefficient of conversion: the amount of prime agricultural land con- 'verted to urban use per unit.of population growth. The coefficient of conversion calculated for any individual city would vary depending on the time frame investigated; it is a dynamic measure which reflects historic as well as current conditions and practice. The conversion coefficient performance standard may be supplemented by static measures such as gross urban density, gross residential density, availability of infill opportunities, etc., all of which are observations tied to a single point in time. Minimum density levels and maximum feasible utilization of infill si.tes might be established as threshold requirements.prior to application of a con- version coefficient 2erformance standard. Measures to Implement Performance ." Standards. 1. Establish ThreshoZd Standards of Performance ReZating to Dens$t.y and InfiZZ; The prime land conversion coefficient applies to . future development on prime agricultural land: application of a conversion coefficient performance standard does not address the problem of existing inefficiencies in development patterns. When over- all urban densities are low and significant infill opportunities exist, cities could take steps to ensure that future development be guided in a manner that will utilize infill sites ar_d increase overall. densities before activating the conversion criterion. 1 ImpZementing Agency 1 Individual cities at their option or as mandated.as a condition of EPA or other federal grants. I AppZication 1 Most cities' general plans advocate infill and efficient land utilization patterns, and many cities - 82 - I 3 3 '' I. (including Modesto) are implementing .bbth regulatory and incentive measures to encourage increased density and infill. 'Cond-itions on state grants (see Measure C-6, California's Urban Strategy) and on federal .grants encouraging or mandating such measures could provide. an effective . incentive. .For example, EPA could require that a grantee agency, as part of the Step 1 Clear Water Grant, develop a program of compliance with infill'and density standards. If (or when) a compliance program acceptable to EPA . were adopted, EPA would proceed with Step 2 grant processing. Cities could develop compliance programs to suit local conditions. 1 Effectiveness I ,Standards of performance with regard to density and utilization of infill sites would be helpfu-l in im- proving the efficiency of a city's existing land use pattern. Cities could be required to make such im- provements as a condition of state.and/or federal fund- ing pro.grams. Because the developability of infill sites varies widely within and among cammunities, and because the opportunities for development also vary, the success of this policy will vary.widely. It is likely to be most successful in fast-growth areas. 2.. BstabZish a Conversion Cos-fficient Performance - Standard. ["GGJ ' The requirement that a city minimize agricultural land conversion resulting from growth will neces.s.itate the development of a methodology to evaluate its perfor- mance. A possible measure is the index of historic conversion per unit of growth-. The research arm of the U. S. Department of Agriculfure has used the co- efficient-of-conversion measure in comparative studies of land use change on a county basis (see, for example, Dynamics of Land Use Change in Fast Growth Areus, Economic Research Service, USDA, 1976). This measur'e could easily be adapted to use in performance evalua- tion. 1 Implementing Aqencq Local, state or federal government. I AppZication I The agency conducting the performance evaluation compiles data from at least two points in time dis- closing the level of growth (for example, the popula- tion increase) and the change in agricultural land (acres- o.f agricultural land developed into urban uses over that time period). A coefficient of conversion can then be calculated for the purpose of (1) compari- son with other jurisdictions or (2) establishing a . _- - 83 - . performance standard for the future in the same monitoring sys,tem should be set up so that compliance with the standard can be tested. . jurisdiction. -Once the standard is established, a An EPA grantee can be mandated to maintain or improve its historic performance in converting prime agricul-. tural land to urban use. Monitoring could be tied to issuance of wastewater discharge permits under the National Pollutant Discharge Elimination System (NPDES). These permits are granted by Regional Water Quality Control Boards (RWQCB's) but their.issuance is -I " . *'- \% - subject to review and monitoring by EPA. In fact, . this joint federal-state role suggests that respon- sibility for monitoring'grantee compliance could be shared between the two agencies or delegated to the RWQCB . . NPDES appears to be the logical vehicle for a moni- toring program because the permits may be issued for varying lengths of time. This monitoring approach wculd suggest that cities applying for permit renewais .would have'to demonstrate that they were meeting the performance standard established for prime agricul-- tural land conversion, If the city were not meeting the standarc?, it wo'uld have to propose a program to make up lost ground - for example, through infill programs'or density increases - during the subsequent permit period. EPA would have the option of shortening the new permit period so that compliance could be Yeviewed after a shorter inter-Val. Effectiveness 1 .. . Can be very effective in setking a limit to the *-- degree to which population growth results in prime " :' . agricultural'land conversion. Effectiveness depends --.- on the conversion coefficient established as' the ._. . 'standard and. on the local ..gove.rnment'.s. commitment " . .. " ..j to observe the standard. If the:,standard is imposed as a grant condition, - iieither the standard itself nor the monitoring system should be so onerous as to cause potential grantees to forego EPA funding; if cities self-fund their wastewater facilities, EPA's opportunity to encourage prime agricultural land retention is lost. .. Conclusions Cities surrounded by prime agricultural land have an obligation to conserve that resource. and use it with maximum efficiency in view of the fact that its supply is limited. .. - 84 - .. Among other things, that means that priority should be given to developing non-prime lands first; that infill (even of prime lands) should take precedence over fringe development on prime lands; that density levels should be relatively high compared to cities in non-prime land areas; and that cities on prime land should be able to measure and monitor the impact of their .growth on prime agricultural lands over time. The comprehensive inventory of mitigation measures di'scussed critically in this chapter are presented in. summary form in Table 5-10. For each measure, the matrix identifies (1) the level(s) of government responsible for .implementation, (2) whether it would be implemented as a . regulation or an incentive (or, in a few cases, either or both), (3) in what time frame it is considered implernent- able-, (4) whether the approach is direct or indrrect and (5) the likely effectiveness of the measure when a judg- . ment can be made based on information available now. The reader should note that the assignment of a time ' frame for implementation assumes that a measure is feasible and considers both the time it would take to adopt the measure and the time needed to make it operational once it . is adopted. If a measure's effectiveness is indicated to be uncertain, that generally means (1). contextual factors will have a great influence on effectiveness or (2) the specific features of a type of measure would determine its degree of effectiveness. - 85 - . -.. i I .. TabJ,e 5-10 PRIME AGRICULTURAL LAND MITIGATION MATFUX 1 li .-. I/ - 86 - I _. .. ,. - +. . . d',.. Modes to ' s Agricultural Land Conversion Mitigation Program The evolution of this environment& impact statement included a review by EPA and the City of Modesto of the city's past performance in d.eveloping and implementing policies affecting agricultural lands, which provided a useful background to the consideration-of further actions the city might take. This chapter summarizes the back- . ground briefly, and then sets forth a description of the specific pro-gram the City of Modesto has committed itself to pursue in mitigation of the impacts on prime.agricu1- t.ural land resources posed by the expansion of the waste- waterTtreatment plant. ._ . - -" Past -Agricultural Zand- Absorption in- Modesto.. The - ' very rapid growth of the 1970 Is- - approximately 5 percent " _. .. " . per year "was the subject of community .$iscussion in Modesto before-EPA's zssistance in wastewater funding was. sought. Concerns about the effects of growth 'spu-rred the city to monitor its expansion quantitatively which the city has done by tabulating and publishing data on land use change and by preparing'a growth report annually for city government and public review. - . City data suggest that n2w development in the 1970's has had less impact on prime agricultural' land than earlier development had. This conclusion is .based on the calculation of the coefficient of agricultural land conversion from land use survey data tabulated and published by the city in 1971 (reflecting conditions in 1970) and 1978 (reflectin2 con- ditions as of January 1, 1977.). The 1970 population of the area covered by the 1976 land use survey was 95.,370. The developed area occupied by this population and associat,ed urban land uses.including roadways was 14,415 acres, the vast. majority of which would have. been prime land prior to its development. Since Modesto was first settled, then, about 0.15. acres of ag- ,riculturally-valuable land has been developed for'each person added to the urban population. . - . _. : . .. I - . . "" . During the period between the two land use surveys .c'ited, the population of the 1976 survey area rose by 24,430 - 87 - " .- L . ' . a',,. 4 to 119,800. At the same time, agricultural.land acreage in the land use survey area declined by about 3,000 acres. The coefficient of conversion during this period was therefore 0.12 acres per person. This represents a reduction of about 20 percent in the earlier rate.of agricultural land conver- . sion per unit of population growth. . -However, that improvement would not suffice if (1) per- formance remained poor in an absolute sense, or (2) further measures could be taken to mitigate the impacts of growth on agricultural land resources. The next section views Modesto's performance as compared, to that of other cities. TKen the program Modesto has developed to further reduce the agricultural land impacts of growth is described. Modesto's Performance Compared to Other Citi.es in California's Principal Agricultural Areas. Little compara- tive inforKation on urban land use patterns is generally available, and less information on land use change at the urban periphery. In order to develop some comparative measures of performance on urban land use patterns from which sensitivity to agricultural land retention objectives could be inferred, Gruen Gruen + Associates Sought informa- tion from the 15 largest cities in the valley.and delta areas of the Sacramento and San Joaquin Rivers on density and land use patterns. This group of 15 cities includes all those in California's most important agricultural area with 1978 populations in excess.of 25,000. Three measures were used: gross urban density, gross residential density and availability of infill opportunities. Each of these constitutes an indirect.measure of the . efficiency of local land use patterns. The higher the . density and the more contiguous-the develcpment, the less impact growth has had on agricultural lands. Table 5-11 summarizes the comparative density statistics and Table 5-12 summarizes the comparative infill data. The statistics presented in Tables 5-11 and 5-12 show a wide variatiol! among cities in California's agricultural areas with regard to existing land- use patterns. An over- * all ranking representing all .three measures is not possible due to inconsistencies among the measures (which suggest underlying differences among cities in definitions and tabu- lation methods). However, the data are'sufficiently complete - to show that Modesto has generally a respectable record, while such cities. as Fairfield and Vacaville. (both in Solano County) generally rank toward the bottom, and Davis and Wood- land (both in Yo10 County) rank near the top. From the' fact that Modesto is not top ranked, it can be inferred that some margin of improvement remains attainable. - 88 - .' Table 5-11 COMPARATIVE DENSITY STATISTICS: FIFTEEN LARGEST CENTRAL VALLEY AND.DELTA CITIES Land -ea. Acres Developed Total Persons p-r Acre ’ hsiden- Population Total. Residential Acres Rank tial Acres Sacramento Fresno Stockton Bakersfield Modesto Visalia fairfield Vacaville Redding Davis Lodi Herced Clovis Woodland Chico 261,500 195,800 127,300 94,500 86,100 41,050 54,400 40,050 35,650 36,050 32.930 30,150 32,800 25,250 26,950 60,282 25.966 37,427 36,143 15,255 32,256 13,056 11,962 18.112 4,288 5,082 4,922 7.542 8,040 4,217 18,000 N.A. 7,008 4,268 7,007 8,843 3,600 N.A. 3,338 3,750 2;ezo 5,436 N.k. 2,230 1,230 4.34 5.20 9 6 4 .go 7 6.19 4 2.38 13 1.69 15 3.14 10 2.21 14 3.01 12 8.31 1 6.48 2 4.35 8 6.13 5 6.39 3 3.14 11 14.5 4 N.A. - 18.2 3 13.5 5 19.2 2 6.2 11 11.4 8 N.A. - 10.8 9 12.6 6 8.& 10 C,O 12 N.A. - 12.1 7 20.5 1 Totals/ Averages N.A. = -not available. 1,119,480 284,550 67,750 3.93 12.6 Source: Po2ulation estizates (1976) from California Department of Finance, Population kesearzk. Unit, Re-port 7e E-1 (&nded) ; acreage estimates from individdal cities. Table 5-12 COMPAXATIVE INFILL DATA: FIFTEEN LARGEST CENTRAL VhLLEY AND DELTA CI.TIE.5 Vacant Developed Vacant Cm- Total Devaiopable 0 Residen’dal ResiBential P pcsite Acres Acres Vacant Acres, Gross Acres Yacmt -%?k Sacra*ento Fresno Stockton Modesto Bakersfield Fairfield Visalia Vacaville kedding Lodi Davis Nerced Clovis Woodland Chico Total 60,2EE 37,427 24.972 15,255 34,143 32,256 12,480 17,920 11,962 4,308 5,083 7,542 4,922 4.216 8,040 280,814 14,500 7,056 3.983 2,265 16,865 11,209 1,200 9,000 6,862 1,040 463 N.k. N.A. 925 1,350 ” 11 24 28 . 15 49 35 10 50 57 24 9 N.A. N.h. 22 17 ” 18,900 N.A. 7,008 7,007 4,488 8,843 3,600 B.k. 3,338 2,820 -3,750 5,436 N.A. 2,230 1,230 ” N.h. N.A. 3,767 1,831 11,117 5.670 600 N.k. 2.765 525 491 74 N.A. 270 807 ” N.A. 8 N.A. . 35 3 10 22 . 6 71 39 14 14 11 4 N.A. 12 45 13 16 I 2 1 8 2 11 5 40 9 I.A. - ” Base Averaging 268,350 76,718 ” 49,750 27,937 ” \ 2 Average ” ” is 77.687 36 -.. . N.A. = not available NOTE: Composite rankings are based on the sum of the percentage columns. Where data &re not available (N.A.) for either one indicator or the other, the available datum was doubled for the composite ranking. Tne rankings should be regarded as highly approximate due to dlfferences anwng cities “ in the. reliability of data provlded. .. Sources: Cities listed . , .. '. 3 Evolution of Modesto's'Mitigation Package a, Mitigation a Grantee Resaonsibility.. In evaluating applications for grants, EPA is required to take into con- sideration both the .potential environmental impacts of the action supported by agency funds and the extent to which adverse impacts will be.mitigated. The responsibility for selecting and implementing measures to reduce adverse impacts of the wastewater facility project described in Chapter 3 of this report rests with the City of Modesto as grantee agency. EPA's role is to determine whether the measures proposed by the grantee represent the maximum ,feasible mitigation. 1 3 3 3 . *. Agricultural Land Retention Was Modesto Policy Before the Current Project Was Proposed. Modesto's location in 3 the heart of a prime aqricultural land belt, its past history as an agricu1t;ral service and markkting center, and the continuing importance of the food prodgssing in- dustry in the city are some of the reasons why local senti- ment tends- to favor city policies that reduce the effects of growth on prime agricultural lands. Modesto has had in effect for several'years (or longer) planning and development policies that recognize agricul- tural land retention as a city objective. Among these may be mentioned the Urbarr Area General Plan, 'the Urbon Growth PuZicy and the Stanislaus. County Generql PZan (to which the City of Modesto lent its support). The Zevelopment process Modesto already has in effect applies to each newly-developing area the "neighborhood zoning and Zevelop- ment protctype" which sets forth, in advance of considera- tion of specific development proposals, an overall neighbor- hood development program; including general locations of uses, scales of nonresidential uses and residential densities. Furthermore, the city has already implemented, "planned development" (P-D) zoning in a mznner which encourages .infill. in existing neighborhoods. - . .,,, These measures have been reinforced by a number of other city actions .and.programs. In 1975 Modesto began.an :annual public review of its*Urabah Growth PoZicy, which -involves a yearly staff report, coordinated city review of growth trends and poli.cy, and opportunity for public in-' put. The city also organized, in the winter of 1977-78, the Modesto Alternative Futures Symposium, a series of eight public meetings, each focusing on an aspect of the city's management, development policy or resources. The .meetings were .well-attended and were locally televised. Finally, the passage of Measure A (March 1979) requires an advisory vote by the electorate prior to a City Council decision on a trunk sewer extension. -90" 0. I - The fact that all of these policies 'and planning tools are already in place helps explain why Modesto's land development pattern has improved in efficiency (via infill development and maintenance of contiguity in urban expan- sion) and .has increased.in density during the 1970's. In the absence of these measures, the impacts of growth on agricultural land absorption in recent years would have I been considerably greater; and the forecast of the project's impacts on agricultural land absorption would be as much as 20 percent higher than the figures presented in Table 5-8 (p'. 26). EPA accepts these existing measures as partial mitiga- tion of the adverse impact of community growth onto prime agricultural lands. It is the agency's view, however, that additional steps can be taken to reduce G'urther the effects of Modesto's growth on prime agricultural lands, and the city has responded by proposing a series of addi- tional measures, which are presented in the next section. Modes'to's package of mitigation measures builds on the city's past-accomplishments and on extensive discussions and communications with EPA. The outcome of the city's deliberations wzs a commitment by the Modesto City Council (July 19, 1979) to pursue.the measures listed in Table 5-13. ' In addition EPA has been assured by Modesto staff that measures already in effect will be continued. Both the new measures listed in Table 5-13 and key existing measures are incl-uded in the package described below, which is organized in three major sections: measures involving the regulation of land development; measures encomp.assing city policy and advance planking; and measures relating to inter- governmental coordination. This division may be useful to other cities devising programs to protect agricultural land resources. - Mitigation via Land Development Regulation Zoning Reducinc the .Minimum Lot Size. A reduction in the minimum lot size in single-family zoning districts has the objective of reducing the amount of agricultural land absorbed by new single-family development. Modesto's re- ducing the minimum lot size from 6,000 to 5,000 square feet can reduce acreage requirements of single-family develop- ments by as much as 16 percent. Other advantages include potential savings in the land costs associated with a new single-family house and an increase in the potential for infill development when implemented in combination with the next measure. - 91 - Table 5-13 MITIGATION OF THE ADVERSE EFFECTS OF THE MODESTO WASTEWATER FACILITIES EXPANSION ON PRIME .. AGRICULTURAL LAND: NEW KEASURES ACCEPTED BY MODESTO CITY COUNCIL E, Amend the Urban Grawth'PoZicy to contain a policy - within the city. statement that all residential growth should be . .m Amend the Urban Growth PoZicy to contain a goal *. . of increasing the residential density of the city from 6.6 units per net acre (currently) to 7.0 'units per net acre by 1985. .. 0 Revise the General Plan to make the Santa Fe Railroad (rather than Bent Road) the eastern boundary of the urban reserve between Yosemite Boulevard and Dry Creek. m Expand and clarify the priority list for trunk sewer extensions. Amend the zoning ordinance to make the R-1 Zone a density zone. ; a Amend the zoning ordinance to reduce the minimum lot size in the R-1 and R-2 Zones from 6,000 to 5,000 square feet. m Amend the zoning ordinance to specify a maximum lot size in the R-1 Zone. Source: Unanimous vote of Nodesto City Council, July 19, 1979. .. -? Int.erpre't .'the E-.I Zone as a Density Zon'e. Modesto's zoning ordinance has treated the R-1 Zone as composed of '. individual parcels, each of which carries entitlement . -. for onei!single-family structure, irrespective of the .\ size of ,the parcel. That means that even a parcel more than twice as large as the minimum lot size can accommo- date only one housing unit. Modesto's amendment of the zoning ordinance to interpret the R-1 zone as a-density zone wc:uld mean that parcels twice as big as the minimum lot size .would be entitled to two (or more) housing units as long as other zoning- requirements (such as for yards and access) are 'met. ' This measure, when combined with the reduction in minimum lot size, increases infill opp,ortunities in developed areas of the city. Under the minimum lot size of 6,000 square feet, a single-family parcel would .have to be at least 12,000 square feet in size to ac- commoda'te a second unit. Under a minimum lot size of 5,000 square feet, a second unit could be Acconmodated on a single-family lot.of only 10,000 square feet. Establish a Maximum Lot Size. A maximum lot size puts a ceiling on the amount of Land that car! be en- cumbered by any one housing unit, thereby helping to reduce the amount of agricultural land comrerted to low density residential development. Of 1,850 sub- division lots recorded in Modesto in 1977, 145 (7.8 'percent) contained over 10,000 square feet. The Modesto City Council committed itself to the maximrtm lot size 'concept, directing staff to indicate what the maximum would be. With less than 8 percent of all subdivision lots in the 10,OOOt- category, a 10,000 square foot limit appears acceptable. Subdivision Controls Duplexes on Corner Lots in flew Subdivisions. A measure implemented by. Modesto in 1978 allcws an in- crease in R-1 subdivision densities'by permitting duplexes on corner lots. The overall increzse in the number of units in a single-family subdivision resulting from this measure could be as high as 18 percent (be- cause about 18 percent of all lots are corner. lots). Duplexes are subject .to special orientation..and access requirements. Use of P-D Zoning to Achieve Higher DerLsities. . Modesto has implemented a P-D (Planned Deveiopment) over- lay zone in order to (1) permit increased single-family density while (2) ensuring quality design, particularly with regard to privacy considerations. The P-D zoning has proven effect.ive in increasing residenti-a1 densities substantially over the minimum R-1 lot sizes: P-D den- sities can reach up to 10 units per net acre,'while R-1 . sites accommodate (at the old minimum. lot size of 6,000 square feet) only about 7% units per net acre. This measure 'therefore can achieve a density increase of as much as 37 percent. Like other measures encouraging , higher density, the effect of this measure is to reduce the amount of agricultural land absorbed by residential development. - 93 - .. 1 I Building Code P ". . I i I, I Review MuZ.ti-fam2Zy Construction 'Standards. The neighborhood prototype zoning (to be discussed further below) provides an opportunity for construction of multi-family units in R-3 districts, but Modesto's experience has been that, at certain times and in cer- tain parts of the city, the buildout in R-3 zones has, been at lower densities than the maximum (28 units/acre) permitted under the zoning ordinance.. In connection with the EIS, Modesto staff agreed to review construc- .tion standards for multi-family residential structures to ensure that the standards are not so onerous as' to discourage R-3 density development. .. Mitiqation via Land Development Policy and Planning 4, Urban Growth Policy Review. Modesto first developed its Urban Growth PoZicy in 1974, and has 'conducted an existing and new mitigation measures which fit under thehumbrella of this city activity are the following.: ' annual review of that policy from 1975 on. Among Monitoring OveraZZ Urban Density. Modesto's overall urban density is monitored as one element of the annual growth review. In 1978, net residential density was 6.6 dwelling units per acre.. Establishing Urban Density Objectives. One of Modesto's new mitigation measures is.to increase the residential density of the city from 6.6 units/net acre to 7.0 units/net acre by 1985. - Encourage InfiZZ DeueZopment. It is Modesto city policy to encourage infill development. Some examples . of city actions in furtherance of this policy include .- city annexation of enclaves and joint city/county action to upgrade services in the former county islands to city standards, thereby reducing the impediments to development of infill sites in those areas; and the decision to site any new subsidized housing outside -;.. of .the west and south portions of the city, so as to . .reduce or avoid overconcentration of such units (a . . - high concentration of subsidized .units generally reduces the feasibility of market-rate housing in the same . . .' neighborhood because it affects .the image of the ne.igh- borhood) . .. In another move to encourage infill, the 1979urban growth policy. review revised city policy so as to per- mit small residential annexations of sewered areas in unincorporated South Modesto.. (Previously, such annexation was only considered if the area annexed 3 R -1 )r 3 -1 L 94 - . .. & .. .. .Y 3 was of sufficient size to support a branch fire station.) Over 500 acres of potentially developable land exists in this area. Since the policy change, one subdivision map (23.5 acres) has been filed. Infill 'policies described thus far covers sites . th'at are generally surrounded by development. Other sites lie at the fringe of Modesto's existing urban area, but within the short-term urban service area (described below). Development at these locations is .encouraged by city policy requiring development to take place within city limits (first measure in Table 5-13) and within the current sewer service area. Infrastructure Extension Policies Service Area Definitions. Modesto has de'lineated urbanservice areas, both short- (current sewer service area, or CSSA) and long-run (ultimate sewer service area, or USSA). This distinction makes clear which lands the city is committed to provide with urban ser- vices in the short-run, and it a.lso nakes clear which lands lie outside the city's long-run service area. The third mitigation measure in Table 5-13 - the change in the urban reserve boundary from Bent Road to the Santa Fe Railroad - in effect leaves the area betwn,en those roads out of the city's ultimate urban service area, thereby helping to ensure the long-run commitment of that land (comprising about 1,045'acres of prime farmland) . to agricultural use. Trunk Sewer Eztexsion Priorities. Establishment, of trunk sewer extension priorities offers an excellent approach to assuring that the direction of future urban ' growth will respect agricultural land retention ob- . jectives. In 1978, the Modesto City Council adopted an initial set of priorities for sewer trunk extensions. This list has been reconsidered and' elaborated upon as a result of the environmental review of the wastewater , project. The priority list [with further descriptions in brackets] is as follows: 1. Yosemite Trunk, Lincoln to Claus 2. Yosemite Trunk, Claus to Santa Fe Railroad [The Yosemite Trunk extension will serve a portion of eastern Modesto which the city considers an infill area. The ab- sence from the.priority list of any ex- tension of this trunk beyond the Santa Fe Railroad reflec,ts Modesto's decision not to provide sewer service to agricultural areas lying t'o the east of Empire within. at least the next two decades.] 3. 4. 5. 6. 7, 8. The Sonoma Trunk, Floyd to Sylvan Lakewood Trunk, Briggsmore to Floyd Lakewood Trunk, Floyd to Sylvan Sonoma Trunk, Sylvan to Claribel Lakewood Trunk, Sylvan to Claribel 1 3 .[These five extensions,'will permit substantial urbanization of the northeast portion of Modesto. This area comprises that portion of Modesto's ' ultimate sewer service area which lies primarily on non-prime soils.. J 1 Further extensions of the North Trunks.and/or further development of the West Trunk [The areas served/potentially served by these trunks contain extensive agricultural acreages, much of which remains in fairly large holdings.] 3 3 first seven trunk extensions on.the priority 7 list will accommodate all forecast development through &.I the year 2000 and a significant.amount of growth into the next century. Table'5-14 lists the neighborhoods served by the trunk extensions and their population capacities. - 3 The selection of priorities reflects a number of im- .portant considerations in addition to agricultural land . ' impacts of urban development. But the city also maintains that this list, by permitting'infill on the east, by en- couraging growth toward non-prime lands on the northeast, . and by deferring to the long run action on trunk sewers 3 serving the areas of Modesto that are presently most committed to agriculture, represents the city's intention to use infrastructure extension decisions in a manner that will help retain agricultural lands. PZan :implements planning on a neighborhood basis through 3i 1 prototype applies to an area of about three-quarters of a 'square mile divided into a grid of 40-acre cells by collector i3 .. Prototype Neighborhood Concept. Modesto's Genera2 use of the "prototype ,zoning and development plan". The ., streets. The prototype provides for residential uses (with higher density zoning along the arterial streets at the perimeter of the grid) and for public facility, and commercial support uses. There are roughly 480 acres in each new neighborhood available for development. GROWTH ACCC Prior- Trunk 'Extension i ty Yosemite, Lincoln to Claus 1 Yosenite, Claus to Santa Fe Railroad 2 Sonoma, Floyd to Sylvan 3 Lakewood, Briqgsmore $0 Floyti 4 Lakewood, Floyd to Sylvan ' (betw. Lincoln & Claus) Sa J (betw. Claus & Santa Fe I Railroad) 5% u) TOTAL BY YEAR 2000 .' 5b 2 . Sonoma, Sylvan to Claretina 6a Claretina to Claribe'l 6b Claretina 7a Claretina to Claribel 7b Lakewood, Sylvan to GRAND TOTAL - Table 5-14 iIODATED BY PRIORITY SEWER TRUNK EXTENSIONS Neighbor- Percent' of Prime hood Gross Agriculturial Served Acres Land Ycsemi te 7 28 Empire West 788 Roselle 489 Merle 491 Claus . 477 Merle East First 80% 234 3,207 . Merle East Remaining 20% 58 blab 1 e 490 Oakdale 49 2 Santa Fe 457 Plainview . 457 - 5,267 100% 100 75 . 60 10 10 . 70% 10 25 25 . 0 0 48x2 Potential Net Populat'ion Residential Potentially Acres , Accommodated 437 10,925 473 11 825 29 3 295 7,325 7,375 286 2,150 140 3,500 2,924 48,100 35 875 29 4 7 I 350 295 7,375 I. F' 274 6,850 274 6 850 3,096 - Cumulative Total 10 I 925 22,750 30,075 i. 37,450' ::, . .. c. 44 600 48 , 100' 48,100 48,975 56,325 63 , 700 70,550 77 , 400 I 77,400 'New population by year 2000 as given in Table 5-7. 2.Weighted average of preceding percentages in column. Source: Gross acreages of neighborhoods from City of Modesto (Osner, pers. corn.) ; percent of prime agricultural land. estimated approximately by referring to prime and nbnpri.me soils map in Draft EIS; potential net residential acres estimated by GG+A as 60 percent of total gross acres based on review of neighborhood prototype; population capacity based on 25 persons/net residential acre from City of Modesto ektimates (Osner, pers. corn.) for two other recent neighborhoods. t L" -""L ~ I Anow for a Mix of Densities in Future DeveZopment. The neighborhood pratotype assumes that newlydeveloping areas will contain mix- of densities. Of th total resi- dential development-in an "average" new neighborhood, 48 percent is earmarked for R-2 or R-3 development, with maximum densities of 14.5 and 28.0 units per acre, re- spectively. In addition to the provision for higher density zones, the entire R-1 zone in the prototype carries a P-D overlay, so that actual' densities can be considerably that route. ' higher than standard R-1 zoning if the subdividers choose . If developed to the maximum permitted, overall den- . sities under the prototype would be 9 units/gross acre - as compared with 4.8 units/gross acre, the density figure (reflecting historic preferences .in Modesto) used in the land absorption forecast of this EIS. The .neighborhood prototype approach both permits and facilitates higher densities than Modesto's historic pattern. .. Target Neighborhood Densities. The prototype allows hisher densities, but does not mandate them. A*-developer wh6 is proposing a subdivision in an R-2 or R-3 zone can propose R-1 densities, and, in the past, the city has approved many subdivisions with densities well below the maximum permitted. In order to help assure that oppor- tunities for higher densities are.not foregone in this manner, Modesto staff will, for all future neighborhoods, establish a density goal based on both the prototype and the land ownership pattern in newly developing areas. Monitoring the Density of New Development. ' Modesto will monitor the density levels of new neighborhoods as they develop as part of the annual review of the Urban Gr?owth PoZicy. This monitoring will help to guide de- velopment approvals in a manner consistent with the city's * ' objective of increasing overall density to 7.0 units per net acre by 1985. Mitigation Via Intergovernmental Cooperation. A number of .the important actions taken in the Modesto area to help reduce agriculture's loss of land to urban uses have resulted from actions. by .Stanislaus County and its agencies, such as the Local Agency Formation Commission (LAFCO), typically with support of or in partnership with . the City of Modesto. Such joint efforts offer a valuable model to other localities, recognizing, that prptection of agricultural lands requires coordination and coopera- tion among all local agencies with land planning respon- sibilities. .Because these measures are not implementable directly by the City of Modesto, they are presented only briefly here. .. - 98 - c 0 . ,. . .. Limiting Parcel Division in Rural Areas. Stanislaus County permits lot splits in agricultural. zoning districts only upon a finding by the Board of Supervisors that the proposed split will serve an agricultural purpose. The county's 1979 rezoning to agriculture of substantial acreages around Modesto, Oakdale and Riverbank formerly classified as rural residential increases the impact of this measure. Agricultural Element of County General Plan. Stani- slaus County established an agricultural study group in ,1978 to review agricultural land issues and make recom- mendations to the Board of Supervisors on such matters as minimum lot size in agricultural zoning districts and the preparation of an agricultural element of the general plan. Modesto has offered staff support in the development of a county agricultural element. ., Implementation and Effectiveness of Mitigation Measures As noted earlier, mitigation measures are effective only when they reduce the adverse impact of a project below what it would have been in the absence of any measures. There is little doubt that Modesto's mitigation pro- gram as outlined in this chapter will reduce the urban demand for agricultural lands. The reduction will be accomplished by a mix of complementary and overlapping strategies which (1) encourage infill, thereby increasing densities of currently developed areas; (2) increase the density CF newly-developing areas; and (3) reduce .urban pressures on agricultural lands both generally (by reducing the amount of agricultural land needed to accommodate a given level of urban growth). and in specific fringe areas of the city. a Quantifying the impacts of these measures is a diffi- cult task for many reasons. Because certain measures over- lap, the advantages of one preclude the advantages of the overlapping measure. For example, where P-D zoning is . used in place of R-1 zoning', measures available to increase . density in R-1 districts are foregone in favor of the den- sity increases permitted by P-D. Because of such overlapping, the density gains estimated for various measures are not additive. Another complication in estimating the impacts of mitigation measures is the fact that developers will con- tinue to enjoy some flexibility within Modesto's planning and development controls with regard to housing type and density. This flexibility.is desirable because it helps to assure that Modesto housing will.be able to satisfy most consumer preferences, thereby minimizing spillover i " - 100 - . . - I development to other areas. But it also means that the actual land absorption of new development 'cannot be pre- dicted with a high degree of accuracy - an order-of- magnitude estimate is the best measure of impact possible. Finally, in some cases not enough information is available to estimate impacts quantitatively. For example, the number of oversize R-1 lots is not known. In other cases, assumptions as to how certain measures will be implemented r,emain to be verified. For example, a maximum lot size of 10,000 square feet has been assumed, .but the final determination has not yet been made by the city. Table 5-15 provides a summary of the main elements of .the city's mitigation program, including estimates of the potential impact of individual measures wherever esti- mates were. possible, and the status of implementation. The immediate effect of the new mitigation package will probably lie in the vicinity of a five percent de- crease in agricultural land absorption below what it would have been in 1985 without the new maasures. This estimate is based on Modesto's commitment to achieve an increase in overall city residential density of six percent between 1979 ' and 1'985. The various measures set forth in Table 5-15 appear to offer sufficient opportunity for increased resi- dential density to make that six percent improvement realistic and probay-,ly somewhat conservative. On the other hand, the density gains in residential land use are unlikely to be matched by compara.ble gains in other use,s. - industrial, commercial, and public - which are less amenable to density reduction. * The five percent reduction applies to the period end- ing in 1985. Beyond that year, assuming the same measures are in effect, an additional five percent reduction during the 1985 to 1990 period appears to be a reasonable expecta- tion. Beyond that point, the reduction is assumed to ' stabilize as most vacant infill sites will have been de- veloped, and further infill could be accomplished only . through redevelopment. On a rough basis,. over the period .' of time during which the full wastewater project attains capacity, 'a reducti-on of 10 percent in agricultural land absorption is a defensible estimate of the overall impact' of the mitigation package developed by Modesto in response to the Draft EIS. This impact buil-ds upon and extends the 20 percent reduction,in agricultural land absorption that prior 'measures in the 1970's have already accomplished. 1 -1 -..a I 7 :i .i .. .. - 101 - Table 5-15 . ' MODESTO I s. AGRICULTURAL LAND MITIGATION PROGRAM: IMPACT SUMMARY AND TIMETABLE FOR IMPLEMENTATION. .. Implementation Status: Measures of Land Needed of Land Needed :' 0 Under Consideration New (July 1979) .I Effect on Amount EEfect on Location a Adopted . B Amend Urbm Growth Pol- Negligible. icy to contain a policy statement that all resi- dential growth should be within the city. Enforces continguity, reduc- 9 Considered and approved ing pressure for agricultural by Modesto City Council, land conversion. August 7, 1979. 8 Amend Urban Growth Pol- An increase from 6.6 to None. 0 Considered. and approv~d icy to contain a goal 7.0 du/net acre reduces by Modesto City Coun; 1, of increasing city resi- land requirements by about August 7, 1979. dential density to 7.0 6 percefit. units/net acre by 1985. r. 1. , I Revise Genera1 Plan to None. .Preserves appr0xirnati1.y 1,045 o Amendment and EIR tb be 0 urban reserve area on . .. reduce extent of the the east. road for at lea+ the next anticipated April 1.980; c" acres of prime agricultural prepared by February 138C lands east of the'Santa Fe Rail- Planning Commission actic .w 1.' two decades . Council action, May 1900. E Expand and clarify ' Negligible. Channels growth toward and on 0 Considered and approved . priority list for nos-prime soils; allows for de- by Modesto City Council, trunk sewer exten- velopment of 1,018 acres by year August .7, 1979. sions. 2000 on non-prime soils that might otherwise fiave absorbed 1 prime' soils. Amend Zoning Ordinance Permits additional.develop-- Encourages infill; reduces UT- 0 Amendment has been draft to make the R-1 Zone mcnt on oversize lots in ban demand for agricultural Planning Commission acti a density zone. previously-developed R-1 lands. anticipated January 1980. Council action, Fcbrua.ry Zones. 1 ' 1980. ." Table 5-3.5, continlmd i '. .. ~ Implementat New (July 197.9) kffec.t on mount . ' Effect on Location 0 Adopted Measures . of Land Needed of Land Needed 0 Under Con 8 Amend Zoning Ordinance Change from 6,000 to 5,000 Reduces urban demand for, agri- . Amendment k to reduce the minimum square feet allows a maximum cultural land,s. Planning Cc lot size in R-1 and R-2 ' reduction in land requirements anticipatel Zones to 5,000 square of 16 percent. Council act feet. 1980. Amend Zoning Ordinance to add a maximum lot size to the R-1 Zone. Other Recent, (1978-79) Keasures Duplexes on corner lots in new subdivisions. il Permit small annexa- . I tions in South Modesto; W reduce concentration of c.' 0 annex county enclaves; subsidized housing. I Maximum lot size of 10,000 square feet could reduce single-family subdivision land requirements by 5 percent. 2 If fully realized, would re- duce by 18 percent the land requirements of'new single- family subdivisions. None. Reduces urban demand for agri- 0 Same. cultural lands. 1 Reduces urban demand for agri- 0 In eftect. cultural lands. .. ... 1. : . %. Encourages infill; reduces ur- 0 In e.ffect. ban demand for agricultural lands. . .. Major Prior (1977 and Earlier) Measures P-D Zoning If fully'realized, could re- Encourages infill (especially @In effect. duce land that would otherwise by higher-density single-family be absorbed by R-1 development, structures) and reduces land re- by 37 percent:' quirements of new subdivisions. I B Neighborhood prototype At 75 percent buildout,, allows Reduces urban demand for agri- .In effect.. for 38 percent higher density cultural lands. than 1976 levels. 4 'Impact cannot be quantified because the number of oversize lots is not known. 2Estimate based on 1977 subdivision data, assuming that lots in excess of 10,000 square feet average 15,OOC 'Maximum R-1 density is 7s units/acre compared to 10 units/acre under P-D zoning, resulting in a potential feet in area. 37 percent in land absorption. At a buildout of 75 percent of maximum allowable density, the prototype yields 6.825 units/gross acre comp 1976 city average of 4.95. 4 Source: Modesto Planning and Community Development Department and Gruen Gruen + Associates. F .. " A , , ,,'. * In addition to gains in agricultural retention result- ing from revisions in residential development regulations, gains will also be realized via infrastructure extension policies which give.weight to soils type in determining the priority areas for urban expansion. Approximately 960 acres of non-prime soils will be developed by 2000 (and 1,700 thereafter); these lands will be developed in lieu of con- verting prime agricultural iand to urban use. In Table 5-16 are summarized the agricultural land re- tention results of complementary Modesto policies concerning urban development and infrastrvcture extension. The table presents total urban land needs, residential land needs, and prime agricultural land conversion under three conditions: ' unmitigated (i-e., a return to pre-1970 development patterns), partially mitigated (reflecting the programs put: in effect by Modesto and Stanislaus County prior to the publjcation of the Draft EIS) and mitigated via new land development regula- tions proposed as a response to the Draft EIS. These first three sets of estimates indicate that most urban land needs would be met via agricultural land,conver- sion in the absence of the infrastructure extension priorities recently established. The mitigation measures of greatest immediate importance are those relating to land development regulations. However, the infrastructure extension priority system begins to emerge as extremely i-mportant.once the Sonoma and Lakewood trunks are extended beyond Floyd into the north- east area which contains the major areas of non-prime land in Modesto's ultimate sewer service area.. Once the Lakewood trunk is extended beyond Floyd (priority 5 as listed in Table growth will drop from about 87 percent (of major residential land needs) to about 12 percent. '5-14), the prime agricultural land *sorbed by residential This retention effect would be achieved sooner but for the Yosemite trunk extension; the area served by that facility is totally prime. However, there are other compelling reasons to proceed with the Yosemite extension, which will permit development of one of Modesto's largest infill 'areas. The area to be developed once the Yosemite trunk is extended is currently encompassed by development on three sides. Further- more, this area, of the potential residential expansion areas .available,.is closest to major employment centers both down- town and in the Beard industrial tract. From the perspective of overall efficiency in the land llse'pattern, including'con- 'sideration of commute distances and related air quality .impacts, the Yosemite extension can legitimately be given ' cultural. land. priority even though it will serve development on prime agri- .. .. - 104 - .- ':Table 5-16 PRIME AGRICULTURAL ACREAGE RETAINED 1984 Project) UNDER MODESTO'S MITIGATION PROGRAM Urban Land Needs Unmitigated Partly Mitigated (Existing Condition) * With New Land Development Regulations3 Residential Land Needs Unmitigated' Partly Mitigated (Existing Condition) With New Land Development Regulations4 Prime Agricultural Land Conversion Unmitigated' Partly Mitigated (Existing Condition) With New Land Development Regulations' Prime Agricultural Land Retained via Total Mitigation Program: 1995 (capacity (Capacity of Initial of Full 1,370 1,095 1,065 ' 870 695 665 1,025 820 . 790 .. Retention via New Land Development Regulations' . 235 Retention via New Infrastructure Extension Totai Acres Retained 235 6 0 Priori ties Acres of Prime Agricultural Land Retained as Percent of Frime Agricultural Land Conversion 23% in Unmitigated Condition Project) 5,770 4,615 4,295 4 010 3,210 *- 2,890 4,480 3,585 3,275 1,205 55 1,260 28%' 2000 8 050 6,440 5,980 5 , 700 4 I 560 4,100 6,650 5 I 320 4,860 1,790 1,020 2,810 42% 'As discussed in the text, measures adopted in the 1970's have reduced agricultural land absorption by about 20 percent from what it would otherwise have'been. Thus, acreage estimates for the unmitigated condition are those figures wnich, reduced by 20 percent, yield the estimate given for the'partially mitigated condition. 2The EIS forecast, as presented in Table 5-7, p. 25. 3'Total acres required in partly mitigated condition (preceding row) minus change in residential acres required between partially mitigated condition and condition with new land development regulations. 4Residential land requirements under partial mitigation (preceding row) have been reduced by 1 percent for each elapsed year to 1990. That is, in 1981, required residential acres under new regulations are 1 percent less than under partial mitigatic:n; in 1982, 2 percent less, and so forth. After 1990, a 10 percent re- duction is maintained. 'The EIS forecast, as presented in Table 5-8, p. 26. 'Deducts difference in residential land needs from agricultural land conversion in I 'Agricultural land absorption in the unmitigated cpndition minus agricultural land the partly mitigated condition. . absorption under new development regulations. 'Calcu1,ated from data presented in Table 5-14, p. 97. Source: Gruen Gruen + Associates .. - 105 - .. . .. ... , , Programs like Modesto's - including both the mitigation measures adopted prior to the Draft EIS and those developed subsequently - can reduce this conversion. For example, a 40 percent .reduction in conversion.of agricultural land * to prban use would retain 5,600,000 acres of that land in agriculture. While the actual number of acres retained from one jurisdiction to another may seem insignificant viewed- in isolation, the cumulative effects are substantial, argu- ing that no community with prime. agricultural land resources should ignore agricultural land retention issues in its plan- ning, development and infrastructure extension decisions. .' . .. END OF REPORT ANOTHER DOCUMENT FOLLOWS .. I .*- L' .. . .. CHAPTER 1 COMPENSATORY PROGRAMS FOR PRESERVING AGRICULTLRE I ! I I .. 1. Preferential property tax assessment; 2. -Transfer of development rights; 3. Purchase and lease-back; sand 4. Other methods. Compensatory prnc~rarns such as these are capable of providing positive incentives for using land 'for agricultural purposes. The provision of some Form of ccnpen- sation to owners of land restricted to agricultural use may also be desirable as a m'eans of mitigating adverse economic effects of governmental regulatory decisions. PREFERENTIAL PROPERTY TAX ASSESSMENT: THE WILLIAMSON ACT , Introduction Naticnxide, one of the mst popuiar methods of providing compe,nsation I to cwners of land restricted to agricultural use is preferential propertly tax assessment. Comnly, land so restricted is assessed based not on its marqet value but on its value for agricultural uses. According to a 1977 report 412 states have tluse-value'' assesment programs for asricultural or other opes;-space lands. California's program was enacted in 1965 as the California La;r,d Conservation Act, or Williavson Act. By 1976, 47 OF California's 58 counties pa'rticipated in the program, mkinc. it one of the most important in the United Sta'tes. The Williamson Act permits participating counties in Cal'iforni!a to enter into contracts with owners of agricultural or open space land. The. contracts restrict the use of the land and limit its potential for subdivision in exchange fcr a reduction in property tax. The contracts run for a pzriad of ten years and are renewsd aucomarically each year. The amount of the tax reduction is based an the difference between the asricultural value of the property and its mzrkct value. " -i I The Co~inty of San Diego has been an active partiripant in the Uilliamson Act program since 1969. The following table shows the total dollar value of taxes saved each year by those property owners with lands under contract. . .. .- .. . 'I .. .. . .. -. . TAX YEAR TAX SAVINGS 1969-70 1970-7 1. 1571 -72 1972-73 1973-74 - 1974-75 1975-76 1976-77 1977-78 TOTAL $ 204,612 270,745 425,175 727 ,ea9 1,025,045 1,280,753 1,443,599 1,663,008 1,732,376. $8,772,322 The goals of the Williamson Act are expressed within the Act itself, as Pollows: I. That the preservation of a maximum amount of the limited 1 I i supply of pri:ne agricultural land is necessary to the conservation of the state's economic resources, and is necessary rvat only to the niaintenance of the agricuitural economy of the state, but also for the assurance of adequate, healthful, and nutri tioirs food for future I f '. residents of this state and nation; I I 2. That the discouragement of premature and unnecessary conversion of prime agricultural land to' urban uses is a matter of public interest, and will be of benefit to urban dwellers themselves, in that it will discourage discontiguous urban development patterns which unneces- sarily increase the cost of community services to community residents; i I 3. That in a rapidly urbsnizing society, agricultural lands I . have a definite public value as open space, and the I preservation in agricultural production of such lands, the use of which may be limited under the provisicns - of this chapter, constitutes an important physical, social, esthetic, and economic zsset to existing or . pending urban or mstropolitan development (Section I i 1 i .- 51220, California Government Code): .. I I i I . .. -. These staternents make it clear that the State legislature intended that the Act would.be used to further land use planning goals of preserving agricultural land and containing urban sprawl, while providing open space to be used for agricul- ture. Let us examine the relationship between these goals and thc actual use of the Williamson Act program in San Diego County. First, has it helped cause the preservation of a maximum amount of the limited supply of prime agricultural land in the County? The answer to this questicn depecds on what is meant by "prime agriculturzl ,land." Such land is defined ir! the Act as follows: (1) All land which qualifies for rating as Class I or Class II in the Soil Conservation Service land use capability classifications; .. (2) Land which qual ifies for rating 80 through 100 in the Storie Index Rating. (3) Land which supports livestock used for the prduction capacity equivslept to at least one animal unit per Agriculture. . acre as defined by the United Ststes Department of (4) Land planted with fruit- 3r nut-bearing trees, vines, bushes or crops which have a nonbearing period of less than five..years and which will normally return during .the commercial bearing period on an annual. hasis from . the production of unprocessed agricultural plant pro- duction not less than two hundred dollars ($200) per acre. .. (5) Land which ha5 returned from the production of unprocessed agricultural plant products an annual gross value of not less thsn two hundred dollars ($200) per acre for three 1 of the previous five years. According to one source there are 192,300 acres of "prime" land in the County. Of this acreage, 3.1 percent, or 17,433 acres were under contract during the 1975-76 tax year. More recently, the San Diego County Assessor has reported that, for the !978-79 tax year, there are 20,807 acres of prime agricultural land under contract out of a total of 135,679 acres under contract. Thus, only 15 percent of the land in the County now under contract is prime agriculturai land. . .. ' .. .' I. .. Second, has the Willfawon Act program in San Diego Cc--.iy helped contain urban Sprawl? To answer th: :;wT;tion onc must analyze the ,)atiaI distribution of the lands under contract. A map showing the location of all corltrac:t lands reveals that most of the contract lands lie far to th? east of the urbanized areas of San Diego County. The lands under contract lying within or near urban areas are relatively smaller- and discontigtious in comparison to the vast tracts in the more remote areas. The overall effect of these contracts on the spatial characteristics of urban growth would appear to be minor. One reason for the present spatial distribution of lands under contract is the voluntary nature of the Williamson Act program. The law provides for the County to establish agricultural preserves for the purpose of idbntifying which lands should be eligible for contracts. However, the County has never attempted to estab1 ish ayricul tural preserves for the purpose ,of keeping agricul tur-a1 !and from being urbanized unless the owner desired to sign a Land Conservation Contract. In general, the County has only established preserves in response to the expressed desires of landowners to sign contracts. Exceptions to this policy have occurred only in the more remote areas of the County. Thus almost all of the land within agricultural preserves but not under contract is located far from any urbanizing areas. The agricultural preserves that do exist near urban areas are generally coterminous with the boundaries of land under contract. Third, has the Williamson Act program served to foster ayricul tural production on agricultural lands? The answer to this question can be approached by analyz- ing what lands are under contract. This analysis wi 11 shotr wh,o the beneficiaries are of the Vi lliamson Act in San Diego County. Once the beneficiaries are known, one can attempt to evaluate the extent to which the tax benefits of the Wi 11 ianlson Act appear to foster actual agricultural production. The following questions are asked as the basis for this analysis: 1. How many acres of land devoted to particular agricultural activities is .. under contract? 2, How much OF the total annual tax savicgs under the County's Vi 11 iamson Act program supports each agricultural activity? .. '3. What is the average percentage of tax savings by agricultural activity? The answer to the first of these questions is found in the table helaw, as reported by the San Diego County Assessor as of 14arch 1, 1978. AGRI CULTURAL ACT I V 1 TY ACREAGE ' % OF TOTAL - Grazing and Dry Farming 122,217 88.2 .. Trec Crops 10,127 7.3 I rr i ga ted Crops .2,346 1.7 . . Flo~ers 1,1013 .a space easenients) 2,807 - 2.0 TOTAL 138,605 100.0 .Other (includes open "-L- . . .. Note that 88.2 percent of the total acreage under contract is classified as land for grazinc; or dry farming. AVERAGE Q AGRl CULTURAL TAX SAVI NG ACT I V ITY TAX SAV I tlG % Of: TOTAL TO OWNE!? Grazing $1,O83,890 63% 80% Tree Crops 336 178 '1 9% 42% Flowers 180,442 10% 61% I rr i ga ted Crops 45 , 625 3% 74% Dry Farming 39,101 2% 63% Open Space Easements 21,835 .. 1% 75% Dairies . 19,302 18 66% _I TOTAL $1,727,374 The answers to'these three questions c?early show that by far the principal beneficiaries of the Will iarnson Act in San Diego County are the owners of grazing land. Grazing is the most predonlinant agricultural activity under contract; owners of grazing land receive 63 percent of the total t'ax savings in San Ciego County from the Williamson Act program; graziag results in thz highnst percentage tax savings of all the agricultural activities. Thus it appears that, in San Diego County, the Williamson Act program has provided the strongest incentives for owners of grazing land to sign Land Conservation Contracts. This relative emphasis of the program on grazing wou!d make more sense if livestock made up an important segment of this County's ayri- Cultural production. iiowever, as shown in the tGbie beiow, cclt of a gross value of $335 million in agricultural sales in 1977, only $5.8 million was derived from cattle and calves. These fisures are reported in the 1377 Agricultural Crop Report prepared by the County Department of Ayricu! ture. .. . '. .- .. ." . .. PERCENT OF CROP DOLLAR VALUE . TOTAL VALUE Tomatoes Eggs Avocados Milk Valencia Oranges Strawberries Lemons Carnations (Standard) Cattle and Calves $63,332,000 5lY408,0G0 50,958,000 24,701 .,OOO 7,721,000 6,634,000 5,654,000 , 5,824,000 17,830,000 18.9% 15.3 14.9 7.4 5.5 2.3 2.0 1.7 1.7 Cattle and calves were the ninth most valuable agricultural comnodity in 1977, comprising only 1.7 percent of the value of all agricultural commodities. Significant also is the fact that the signing of a Land Conservation Contr'sct in'no w;iy obligates the owner to use any OF his land for agricultural purpcses. The owner may enjoy his. tax break without producicg an agricultural conmdity. The contract provides disincentives and restrictions on nonagricultural uses, rather than positive incentives for agricultural use. The discuisions above lead to the conclusion that, in San Diego County, the Wi 11 ianson Act progrm does not appear to have been encouraging wners of la~d suitable for the prodcction of the County's mst important agric.ultura1 cmanodi- ties to sign Land Conservation Contracts. One might yet, however, conclude that the progran has, in accordance with the third goal of the Williamson Act itself, fostered the agricultural use of open space land by discouraging nonagricultural use of grazing land. However, one could hardly argue that this has been the most efficient or productive use of the County's investnent in the Kiliiamson Act program. Effect of Proposition 13 on the Williamson Act Program It must also be noted that the Wi 11 iarnson Act program, 1 ike many others, wi I? be . sigrlificantly affected by Proposition 13, the Jarvis-Gann property tax initiative. As the discussion bzlow derconstrates, the property tax savings incentive for signing or renewing a Wil 1 iamson Act contract wi 11 be greaily reduced 5y Proposi- tion 13. In scme cases, the tax savings formerly attributable to the Williamson Act contract may now be exceeded by the savings attributable to Proposition 13 even if no contract is signed. -1 I _. . .. .. .. This discussion wi 11 compare various examples to show the difference made by the passage of Proposition 13 on the tax savings resulting from signing a Cli 11 ianlson Act contract. Each example below is computed on a per acre basis for a typic31 mature avocado orchard in Valley Center. Estimates of market values, restricted County Assessor's Off ice. . or agricultural values, and tax rates were received from personnel from the K II 1975 1978 - rtarket Vilue (typical) $7,500 $15,000 Restricted Value (typical) $G,ooo $ 6,000 - tiow taxes were computed before Prooosition 13 -- Had Proposition 13 not passed, I9";ri;rty taxes would have been conlputed by multiplying the tax rate times the assessed value of the property. In Examples 1 and 2 a typical tax rate for Valley Center was selected equal to $.IO28 per dollar of assessed value. In Example 1 the assessed value is equal to one-quarter of the "restricted" or agricuittiral use value ~f the land under Wi 11 ianson Act contract. " Example 1 -- 1978 tax per acre on land not under contract had,Proposition 13 not passed : - " Tax = (Tax Rate) (Assessed Value) = (Tax Rate) (Market Value) = "-7 = (.1028) ($15,000) = $385.50/aere _71_1 Example 2 -- 1978 tax per acre on land under contract had Proposition 13 not . passed: " Tax = (Tax Rate) (Restricted Assessed Value) = - (Tax Rate) (Restricted Value) = 4 = (,1028) ($6 030) = $154.20/acre " .. -. How taxes are computed under Propos i t ion 13 -- Under Propos i tion 13, property taxes shgi 1 be levied at no more than one percen; of the full 1975 property value, adjusted annually by a two percent inflaticn rate, as shown below: 1978 property tax = -01 (1975 full value) (1.~)~ where .01 is' the one percent tax rate and (1.~)~ rcpresents three years of .- inflation at a rate of two percent. .. : . .. If ownership of the property has changcd since 1975, than one percent 01'. its full v;.lue at the time of sa two percent inflation rate. Example 3 -- 1978 tax on land - not under contract but Tax (.01) (1975 t?arket Value) (2% inflat the tax shall be no more e, adjusted annually by the according to Proposition 13: on for 3 years) How taxes are computed under Proposition 13 for property mdcr Cli lliamson Act contract -- Property mder \.li 1 Tianson Act (Caiifornia Land Conservatiom contract wi 11 be taxed based on its 1975 ayricul tural or "restricted" value, adjusted by the two percent inflation rate, as shown below: 1978 property tax = .Ol (1975 restricted value) (1-02) 3 For property now ur?der contract but not under contract in 1975, the tax is computed based on the restricted value at the time of sale, adjusted for infla- tion. Summary of Examples -- 1378 tax per. acre avocado land, if: 1. No Proposition 13 and no contract - $385.SO 2. No Proposition 13 but under contract - $154.20 3. Proposition 13 but no contract - $79.59 4. Proposi tion 13 and undcr contract - $63.67 The most important effect on the Williamson Act program will be the apparent reduction in incentive for property-owners to enter into new contracts. The incentive will be reduced because the dollar value of tax savings resulting from the contract will be greatly reduced. The effect of Proposition 13 on, for example, acreage planted in avocados' but not ur;der contract would be to reduce taxes by as much as 80 percen:. This savings Is based on the approximately 60 percent reduction in tax rate coc!pled with the fact that 1975 prcper-ty value may be only 50 percent of 1978 property value. Signing a contract now should s.ti 11 result in a tax savings to the property owner. HGwever, the dollar amount of that tax savings may seem.insiynificant relative.to that amount saved solely'because of Proposition 13. Another possible effect of Proposition I3 may be increased numbers of property owners with lands now under contract deciding not td renew their contracts. When property owners decide not to renew, each yecir for ten years they pay an increasing percentage of what would have been their taxes had their land not on the full 1975 value, adjusted for inflation by only two percent per year. These paynlents will b:l considerably less than they would have been without Proposition 13 because the tax rate has been reduced by approxima:ely '60 percent and the two percent inflation rate is far belo:?l the actual inflatior. rate for property value. ! been under contract.' Undcr- Proposition 13, these yearly paynlents will be based A further possible effect of Prdpositicn 13 on the Williamson Act program rnsy he to increase the number of petitions for outright cancellation of contt-arts. The Board of Supervisors may cancel a contract at the owner's request and impose a cash penalty equal to 12-1/2 - 25 pe.rcent of tne "full cash value of the land as though it were free of contractual restriction" (Section 51283, Government Code; see also Board of Supcrvisors Policy 1-38), Before Proposition 13 was passed, this "full cash value" meant market value. Now it means 1975 market value adjusted at only a two percent inflation rate. Since market value has been increasing at a much higher rate than two percent, as each year goes by the maxinwm dollar value of the czncellation penalty becomes less and less an effective disincentive to petition the Board of Supervisors for a contract cancellation. Already since the passage of Proposition 13, one property owner- has successfully petitioned the Board of Supervisors for a cancellation. Conclusion " The following conclusions can be made from the above discussion: 1.. In the last nine years, the Williamson Act has provided tax savings of over $8.7 million to owners of contract lands. .. 2. Only !5 percent of the land under contract rwets the definitions of prim agricu? tural land. 3. Contract lacds are most likely to be lccated far from urSan areas and suitable only for grazing, a relatively unimportant segrreni of our agricul- tu ra I economy. 4. The passage of Proposition 13 significantly reduces the incentive for entering into or continuing a Land Conservation Contract. Thus, it seems that the Williamson P.ct program in San Diego County has been of linlited public vaiue relative to the qoals of tile Act itself. The program has not been espscially effective as a means of effecting the Act's land use planning goals of preserving prime agricultural land or containins urban sprawl. The open space preserved through the program has, by and large, not been land suitable for highly productive agricultural use or subject to the pressures of urban growth. In the future, the program will probably be even less successful because the limitations on the property tax reduce the incentives to participate in the program. It is likely that the progr-am no:.r provides highest incentives for owRet-5 of land unsuitab!e for any use at all to enter into or continue contracts which provide them with zn 80 percent tax reduction. .* h *- .. TRANSFER OF DEVELOPHEIIT RI CtITS Another method of providing compensation to owners of land restricted to agri- cultural use is a proposed system known as "transfer of development rights," or TDR. The principle on which TDR is based is that 1and.ownership nay bc considered to consist of the title to various rights. One of the norma1 rights of ownership is the right to develop or improve property. Under TDR, this right Is separated from the other rights of ownership and nay be ptJr-chased by others. Under one type of development rights transfer, a governmental agency would purchase developmnt rights of land the agency.desircd not to he developd. This kind of program Is often called PDR, "purchase of development rights." Except for this case, TDR involves the estaslishment of a market for developm~nt rights to be sold by owners of land planned "- not to be developed to owners of land planned for developnent. Thus, governmental actions to restrict the development of certain lands WGUI~ not necessarily have their usual effect of lowering th:: value of the owner's invest- ments in those lands. c1 portion of those investments would consist of the devel- opment rights, the sale of which would provide compensation to the owners of lands restricted from development. in order to set up a TDR prcgrarn for the purposc of restricting certain Iznds to agricultural ~se, the governmental jurisdiction nlaaacjing the proyram would designate sites for agricultural preservation and for development and would issue certificates of development rights. Each owner would receive certificates based on some eqult- able principle of distribution. One system would be to issue certificates zarres- ponding to the lnaxirilun nunder of dxell ing units each obmer nlight have been permitted prior to the adoption of tqe plan to be implemented by the TO?, proposal. 'Then mrners of developable Iar?d/mtild be req5ircd to pt:rchsse developccnt rights from the omers of undevclopabl4 land in order to develop their land at mare than a rnInirr,um intensity. I According to Cavid I-. Peteeson, fiscal and c-zonornic consultant to the Regional Growth kmgenent project, :transfer of developwnt rights has both advan:s?es and disadvantages as a technique of plan implcnierltaticn, as listed below: Advantaqes 1. I .+ " _. 1. Consistent with established constitutional principles. 2. More politically acceptable than public acquisition or stringent zoning wl thout compensa t i on .) 3. Hinor expenditure of public funds. 4. Alleviates ''windfa1 Is" and "wipeouts"; prcmotes equity. 5. Fleiibili ty; can protect any resource from market forces. " Disadvantages I. Too new and complex. 2. Will not work without proper economic conditions. -. * .. ' i I i I. I 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. k'ould take years to study and implement. May not work unless adopted regionally. Requires significant political conmittment to be credible to would-be participants. Ends may be more efficiently accomplished throcsh less complex mechanisms. May conflict with existing zoning and plans. Involves administrative and bookkeeping problems. Involves questions of property taxation of development rights. He concludes his discussion of TDR as follows: TDR is a complex implenlentation technique which would not be easily under- stood by the general public, the development industry, and local decision- makers. TDR would require a significant administrative structure with assciciated costs. TDR shares, with density bonuses, the problem that it is -relatively easy to identify areas from which to take rights, but it is rwre d'ifficult to identify areas to which rights wouId be transferred. FL!rther, such transfers coula reduce the effectiveness of existing Community Pians as well as create problems in capital facilities and service delivery planning. . . .[E]xtensive use of the technique seems premature at this time. ! would seem wiser to let others experiment, and to hold general use of in reserve for possible future application. .The Arroyo Group, consultant for the City of Riverside, California, recent t TDR 1 prepared a docuinent entitled "TDR: An Evaluation of the Potential for Uti1 the Transfer of Development Rights 2s a ;jeans for Implementation of the Arl Heights Plan and Growth Managment Program." This report proposes that TDR used in the Arlington Heights area for the following reasons: Y i z i n 3 i ng tor) be 1.' To ensure greater equity far property owners by eliminating or minimizing windfalls and wipeouts, and 2. As a means of acquiring or preserving public open spaces and envfronmentai resources. . This consultant's propGsal includes draft enab1in.g legislation and a city ordinance. Enabling legislation may,be necessary for a number of reasons, as listed bcloLr: I 1. So that.development rights can be cotlsiderred estates in real property which can be transfered, recorded, and insured; 2. So that land will be assessed for tax purposes based on the density and type of use permitted after development rights transfer; 3. To permit local agencies to require the recordation of TDR certificates to evidence the existence and transfer of development rights. . .. .. .. ". .. .. . . . .. CEAPTER 2 LAND USE REGULAT I Otis !- I LARGE-LOT ZONING Large-lot zoning is probably the-most common technique used in this country for the preservation of open space. Wherever land is not proposed for urban uses, that land is likely to be subject to large-lot zoning. This technique operates by directly affecting the process of dividing land. When land subject to large- lot zoning is subdivided, new lots can be made no smaller than some minimum size. How large this rnininlcm standard must be for it to be considered "large-lot zoniny" depends on the circumstances. In some situations, a 10,000 square foot lot size requirement may be considered "large." in another case, 600 acres may be the size of the large lots required. The theory behind the use of large-lot zoning ir that the private land subject to it will be more likely to remain as open space if it is not divided ipto small lots. \/here the dzsired open space use is agriculture, then large-lot zoning is often imposed in the hope that either the land wi 11 not be subdivided at all or that new lots will be large enough for agriculcural use. fheorctically, the imposition of large-lot zoning will prevent the speculative value of land from rising so much above its agricultural value that agriculture can no lozger be considered a permanent economic use. Large-lot zonir?g is now the principal technique used in San Diego County to preserve land for agricultural use. It is now imposed by three differer:: means -- by The Zoninc( Orciinaitc.e, by the General Plan, and by Williamson Act Contract. In the past, The County Zoning Ordinance contained four types of large-lot zones -- estate zones. asricultural zones, temporary zones, and the limited con%rol zone. These zones provided for minimum lot sizes ranging from ooe-half scre to twenty acres. The newly adopted Cclunty Zoning Ordinance'provides for the zFpiica- tion of any minimum lot size standard desired. This may be accomplished by apply- ing the desired lot size designation at the time racing Is adopted 01- revised 3r-1 a particular property. For exampls, under !.he old Zoning (jrdinance the agricultural zones of thc County provided a choice ot unly five different minimum lot sizes -- 1/2, 1, 2, 4, or 8 acres. Under the new Zoning Ordinance, the County has av.?i!able the legal machinery needed to expand the range of possible mininlunr lot sizes from these few to any size desired. What this means is that the County need no iongzr create and adopt new zones in order to impose new and different lot size reqc;i rz- ments. The County General Plan, since 1375, h2s included minimunl lot size standards over and above those required by The Zonir;g Ordinance. Land Rot planned for urban use may be subject to minimum lot sizes ranging from one to f0rt.y acres depending on slope, JCC~SS, water availability, and other criteria. Land designated, for example, as "Intensive Agriclrlture" may have minimum lot size standards of 2, 4,.or E! acres depending on certain critcria, I. . .. The table on the following page shows the acres of land in agricultural use for each land use planning category of the County Gerlcral Plan. Note that the three categories with the most acreage -- Rural Residential, Agricultural Estates - Medium, and Intensive Agriculture -- all permit lots as small as two acres. Together these three categories contain 52.5 percent of the land in the County in agricultural production. Other figures of note are that mpre than 11 percent of the land in agricultural use is now planned for urban use; almost 28 percent is planned in categories that permit lots as small as one acre; and almost 69 percent is planned in categories permitting lots as small as two acres. The significance of this analysis lies in the possibie ioss of agricultural production that nay result from the inpiementation of the County General Plan. If the General Plan is implemented in a way such that land in the County is divided into the mininum-sized lots perma'tted in each land use category, then many areas nevi in agricultural use will be divided into lots of two acres ar . smaller. Dividing land into lots this small may result in reduced agricultural production. Owners of small lots may chocse to take a1 1 or part of their land out of production in order to substitute residential uses or simply because not enocgh none:, can be made to make farming worthwhi le. 60ard of Supervisors' Pol icy l-_?G, "Agricultural Preserves," also contains minimum lqt size standards for land mder Land Conservation (Wi!lianson Act) Contract. These minimums depend on the agricultural activity and have ranged from 8 to bC0 a res. The larscst minimum lot size standard now ir?posed by Policy l-3e is 80 a$res, as zhowr; in the taSli: belcw. c Graz i ng Dry Fa rm i ng Cattle Sreeaing Horse Rreed i ng Poul try Dairies Tree Crops Truck Crops Flowers (Field) Flowers (tlothouse) .. GO acres 40 acres 40 acres .: .-. 40 acres 10 acres 20 acres 10 acres 10 acres 10 acres 10 acres .. - . Large-lot zoning has a number of important advantages over cther methods of agri- cultural preservation. The most important of these is that it is a regulatory technique based solely on the police pGwer of the state. Thus, it requires n3 direct expenditures by qovernrnent other than the costs of administering the program. Aside from being inexpens ive, the technique is easy to understand, relatively easy to adnini,ster, legally sound, and politically acceptable. Its legality and acceptabi 1 i ty are, however, subject to the liinitation that the standards imposed are reasonable. MAX I MUM PERMITTED ACRES OF L4ND IN LANP USE CATEGORY DENS i TY AGRICULTURAL USE .% OF TOTAL - Urban Categories Very Low Res i dent i a 1 Medium Low Residential Low Res i dent i a 1 LOW Medium Residential Medium Residential High Medium Residential Medium High Residential High Residential Office Commercial Nei ghborhood Comne rc i a 1 General Comaercial Heavy Industrial Idonurban Categories hral Residential Agricultursl Estates - Lon Agricultural Estates - Ned. Agricultural Ebtates - Rural Agricul?ural Preserves Intensive Agritul ture Moun ta i n Geve 1 c.pinen t Multiple Rural: usc National Foresfr I Other Categories! Floodplain j Open Space Pub1 ic, Semipubl ic Greenbel t Special Planning Area TOTALS Urbar: Nvnurban Other GRAND TOTAL 1 du/ac 2 du/ac 2.9 du/ac 4.3 du/ac 7.3 du/ac 10.9 du/ac 14.5 du/ac 29 ddac - 1 du/1,2,4 ac 1 tiu/4 ac 1 du/2 ac 1 Ju/2-4 ac 1 du/8 ac 1 du/2,4 $8 ac 1 du/4,8,?0 ac 1 du/4,8 ac 1 du/4,8,29 ac 1 du/4-8 ac 1 du/8 ac L. - (various) 1-29 du/ac 1 ddl-20 ac (various j I 18,982 1,173 22,286 5,564 13,327 20,104 7,703 6,370 681 116,753 1.03 0.89 2- 35 0.39 6.30 0.G3 0.13 0.06 0.07 0.01 0.06 0.17 16.25 1 .oo 19.08 4.75 11.41 17.21 6.59 5-45 0.58 3.04 0.36 0.53 0.22 1.95 11.48 82.38 6.12 There arc also a nuinber of important disadvantages to the use of large-lot zoning as a means of preserving agricult:,lral land. Probably the most important of these are tt-z problems of estahlishiRg large enough mininlum lot size stancl'ards and then maintaining them over time. Another disadvantage is that large-lot standards arc difficult politically to impose when their effect will be to lower the value of private investmznts in land. Even when such standards are imposed, the rational2 for their imposition may often be based on their temporary nature. For example, in this County, a minimum lot si7e standard of twenty acres is applied by Zoning Ordinance only when that ordinance was explicitly intended to be temporary. In additicn, the imposition of large-lot zoning nay have serious unintended economic effects when ttx land is owned by the samc party who fzrms it. In some cases, the owner-farmer is able to continue his agricultural acti- vities because of the rising value cf his lsnd investment. More stringent minimum lot size standards may lower this value, making it more difficult for the owner to obtsin r.lortoaGe money that he may need to finance his a9ricultural provide thc owner with an important source of capital he may need for continuing agricultural production. I -. . pursuits, The abil ity to sell off small' portions of thc property may also A further disadvantage of using large-lot zoning as a means of preserving agri- cu1t:lt'e is that the mere threat of its imposition, whether real or imayir!ed, may inflirence owners of agricultural land not to continue agricultural uses. There is sme evidence that this built-in disincentive for ayricul tvre my already be functioning in San Diego County. Landowners in at least one area have apparently stopped leasing their land for agricultural use because they . fear that the evidence oq such use will be a factor in the County's decisions the tcnporary agricultural use of their property have become willing to forgo that gain. This effect of the threat of large-lot zoning seems to have the most impact on our vecytable crops and field flowers. However, more permanent agri- cciitursl uses, such as orchards and greenhouses, may also have a1 ready been affected in this way. It should be noted that the present minimum lot sire criteria for the "Intensive Agricu!ture" land use category of the County General Plan provides incentives ,For tisiny land fcr agriculture. If land.has been planted for the previms year in certain crops, and some other criteria are met, then the land ray be considered for 2 rather than 4-acre lots. This offer of a smaller minimum loc size may serve as a counter-balance to the disincentive to agricultural use discussed a bave "Poir:ts System" Zonina Tulare County in California has established a corqrehensive program of large-lot zorting w$ere any requests for smaller lot zoning are evaluated by a detailed rating system. The purpase of this rating system is ro provide ex.plicit guide- lines for decision-makers to cse in considering mking exceprions tc the overall policy of preserving agriculture by means of laroe-lot zoning. Thus, tiulare Cwnty's large-lot zcning pro:Jrrarr! includes criteria for ilexibil icy. Where iand is lcss suitable for long-term agriculttlre, then, if certain criteria are met, smaller lot zoning may be granted. i to impose more stringent land use controls. Owners who would norna?iy gain fron? ._ .. c - . 0- 4 c i '. . .. - A The Tulare County rat; system w6t-ks a5 follows. if ,d zoned for large lots fs not within an agricultural preserve {Williamson Act) and is sui table for an individual waste disposal system, ihen points are awarded based on to what extent the property meets thirteen different criteria. In all, thirty points may be awarded for such features as soil classification, parcel size, land use, proximity to certain uses, water availability, fire protection, road access, historical or archaeological value, wildlife habitats,,unique natural features, and floodplains. The more points awarded, the more suitable the land is for agriculture. A low score, however, would provide the basis for deciding to rezone the property to permit smaller lot sizes. The most valuable feature of the Tu'lare County program is the explication of the factors to be considered in the decision-making process. Too often land use planning decisions are made on an arbitrary, inconsistent, or unclear basis. Getting a policy adopted which contains in great detail the criteria for decision- making would be a yreat step toward improving the credibility of the lacd use planning process. Explicit criteria, if adhered to, make planning regulations seem more objective an3 fair to the affected iandwmcrs. Another intcresting Feature of the Tulare County large-lot zoning prcqr-am is the inverse relationship between sui tabi 1 ity for agriculture and permi tted minimum lot size. Ten-, 20-, 40-, and 80-acre mirtinun lot sizes are imposed for agricultural preservation. The most productive !and is zoned for 10-acre minimums, the !east, for 80-acre minimums. The rationale for this inverse relationship is that more land is needed to run a profitable agricultural enterprise on less productive land. There are some apparent, but possibly minor, drawbacks to the Tulare- County "points" system. First, it would probably be d'ifficult to prepare a contpre- he!,sive rating system for San Diecjo County's agriczltural lands that cbuid work throughout the County. Our County seem much mare diverse in character thzn does Tulare and, therefore, might require an even more corcplicsted rating systeln for it to be expected to work rationally. Second, any coinpl icated rating system requires a certain amount of administrative effort to m;lke. it work. A system complex enough to be justifiable miyht,be too complicated to administer cffi- ciently. .. DENS I TY ZON 1 NG Density zoning is a commonly-used alternative to standard large-lot zonic2. The "quarter/qQarter" and "sliding scale" techniques discussed below, are forms of density zoning. With decsity zoning, the regulations determin.e hc~w n!any lots may be created out of a particular parcel. The emphasis is on the nu!nber of. lots, not on their size. For example, 2 density zone of one lot per IO acres, when applied to a 100 acre site, would result in 10 lots. For the purpose of prsscrving agriculture, it might be best iF 9 of these lots were I-acre hornesites, acd the remaining 91-acre lot were kept in agricultural ube. Under standard large-lot zoning, as used in this County, the 100-acre lot wmld be divided into 10, IO-acre lots. Where a particular agricultural enterprise on the 100-acre site requires more land than 10 acres to be profitable, it is likely that the division into lo-acre lots will result ir! a significant loss in production. Thus standard large-lot zorliilg may cause the subdivision of agricultural land .-' - into lots not large enough for continued agricultural prcduction. - I.L. .. a The following diagram shows the difference in the ultimate lot patter125 that may result frc:n the subdivision of a 100-acre parcel into 10 lots under standard large-lot zoning arrd under dens i ty zoning. The desirability of density zoning as an agricultural preservation technique is limited by the possibility that the creation of small lots, however few, for residential purposes will result in land use conflicts. Living next to a farm may seen idyllic to some, but pesticides, fertilizer, smudge pots, noisy machinery, flies, and noisy or smelly farm animals may prove to be unanticipated dra9backs. Complairlts from rural residents may be an important factor in the farmer's decision to consider nonagricultural use of his land. Such complaints may include threatened legal action or result in investigations by County authorities. In addition, the encouragement of a land use pattern of non-farm residences scattered thrcvghout rural areas may result in a nigh pub1 ic cost fer such services as school tus transportation. Density Zoning kfith Open Space Easements Dcnsity zoning has been uscd in this County in sone specialized situations. The most ccnnon of these has been in the grantins of special use perr:;its for Planned Residcntial Developments (FED's). PRD's are condominium subdivisions, where smal 1 building lots are sold individually and one or njore large lots are sold in cornxon to the residents to provide open space and recreational areas for al! of thm to own snd enjoy. Condoninium ownership arrangements have also been used in standard subdivisions to provide for the ownership of open space lots. Often these open space lots are created to protect very steep land from being developed. The open space lot is protected from resubdivision by ar! (?pen space eascxnt granted to th? Cotinty by the original subdivider. Such an ease- ment, in effect, transfers the right to develop the property to the County. The OWilerS of the residential lots then jointiy own the open space lot. Condominium ownership of an o?en space lot does not seem appropriate or necessary when such a lot is suitable for agricaf tural use. Even with a restrictive <)Fen space easement on the property, it could be retained by the. criginal o\nii;er icr continued agricultural use, or sold for this purpose. Oae problem this County has faced with open space lots has been the failure of Owners to make mortgage pdyments OI- pay property taxes. Foreclcsure can result in loss of the open space easement restrictions. Therefore any program to retain large lots in agricultural use by means of open space easements IT US^ be devised with this possible pitfall in mind. Another problem to be solved regarding dznsity zoning is how to encourage sub- dividers. to use it. If the owncr has the choice, he may prefer the more standard approach of subdividing land into large lots of equal size. In order to assure the retentior: of a large lot reserved for a5ricultural purposes, it nay be necessary to make chis approach mandatory. Cltherwise other inducements nay have to be offered, such as a dens i :y bonus or eventual expi ration of the open space easement. (State law allows oper! space easements tr, be granted for 20 .. year or lonyer periods.) . . " r4 Large-Lot Zoning Original I OO-Ac re Pa rce 1 Original' 1 OO-Acre Parce 1 I Density Zoning - New 91-Acre Lot I 5 New Onc-Acre Lots I .. * . .. I Quarter/Quarter Zoning Quar-ter/quarter zoning is a special kind of density zoning technique used in some counties in Minnesota. This technique permits a certain number of small lots to be located within each quarter of a quarter of a section of land. A quarter/qvarter section is one-sixteenth of a section, or approximately forty acres. If any quarter/qusrter section had already been divided into a number of lots equal to or greater than the number permitted, then no new lots Lvou1d be allowed within it. Quarter/quarter zoning was proposed as a more flexible a1 ternative to the standard large-lot zoning technique. Its purpose is to preserve agricultural land by keeping rnost of it in very large lots. In theory, the one or more small lots permitted in each quarterjquarter section will not interfere materialiy with :he .long-term agricultural use of the property. The ability to sell off a limited number OF small lots provides the owner with some income-earning potential over and above the agricultural value of his ?and. Another advantase of the technique is its ease of adwinistration by the land use control jurisdiction. Ai! that is needed for administration is accurate legal lot infornlation for all the land surveyed into sections. While quarter/quarter zoning offers a solution to some of the problems of standard large-lot zcining, its applicability to San Dieso Cosnty my be limited because of the fol lowing factors: 1. Not all of the County's agricultural land is surveyed into sections. The . tech ique could ngt be used within the Cai i forni a ranchos. 2. Much of th& County's agricultural land is already divided into parcels' smaller than 40 acres. Quarter/quarter zoning does ROC work well unless tile land is still in large tracts of 40 acres or, tzetter yet, multiples of 40 acres. Sliding Scale Zonina Another type of density zoning is the use of a "sliding scale" for the deternina- ticn of minimum lot size. With this technique, the subdivision of land is per- mitted in acccrdance with a ielxible standard -based on the size of the parcel proposed for subdivision. T!le larger the original parcel, the lower the pertxittcd dens i ty. The folloNjny tabie shows how the sliding scale is used in Baltimore Ccuaty, Mary 1 and. Area of Lot of Record -x . at the Time of the Effective *- Waxirnurn Number of Date of this Ordinance . Lots Permitted - Less than 3 acres 1 At least 3 but not more than 10 2 More than 10 'but. not more than 23 3 /+ore than 20 but not more than 100 4 .. * Hore than 100 5 lots plus one additional lot Pot each 25 acres in excess of 100 acres of the total tract area r.- 4 ,** -Thus, in Baltimore Cot ', the sliding scale would all densities ranging from one dwelling unit per acre to one dwelling unit per twenty-five acres, depending on the size of the original lot. The theory behind "sliding scale" zoning for agricultural preservation is that smalier lots are less likely to be important segments of the agricultural base of the area. This technique is designed to keep larger tracts in agriculturzl use while snm1 ler parcels would be permitted to be divided for residential estates. The proponents of thc-llsliding scale" technique would also argue that large landholdings arc more likely to be profitably engaged in agriculture; there- fore, owncrs of such land are less 1 ikely to need to subdivide ttlei r land to profit by their investnients. "Sliding scale" zoning has a number of important advantages. First, it would appear to be an effective way of minimizing the subdivision of large landholdings and thereby preserving land for agricultural use. Seccnd, it provides for a great deal of flexibility. Different "sliding scales" could be used in different areas to suit local conditions. As in quarter/quarter zoning, the landowner could be relied upor: to decide on the size and location of the-permitted rtew lots. Third, the technique wt~ld theoretically work in areas where quarter/quarter zonirlg r.rouId not bc appropriate. Its use is not restricted to areas surveyed into sections whete all lots are of any particular size. Fourth, it is not difficult to administer. The density perrni tted on any lot is determined by the size of that lot at the tine specified in the ordinance impleslenting the sliding scalc technique. .. However, the "sliding scale" techr,ique also has some important drawbacks. It is not clear whether such an approach would be legal here in California. On the face of it, it seems to violate conmanly held notions of equity. hc might argue that ' owners of larger tracts were. being arbitrarily discriminated against. Even if such si legal chalienge were not effective, it mic$t be difficult to retain in the long run the wcesssry poliTicZ! r-::;rport for such a Frogran. Another drawback is that new owners of land that has al ready been subcl ivi ded in sccordsnce wi th the "sliding scale'' may not. be properly infcrncd about the development potentisl of their prcperty prior to their purchase of it. It my be diif icui t For them to accept that their property cannot be resubdivided when some adjacent snla",er property can be divided. i- '\ c .(. . . ,- CHAPTER 3 FURCHASE AND LEASE-BACK The unincorporated area of SGn Diego County has approximately 1!3,000 acres of land in agricultural production. The bulk of this land lies in four areas: Fallbrook (14,003-13%), North County Metro and San Dieguito;': (25,593-23%), Valley Center (24,104-21%), and Otay (13,695-12z). Clearly, many of the lands in these areas wi 11 be subject to future urban development pressure and thus any attempt to preserve this agricult.ura1 land via purchase and leaseback, etc. would be quite . costly. This paper will examine the financing nlethods and costs of preserving agricultural lands. Based upori post Proucsition 13 r2venue constraints and the methods available, the foilcwing is a summary of the feasibility of preserving agricultural land via its acqtiisition. . Essentially, given the revenue constraints at the Federal! State, and local level and the market price of agricultural land in San Diego County, it is highly impractical to attempt to preserve agricultural land in this County primarily via acquisition. . An estimate was made of the cost of purchasing ag1:icul- tural landi The price tag of such a purchase could well exceed 6@0jmillion dollars at today's market prices. Obviously,;such an ambitiou; effort-is beyond the scope of governmint. The point, however, is that any attempt to purchase agricultural land in Sar. Diego County would involve s +assive sum of money. As a corollary, this acquisition would entail foregoiq other services and -. revenue (property taxes) by local governments. . The nurnber;snd flexibility of financial mechanisms " I \ available to the County of San Diego to purchase agri- culturai land is very 1 inlited. There are no funds currently existing at the Federal and Statelevel available for direct purchase. At the local level, it appears that the purchase of agricultural land by a nonprofit corporation, lcasing this land to the County, and in turn having the County sublease to the grower-tenant is the most practical method st: this point ir~ time. It Is likely that under such a scheme that the County of San Diego would have to subsidize lease payments; the amoullt depending on which agricultural land war, purchased. That is, the market value of existing-agricultural land . and associated debt service costs are likely to be less than market rates. Any deficiency between revenues and costs are likely to be funded in the capital improvement * Jncludes some. incorpcratzd areas. 1. . .- budget . . The issuance of general obligation and revenue borlds by The County of Ssn Diego appears infeasible. General obligation bonds have been virtually eliminated as a result of Proposition 13. According to a financial consul tan t to the County::, issuance of revenue bonds directly by County of San Diego is questionable due to potential lease revenue being insufficient to cover debt services.. Likewise a joint powers agreement is not viable, as these intrajurisdictional contracts are designed for building or' improvement oriented activities. A development fee for an "open space agricultural" fund is probably not legal. This is due to the fact that fees must be directly tied to benefits to the develcpment. Finally, a special asszssment district approach (i.e., City of San Diego's open space requisition bonds) would be difficu!t in the era of post Proposition 13 revenue constraints and according to this municipal financial consultant subject to legal challenge;. . In summary, the large quantity of agricultural screage coupled with the high market price of this land ana the revenue constraints in the post Propositicn 13 era make it virtuaily impossible to preserve agricultural land via its acquisition. At best,'it appears that the use of a private nonprofit corForation approach may be feasible 3s a mi nor supple~i~ent to other more ambitious methods (density zoning, etc.). * Terry Comerford, Blythe, Eastman, and Di 11 ion. I- . >. - METHODOLOGY Explained below is the method for calculating the market value of agricultural land in San Diego Councy. Admittedly, it is somewhat crude. However, to derive a "true" value of agric.ultura1 land in San Diego County would involve a farm by farm appraisal; a quite costly effort. The attempt in this study is to provide a rough value of agricultural land at today's market prices. This value, in many cases, is likely to be above what the land is worth for purely - agricultural production. In other words, much' of the agricultural land in San Diego County is valued for nonagricultural uses. This price of agricultural land by planning subregion was ccrmputed via two steps. Step one was to "inflate'' the most recent information on !and inflation by the most current acreage market value data from the Assessor's property information system. The only information which could be discovered on the inflation rate of land was the average increase in the price of existing single fanlily homes in 1978 by those of 1977. This assumes, naturally, that land value is the sole cause for home price increases from 1977 to 1978. While not .entirely true, it is a good "ballpark" estimate. Between 1978 and ,1977 the average price of an existing single family home in San Diego County increased by 31%;:. This 31% inflGtion rate was applied to the Assessor's estimate of average market value pzr- acre for all land in a planning subregion in 1977. Cleariy, this"imp1ies that iand would be purchased at highest and best use valse.. In summary, acreage in production figures were multiplied by 1977 Assessor's market value and in turn inflated at 31%. The tai-le below summarizc:~ this calculation: TABLE I MARKET VALUE AGRl CULTIJRAL LAND PLANN I NG AREA ACREAGE IN PRODUCT I ON - Pendleton-De Luz 22 80 Fa1 lbrook 14803 Bonsal 1 7829 North County Metro 2@392 San D iegu i to 520 1 Pala Fauma 92 05 Valley Center 241 04 * May 1978, Chamber of Commerce Economic Bulletin. CURRENT MARKET VALUE (In Mi 11 ions] - $ 4.1 166.4 47.8 124.5 95.6 - 14.5 32.2 .. -. 4 .. .- P.. TABLE I (Cont'd) MARKET VALUE AGRICULTURAL LAND PLANN 1 NG AREA ACREAGE ! N PRODUCT I ON - Otay Poway Ramon a Ra i nbow Lakes i de TOTAL : 13695 2592 8720 1715 1154 11 1690 CURRENT MARKET VALUE (In Mi IFonsj $ 20.4 26.1 27.3 6.0 7.7 $632.6 Obviously, not all of the land in these areas would be even considered for preservation due to small lot sizes, etc. The point, hwever, is that such an effort would be quite costly. As can be seen, the total estimated market value of this agricultural land is in the neighborhood of 633 million dollars. This amounts tu an average market value per acre of $5,664. As mentioned earlicr, possibly revenue bonds couirj he issued by a private nonprofit corporation to purchase part of this agrIcul tura! land. In today's market such revenue bonds are issued typical?y for tweoty five years at 78 interest. Related to this approach, the table below "- *1 ~llustrates +he impact on County government of the following scenarios: . The purchase of 10 million dollars worth of agricultural land in 1979 at an overall average purchase price of $5,664 per r'cre (the colilputed average). This amounts to the purchase of 1766 acres of agricultural acres in production; or 1.6 percent of the total acres in the County. . It is assumed that the bonds are issued at 7% for twenty five yezrs. This amounts to an annual debt service of $558,100. . Lease rates begin at an annual $150 per acre and are escalated at 10% per year. . The financing "scheme" is one in which a nonprof i i . corporation leases to the County of San Diego and in turn the County sab!eases to the yrowcr-tenant. Any difference between debt service cost and lease revenue is financed via the capital iRprovemest budget. The term deficit refers .to this capital fund figure. .* c .- h7 1. ., TABLE I I TEN FISCAL IMPACTS OF FINANCING AGRICULTURAL LAND VIA ACQUlSlTlGN IO YEARS (IN ACTUAL NOMINAL DOLLARS) - YEAR DEBT SERVICE COST LEASE REVENUE DEFICIT 1 $ 858,100 $ 264,900 $ 593,200 2 858 , 100 251,390 566,710 3 858 , 100 321,412 536,688 4 858 , 100 353,200 504,900 858 , 100 858 , 100 858,100 '8 858,100 515,672 342 , 423 9 858 , 100 568., 652 283,448 - *IO 858 , 100 625,164 - 232,935 .. _L TOTAL $8 , 58 1 ,000 $4,226,038 $4,354,962 The implication of the data and analysis in this sectjon leads to the following conclusions: 1. Even under what appears to be the most feasible financial alternative, the private nonproFit corporation approach, the County of San Diego could end up "subsidizing" agricultural production. 2. Bearing in mind that the table in this section amounts to less than a modest 2% purchase of agricultural lands in production, an even more ambitious approach would naturally incur substantial costs to County government and would likely cause the elimination of potential capital improvement projects. In addition, the County would be eliminating sources of property tax revenue. 3. There is, however, two apparent advantages to such an approach. . First of all, if the agricultural land is thought of as open space, then the County's nonprofit corporation could gain functional open space and unl i ke most open space receive revenue f rorn i t. Secondly, a substantial profit could pass to the County if future proceeds from the sale of the agricultural land reverted to the County. END OF REPORT ANOTHER DOCUMENT FOLLOWS Exchange AgricrrltrvalLandsRqject Vd. 1. No. 1 Octobor 1979 Natid Auocirtioa of Counties Reaeueh Foundation. 1731 New York An. N.W. Waahingtoo. D.C. 20008 Building a Community of Interests AglandsErcnpnqe. the Agricultural Lands with the publication of this first edition of Pi~]ect ofthe National Association of Counties Research Foundation launches an ambitious effort to cultivate a broader public awareness of. and to rally support for. the need to conserve farmland in the Unites States. for the disappearance of farmland prompted the State of Maryland to adopt the first legislation aimed at consenring its agricultural land base. Since 1956. many government ofllcials. institutions and citizens have wrestled with the question of how to slow down the conversion of farmland to non- agricultural uscs. now taking place at the rate of about 3 million acres a year. But it will take the intemted and active tnvolvement of many more people. lf we arc to succeed in solving this very difficult problem. AU of us have a stake in the preservation of farmland-whether it stems from our concern for world hunger. our desire to maintain environmental quality. our responsibility for the emcient management of government or our need to make a living in the agricultural marketplase. Each of us brings to the farmland conservation issue a different perspective. but we are united by a common concern for an irreplaceable natural resource that sus~na all of our interests. We are a growing "community of tnterests" and must seek to define a consensus on how to address the issue of farmland conservation. It has been over two decades since concern Study of Farmland Conversion Begins The U.S. Department of Agrtculture and the Council on Environmental Quailty have agreed to cooperate in a major study of farmland conversion. The purposes of this National Agricultural Lands Study are to determine the nature. rate. extent and causes of the loss of American farmland to non-agricultural uses: to evaluate the economic. environmental and social consequences of this 1- and to recommend administrative and legislative actions. if found necessary. to reduce the loss suffered by the nation as a result. The shady. headed by Robert J. Gray. former Administrative Assistant to Rep. James Jeffords (Vt.). is to be completed and submitted to the President by January 1981. Further information about the National Agricultural Lands Study may be obtained by ' writing Mr. Gray. Councfl on Environmental wity. Room 3020. ~ew Executrve om= Building. Washington. D.C. 20006. how to expand public understanding. and how to reformulate public policies so as to protect our mutual interest in the agricultural land base. The exchange of Ideas will be vital to this undertaking. Through this newsletter. the Agricultural Lands Project hopes to provlde a medium for the exchange of your ideas about farmland conservation. We intend to include regular features on state and local approaches to farmland conservation. the impacts of government programs and policies on agricultural lands and enterprises. reviews of significant technical and popular publications, editorials and announcements of coming events. We want to accommodate differing vtewpoints and to enable you to let others know what you or your organization are doing to help conserve farmland. Above all. we want to provide creative thought and to stimulate the kind of communication-among an ever- expanding community of interested ofilcials and citizens-that wUl produce cooperative action to conserve Amedcan farmland. Help us out. won't you? Thanks. and best wishes. . Edward Thompma Jr. Editor Advisors Set Direction for NACoFAgriccultural Project The Advisory Committe of the NACoRF Agricultural Lands Project held Its initial meeting on September 5 and 6. in Suffolk County. Long Island. New York. site ofthe first county farmland preservation program in the nation. The members of the committee. formed to give direction to the project staff. participated in three lively discussion sessions and toured local farmlands that have been prmrved largely through the effortsof County Executive John V.N. Klein. meeting by outllntng the prospects for national farmland preservation legislation that he introduced earlier this year. and which is now pendlng before the House and Senate Agriculture Committees. The legislation would provide funds to counties to demonstrate innovative techniques to preserve fannland and would guarantee that federal agency programs are conducted in a manner consistent with local farmland conservation policies. In explaining the need to conserve our farmland, Rep. Jeffords noted that. in order to help feed itself and an expanding global population. the United States "will have to produce as much food in the next twenty years. as has been grown throughout the world since the beglnning of time." Addressing the central question. "Where are we today on farmland conservation?." the committee generally agreed that. while the loss of thre million acm of farmland each year to non-agricultural wes is a significant national problem. the effects of this trend are today being felt mast strongly at the local community level. As the farms disappear. local agrtcuitural busincsses move away or U.S. Rep. James JefTo& (VtJ kepoted the close up. the ccst of providing public semices to wtdely scattered settlement increases. environmental problems become more widespread. open space and the quality of life diminish. and communities are often forced to rely on distant markets for foods once supplied by local farmers. Hfflenbrand opened the discussion of the Agricultural Lands Project by stressing its goal of building a national "community of interests" or coalition in support of farmland conservation. The pro]ect staffwlsha to serve. and to involve in its action agenda. people and institutions that represent all of the various affinity groups that bring to the issue of farmland conservation their own perspectives. The committee members emphasized the need to Lnvolve farmers. in particular. because they often have the mat to Sea COMMITTEE. page 2 NACo Executive Director &mard Suffolk Caunty: Newsbriefs A Farmland Pioneer From its western boundary. an imaginary line running through the suburbs forty-five minutes from midtown Manhattan. Suffolk County stretches over eighty miles to the easternmost tip of Long Island and is surrounded on three sides by salt water. Its Committee Holds Initial Meeting Conttnued from page X lose as development encroaches into agricultural areas and suburban homeowners start complaining that routine farming operations have become a “nuisance.“ As an introduction to a discuseion of various ways that local government can by the Suffolk County staff on the history and preserve farmland. the committee was briefed accomplishments of that county’s pioneering conservation program. The Suffolk program. begun in 1972. relies on the selective purchase of development rights to farmland. after assessments are made and askingprice bids are voluntarily submitted by landowners. The key to the success of the Suffolk program. said County Executive Klein. was the early participation and interest of the local ag&dtural community and. partlcularly. of John Talmage. whose family has farmed in the county for a century. County officials who took pa-t in the Advisory Committee sessions inciuded: John V.N. Klein. County Executive. Suffolk County, New York. and NACo Director: John Spellman. County Executive. King County. Washington. and NACo Second Vice- Presidenr: Ruth Keeton. County Council Chairperson. Howard County. Maryland. NACo Director and Vice Chairman. NACo Land Use and Growth Management Steering Committee: Lester A. Anderson. Commissioner. Blue Earth County. Minnesota. and NACo Director: and Hugh N. Ford. Planning Dlrector. JefTerson Parish. Louisiana. and President. Natlonal Association of County Planning Directors (NACPD1. who partlcipated were: Thomas Barlow. Natural Resources Defense Council. Washington, D.C.; Damn Briggs. Office of Environmental Quality. U.S. Department of Agriculture (representing Norman A. Berg. Administrator. U.S. Soil Cowervation Service): Robert J. Gray. Executive Dtrector. National Agricultural Lands Study (Council on Environmental Quality and US. Department of Agriculture): Davtd Lambert. The National Grange. Washington. D.C.; William King. Massachusetts Department of Food and Agriculture (representing Lieutenant Governor Thomas P. O’Neill 111): Dr. Phillip Raup. Department of Agricultural and Applied Economics. University of Minnesota: Don Reeves. Friends Committee on National Legislation. Washington. D.C.. and Chainnan. Agricultural Policy Committee. Inter-religious Task Force on U.S. Food Policy: and John Talmage. farmer and agricultural businessman. Suffolk County. New York. Other members of the Advisory Committee gently rolling hills and sandy loam are the offspring fo the Ice Age. when an advancing glacier scraped the soil from primeval New shelf. England and deposited it on the continental European settlement of the county was begun over three centurw ago by pioneer familia attracted to the rich agricultural lands in what is now the county scat of Riverhead near the eastern fork of Long Island. Suffolk remained predominantly rural for a long time thereafter. its economy sustained by agriculture. including the famous Long Island duckling Industry. Fish from the surrounding waters and summer midents of its south shore barrier beaches ais0 contributed theirshare to the well-being of the county. But following World War II things began to change. Rising affluence and the population explcaion conspired to push the sprawling suburbs of New York Clty eastward into the countryside. swallowing Nassau County and encroaching into neighboring Suffolk. By had trlpled to 600 thousand. and during the 1960. the pre-war population of the county following fifteen years Suffolk experienced a growth rate five time the national average. reaching 1.3 million permanent residents by 1975. and industry into the county produced vast The expansion of suburban development economic benefits and greatly enlarged the tax base. But it also brought problems. not the least of which-it dawned on county officials foundation ofSuffo1k.s native Industry. its and local farmers-was the erosion of the rich agricultural land. The 120 thousand acres of county farmland that existed in 195 3 had by 1972 been reduced to half that amount. chipped away piece by piece while continued to rank first in New York State in nobocly was paying attention. Still. Suffolk gross agricultural des. with 570 million generated annuaily. It was not too late to tp to preserve agriculture in the county. County Executive John V.N. Klein recognized the mixed blessings of Suffolks phenomenal growth and understood that preservation of the county’s remaining agricultural land would benefit not only the farm population. but also hissuburban constituents who desired open space. In the spring of 1972, he appointed an Agricultural Advisory Committee whose membership was broadly representative of the farm community in the county. The formation of this committee proved to be a turning point in the history of Suffolk farmland. The committee was charged with the responsibility of identifying the problems that most seriously threatened the agricultural industry in the county, and wtth the task of proposing appropriate solutions. It addressed a variety of issues relevant to the retention of farmland and the viability of agriculture as an enterprise. including County Executive Klein‘s proposal to preserve farmland through the purchase of development rights. Two years after it had first convened. after hours of open debate and deliberation. the committee reported to the Suffolk County Leglslature the outline of a carefully conceived plan of farmland conservation. based on the Klein proposal. Continued on page 3 Fumlmd. Protection Act Parallel legislative measures to help conserve American farmland are making Agfands Exchange gas to press. H.R. 235 1 is their way through Congress as this issue of sponsored by Reps. James Jeffords (Vt.) and Richard Nolan (Minn.). S. 795 is sponsored by Sens. Warren Magnuson (Wash.). Pavick Leahy (Vt.) and John Heinz (Pa.). Both bills address the farmland question in three ways: they provide that federal agency programs and actions must be carried out in a manner consistent with local farmland conservation policies: they direct that a study of farmland loss be undertaken: and they authorize “seed money” for state and local governments to demonstrate innovattve farmland conservation approaches. may be obtained from the congressional dnces of the principal sponsors or from Robert C. Weaver. Associate Director. National Association of Counties. 1735 New York Avenue N. W.. Washington. D.C. 20006. Further information about this legislation 2021785-9577, AM fot IdOrmrtiOnl The Agricultural Lands Project is conducttng a continuing survey of state. county and other local programs aimed at the preservation of farmland. The purpose of the survey is twofold: ( 1) to compile a collectlon of literature describing these programs that will be made available to those who request it. and 12) to help in the analysis of the programs. leir accomplishments and shortcomings. - td their adaptability to the geographic. xonomic and political conditions in other jurtsdictions. We ask those of you who are familiarwith state. county or other local farmland conservation programs to send information describing them (statutes. ordinances. plans and other supporting documentation) to us. c/o Agricultural Lands Project. NACoRF. 1735 New York Avenue. N.W.. Washington. D.C. 20006. Coming Events October 14-17 - B8itfmora. Myland - American Planning Association (MA) Annual Sunday. October 14 will deal wlth Conference. Two sessions on federal programs -&at influence farmland w and the Maryland state farmland conservation efiort. Information and registration: John Chcago. IIlinois 60637.312/947-2560. Waxman. MA. 1313 East 60th Street. November 12-14 - Pullm8n. Washington - Conference on ”Farmland Preservation: The State of the Art.” sponsored by the Washington State University Cooperative Extension and the WSU Department of Horticulture and Landscape Architecture. Information and registration: Frederick Steiner. Conference Chairman. WSU Department of Horticulture and Landscape Architecture. Johnson Hall. WSU. Pullman Washington 99164.509i335-2192. 2 Development Rights Key in County Continued from page 2 program is conceptually simple, but its implementation has required political sophistication and conscientious administration. Its basic approach is to use county funds. derived from the sale of general of carefully selected parcels of farmland the revenue bonds. to purchase from the owners right to use the land for purposes other than agriculture. These "development rights" become the property of the county. msferable only by referendum. A Select Committee on the Acquisition of Farmland (many of whose members were on the original Agricultural Advisory Committee) is responsible for the choice of farmland tracts. based on a set of flexible criteria: soil suitability. present land usage. development pressure. the price of the land. and the contiguity of parcels. Relatively large tracts of farmland. situated close to each other so as to form agricultural "cores." have been selected in each of the towns within the county. The price of the development rights is determined on the basis of bids submitted by landowners. and accepted or rejected by the county in an open. formal process. Generally speaking. these bids reflect the difference between the value of the land for development and its value for agricultural use. But the county makes its own appraisai and negotiates with successful bidders on the final price. Nonetheless. the amount received by the landowner represents by far the greater proportion of his total equity in the land. and they do so voluntarily. without fear of condemnation-retain title to the land. the right to possession. the nght to sell their remaining interest and. of course. the right to continue using the land for agricultural purposes. They are also compensated for their relinquished rights and their property tax assessment is reduced. This combination The Su&Tolk County farmland preservation Owners who sell their development rights- provides the owner with additional working capital-used by some farmers to acquire more land. the development rights to which may in turn be sold -and lowers his operating expenses. making his enterprise more financially secure. Moreover. the dedication of his land to agricultural purposes qualifies the protection from most "nuisance" complaints farmer under New York State law for droughty conditions cause dust to be raised from nearby subdivisions. for example. when during cultivation. To date. Suffolk County has purchased the During May and June 1979. the National Association of Conservation Districts (NACDI conducted a swey of the opinions of 2.924 country. When asked. "ThinMng back over local conservation district officials around the years ahead. how would you rate the the past five years. and looking about five agrtcultural land conversion problem in your district?." lopercent ofthe 1.901 respondents categorized the problem as "very serious." 31 percent said "serious." 47 percent said "slight." and 12 percent said "no problem." problem ad serious or very serious. 34 percent called the actions of federal agencies a significant or major cause of farmland conversion. When asked which federal agenda were involved. most respondents mentioned the Farmers Home Of the disVict officials who listed their Administration. Federal Highway Administration and the Environmental Protection Agency. Hfghways were listed as the leading cause of agricultural land conversion. with rural housing and rural sewer and water projects also mentioned frequently. conclusions. For more information. write: Neil Sampson. Executive Director. NACD. 1025 Vermont Avenue N.W.. Washington. D.C. 20005. NACD will soon publish its survey data and "While the farmer holds title to the land. actually, it belongs to all the people because civilization itself rests upon the soil." Thomrs Jefferson development rights to over 3.200 acres at a total cost of roughly S 10 million. 5 percent of which went for appraisals and administration over a five-year period. That's about S3.000 per acre for some of the richest farmland on Long Island. in the shadow of the megalopolis. John Klein and other county officials think they got a bargain. So. apparently. do the local farmers. who have offered to sell the rights to another 13.000 acres. The Suffolk County Legislature has authorized an additional S 1 1 milllon bond iswe to expand the program. first county effort of its lund-cannot be dollars. It seems to have had an encouraging measured simply in terms of acres and effect on the county's agricultural community. which no longer feels quite as insecure about disappearing suppliers and neighbors who do not appreciate the practical John Talmage. whose farm has been owned realities and risks of farming. To some. like and worked by his family for a century. it has demonstrated that county government cams about its native industry and is willing to help ensure its survival. The approach to farmland conservat!on taken by Suffolk County was tailored to its particular geographic. economic and political context. Other counties will want to examine their own situations to determine which techniques will work best for them. There are. however. two fundamental lessons to be drawn from the Suffolk expericnce that apply to all counties. First is the desirability of a strong commitment to a farmland conservation program by the county executive. as in the case of John Klein. whose personal dedication and own mind were But the SUCCCYI of the Suffolk program-the largely responsible for thesuccess of the Suffolk program. Second. but hardly less important. is the indfspensabillty of involvtng farmers. and the agrtcultural community as a whole. at the earliest possible stage in the process by which such programs are conceived. adopted and implemented. Farmers have more to gain. or to lose. than any other constituency group from an attempt to preserve farmland and bolster agricultural industry. The county officials and farmers of Suffolk County were pioneers. whose mutual respect and cooperation have proved that it is never too late-or too eariy-to preserve the agricultural hefitage and economy of a community. For more information about the Suffok program. contact John V.N. Klein. County Executive: Laure Nolan. Intergovernmental Representative. or Diane Anderson. Administrative Aide at the following addrese: suffouc County Executive omces Veterans Memorlal Highway Hauppauge. New York 11787 5 16/979-2956 Publications Update - CEALLENGE and the agricultural 'establishment.' brcn "Never has the consemation community. caught so thoroughly out of position as it has on the agricultural land issue. After decades of agricultural surpluses which exist to this very day. it is perhaps understandable that policy leaders would for a time either misconstrue or ignore both the statistics and on-the-ground evidence that pertain to the loss of agricultural land to urban development. But sooner or later. conservationists and agriculturists will have to face up to the fact that they have an issue in common." - Chuler E. Little American Land Forom Report. Sprlng 1979. from which the foregoing was excerpted. may be obtained by Copies of the Arnertcan Land Fom writing the ALF at 1025 Vermont Avenue N.W.. Room 1105. Washington. D.C. 20005. The cost is S6 per copy. S3 each for orders of 10 or more (64 pages). Preserving t&e Economic Ban "Fanning is often a critical element in the local economy. Since farming is almost always an exporter of goods and an importer of income. the returns to the community are substantial. Yet the effects of the agricultural land base extend throughout the community Farming supports a varlety of other businesses. such as grocery. drug and migrant workers. hired hands. food hardware stores and other retail enterprises. processing plants and the like. But it is a symbiotic relationship -the farms need the support businesses and the support busincsaes need the farms. If the farms disappear. the support businesses will also disappear. Thus. by preserving the farms. and character of their local agricultural communitiesare also protecting the quality economic base." - Willl.m Toner. Saving Fannr cmd Farmland. A Community Guidk American Society of PI- Offici& (nor the Americur Phmhg boociation). Report No. 333 (1978). Brochure Anilrble The NACoRF Agricultural Lands Project has published a brochure that outlines the objectives and services of the project. and contains a discussion of the dimensions of the from the Agricultural Lands Project. farmland loss problem. Copies are available NACoRF. 1735 New York Avenue N.W.. Washington. D.C. 20006. National Aseociation of Counties Research Foundation 1735 New York Avenue. N.W. Washington. D.C. 20006 NONPROFIT US. POSTAGE PAID Washington. D.C. 20006 Permit No. 41968 END OF PREVIOUS DOCUMENT. ANOTHER DOCUMENT FOLLOWS " " - ~~~~~~ ~~ ~~~~~~~ Exchange Agricultural Lands Project December 1979 Vol. 1 No. 2 National Aeaociation of Counties Research Foundation, 1735 New York Ave. N.W. Washington, D.C. 20006 House Panel By a vote of 26- 13. the House Agriculture Committee on November 8 approved the Agricultural Land Protection Act. H.R. 255 1, with the recommendation that it be enacted by Congress. Sponsored by Rep. James M. Jeffords (R-Vt.), the bill provides $60 million over a four-year period to be distributed to states and local governments for the purpose of testing new approaches to farmland preservation. It further authorizes a comprehensive study of state and local farmland preservation programs. including those developed under the demonstration grants provision, so that additional states and local governments will benefit from the test results. The bill received strong bipartisan support from Rep. Richard Nolan-ID-Minn.) and was shepherded through the committee by Chairman Thomas S. Foley (D-Wash.). A move by Rep. Charles E. Grassley (R-Iowa) to strike the grant provision from H.R. 2551 failed by a wide margin, but the committee did remove from the original bill a section that would have required federal agencies to notify state and local governments of pending federal actions that could result in farmland conversion. In a press conference following the King County Votes Farmland Bonds In the November general election. the voters of King County (Seattle). Washington. overwhelmingly approved, by a 63 percent margin, a referendum authorizing a $50 million bond issue to be used for farmland preservation. Sponsored by King County Executive John Spellman, the measure. known as Proposition 3 on the ballot. enables the county to purchase development rights to selected prime agricultural land that otherwise would be converted to nonagricultural uses. Development rights. as the term implies, consists of the right to use property for purposes other than agriculture. The King County farmland preservation program is patterned after that pioneered by Suffolk County, New York. (See Aglands Exchange. October 1979.) During the past several decades, King County experienced the loss of about half its farmland to development. Spellman and other civic and government leaders became concerned about the potential loss of farm income and jobs. as well as the disappearance of open space. The farmland bond issue was first put on the ballot in November 1978, when it failed by only one-fifth of 1 percent to see LAND, page 3 Votes Farmland Measure committee action, Rep. Jeffords said, "The legislation is modest by most traditional measures: it calls for the expenditure of a very small amount of federal money, and it doesn't give the federal government any new controls over our our lives. By addressing the (farmland preservation) issue now. we can afford to proceed modestly. In the long run. this bill represents one of the most significant issues facing the 96th Congress." The Committee Report on H.R. 2551 emphasized that the bill is specifically designed to safeguard the traditional rights and responsibilities of states and local governments with respect ot making land use decisions, containing language to prevent federal restrictions on land and infringement of state and local powers. The philosophy of the bill is to expand the number of different techniques that state and local governments may use to preserve farmland, so that the chances are improved that at least one new approach will be applicable to any given locality. Floor action on H.R. 2551 is expected within the coming months. A companion bill, S. 795, sponsored by Sen. Warren G. Magnuson (D-Wash.), is pending before the Senate Agriculture Committee. (See voting list on page 3.) Wisconsin Curbs Agland Loss Two years after its inception, the statewide farmland preservation program in Wisconsin is showing impressive signs of success in curtailing the disappearance of agricultural land. Inspired by the preservation efforts of Columbia and Walworth counties, the Wisconsin program combines exclusive agricultural zoning established and administered at the county level, with state income tax credits for farmers who meet eligibility requirements. This approach to halting farmland loss is an outstanding example of the effectiveness of a creative partnership between state and county governments. Wisconsin has experienced over three decades of rapid economic and population growth. Many of the houses, businesses and industries built to accommodate this growth have been located willy-nilly in the open countryside, creating "urban sprawl" and causing problems for the agricultural community. One of the leading dairy states in the nation. Professor Richard Barrows of the Department of Agricultural Economics at the University of Wisconsin described these problems: "The spread of development into rural areas causes tax increases and land use conflicts. ... Farm property taxes increase because assessments increase rapidly. reflecting the higher market value of the land; tax levies increase because of the need to provide more (and different) public services to the new residences and businesses. There may be problems of trespass and crop damage from nonfarm residents. Idle lands held by speculators may be a source of spreading noxious weeds. Farmers may be subjected to social and sometimes legal pressures to change certain farm operations such as manure spreading, night plowing or feedlot location. The size of farm operations may be restricted by the inability to buy or rent land in the developing area. Finally, as more and more farmers move out of the area, businesses such as creameries and feed mills See COUNTYISTATE, page 3 A The Use of ‘God’s Gift to People’ A Quaker Farmer’s Response to Pope John Paul I1 by Don Reeves * During his recent visit to the United States. Pope John Paul I1 chose his appearance in Iowa to address issues of land use. stressing both that which God has given and that which man must do. “The-land is God’s gift ... given by a loving Creator as a means of sustaining the life which he had created. But the land is not only God’s gift; it is also man’s responsibility. Man, himself created from the dust of the earth, was made its master. In order to bring forth fruit, the land would depend upon the genius and skillfulness. the sweat and the toil of the people to whom God would entrust it. Thus, the food which would sustain life on earth is willed by God to be both that “which earth has given and human hands have made.” John Paul I1 suggested three appropriate responses from farmers and other rural people. In the first place: Gratitude. Recall the words of Jesus-words of gratitude to His heavenly father, “Father. Lord of heaven and earth, to you I offer praise.”Let this be your attitude as well. All of us, of whatever faith or none, who would make judgments about the use of land ought to be humbled regularly. We may receive life from the earth, we may nurture life or destroy it, but we are unable to create it. Secondly, the land must be conserved with care since it is intended to be fruitful for generation upon generation. ... You are stewards of some of the most important resources God has given to the world. Therefore, conserve the land well, SO that your children’s children and generations after them will inherit an even richer land than was entrusted to you. The principle of stewardship as care for the quality of farmland is wideljrunderstood and accepted. Unfortunately, our practice of soil and water conservation often falls quite short of our understanding. Further, our choices in the use of land are an aspect of stewardship. As careful stewards, we will choose to preserve our agricultural land, being more cautious about diverting farmland to other uses, and exercising greater care to prevent permanent despoiling of land. In both these regards, stewardship as making land productive is often confused with making the use of land profitable. History, as well as divinity, will probably Agriculture Developing Policies tomeserve me Farmland by Norman A. Berg Administrator, Soil Conservation Service The United States is a big country of well over two billion acres, but only 15 percent of this land can scientifically be described as prime farmland. “Prime farmland” is defined by the U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDAI as land that has the best combination of physical and chemical characteristics for producing food, feed, fiber, forage and oil seed crops with the least expenditure of fuel, fertilizer, pesticides and other production costs. It is also the land least subject to erosion and, therfore, capable of sustaining production for future generations. Use of Prime Farmland, 1977 (millions) Use Acres Percent Cropland 23 1 67 Forest 42 12 Pasture 39 11 Range 23 7 Other * 11 3 *Does not include urban and other built- up areas. Source: SCS Natural Reoource Inrentorleo (1977) 2 Prime farmland is a vital but limited natural resource. Most of it lies in a broad belt reaching from the Great Lakes to the Gulf of Mexico. The Corn Belt region has 20 percent of the total, followed by the Northern and Southern Plains with 19 and 18 percent respectively. Of the 115 million acres of prime farmland not now in cropland (Table], USDA estimated that only 54 million (45 percent) could be shifted into crop production. Between 1967 and 1977, over one-third of the 29 million rural acres converted to urban and water uses was prime farmland. (SCS. 1977). Consistent with the rights and responsibilities of private landowners, and the primary role of state and local governments in making and implementing land use policy, the USDA aduocates the retentfon of prime farmland whenever proposed conversions are: caused or encouraged by actions or programs of a federal agency, licensed or required approval by a federal agency. or are inconsistent with state and local government plans. The Secretary of Agriculture has asked each division within the USDA to change its policies and procedures whenever necessary to make them consistent with the above policy. Each division reported to the Secretary on its program on Dec. 7, 1979. USDA welcomes your suggestions as to how its programs and policies can be modified to accomplish the retention of prime farmland. judge harshly land use decisions made solely on the basis of short-term private gain, and those public policies which permit or encourage such practices. In the third place. I want to speak about generosity. ... Recall the time when Jesus saw the hungry crowd gathered on the hillside. What was His response? ... “Give them something to eat yourselves.” Did He not intend those same words for us today. for us who live at the closing of the 20th century. for us who have the means available to feed the hungry of the world.? Although 1979 grain production in the United States set a new record. both US. and world grain supplies are expected to decline in the coming year. In spite of our large exports and modest food donations abroad. some five hundred million people are chronically undernourished. Yet we continue to convert land to urban and industrial purposes, “using up” two to three times as much land per capita as most other nations. “development.” we should at least proceed very cautiously in permitting prime farmland to be taken. turned his remarks toward the human impact: rfwe really need that much land for At the end of his address, John Paul I1 Above all. bring your families (to the altar) and dedicate them anew to Christ, so that they may continue to be the working, living and loving community where nature is revered, where human burdens are shared and where the Lord is praised in gratitude. Sustainable, productive uses of land are probably inseparable from stable, viable communities. “Community sustainability” surely includes at least two elements: relatively widespread ownership of each community’s resources especially land, and widespread participation in making community decision. and a challenge to all of use: to help set policies which guide the most fruitful use of community resources, especially our farmland, in ways to meet human need, on sustainable basis. Pope John Paul’s comments offer both hope *Don and Barbara Reeves are the senior partners in a two-family livestock and grain farm at Central City, Nebraska. Don has spent most of the past three years in Washington. D.C., working on farm and food issues with the Friends Committee on National Legislation. He also serves as chair of the Agriculture Policy Work Group of the Inter- religious Task Force on US. Food Policy. and is a member of the Agricultural Lands Project Advisory Committee. Statelcounty Partnership USuccess Continued from page 1 may be forced out of business. Gradually. the area changes from a rural farm environment and lifestyle to one dominated by the interests and lifestyle of exurban commuters.” Adopted in 1977, the Wisconsin Farmland Preservation Act is designed to protect farmers by giving the responsibility for such protection to local citizens and their elected officials. Its approach is to provide incentives for both farmers and county governments to take the matter of farmland preservation into their own hands, using the tools of planning and zoning. THE PRINCIPLE incentive for farmers is a state tax credit of up to $4.200 annually. As farm income increases, the amount of the tax credit for which he may qualify decreases. so that the credit serves as a kind of “insurance policy” against crop failure and other factors that might otherwise economically cripple farm families. Unlike the property tax breaks offered farmers by some states in an effort to preserve agricultural land, the Wisconsin state income tax credit does not diminish local tax revenues, making it attractive to counties. Until 1982-the end of Phase I, and the beginning of Phase I1 of the Wisconsin program-farmers may qualify for the state income tax credit in two ways. (They may also qualify for protection from special tax assessments levied to fund public services demanded by suburbanites, as an additional incentive.) First, farmers may qualify by signing a contract with the state, agreeing to forego development of their farmland for purposes other than agriculture: these contracts expire in 1982. Second, farmers are automatically eligible for the tax credit if their county adopts an agricultural zoning ordinance that meets the criteria under the Farmland Preservation Act. Once Phase II of the Wisconsin program begins in 1982. the eligibility of farmers for the state income tax credit will come to depend solely on whether their county takes action to preserve farmland. In rural counties, local government may adopt either a farmland preservation plan setting forth goals and policies, or a zoning ordinance which creates an exclusive agricultural zone wherein the best soils cannot be developed for nonagricultural purposes. Counties that are more urbanized, with a population of 75,000 or more, are required to adopt an exclusive agricultural zoning ordinance if their farm constituents are to qualify for continued tax credits. In either case. counties are given rather broad discretion in their choice of the type of ordinance which will best suit their needs and realize their farmland preservation objectives. Adoption of county farmland preservation plans and ordinances is not compelled by the Land Preservation Bonds Are Passed Continued from page 1 get the 60 percent approval required by law. A second effort to pass the referendum failed in this year’s primary election because, although it received 77 percent of the vote, the turnout was insufficient. Convinced that there was substantial support for farmland preservation, Spellman persuaded the King County Council to put the proposition on the ballot again in the general election, when it finally passed. “The approval of Proposition 3 is a landmark in agricultural land preservation in the United “This demonstration of public support.” he continued, “underscores the importance of preserving our remaining agricultural lands. It should have a profound impact on pending federal legislation that would assist other counties in achieving this goal.” Along with the agricultural land preservation measure, the King County electorate also approved a number of Proposition 13-type tax limitations. Political observers in the county noted that this result casts the success of the $50 million bond issue in an even more favorable light-proving States,” said Spellman. “It marks the first that the voters are willing to spend tax dollars time the electorate has voted to reach into for farmland preservation even in a time of its own pocketbook to preserve farmland.” economic caution. HOUSE AGRICULTURE COMMITTEE VOTE ON H.R. 259 1 AYES Democrats Foley (Wash.) Jones (N.C.) Jones (Tenn.) Mathis (Ga.) Brown (Calif.) Richmond (N.Y.) Nolan (Minn.) Weaver (Ore.) Baldus (Wis.) Harkin (Iowa) Bedell (Iowa) English (Okla.) Skelton (Mo.) Glickman (Kan.) Akaka (Hawaii) Whitley (N.C.) Coelho (Calif.) Daschle (S.D.) Republicans Wampler (Va.) Heckler (Mass.) Sebelius (Kan.) Jeffords (Vt.) Findley (111.) Coleman (Mo.) Madigan (Ill.) Thomas (Calif.) NAYS Democrats Bowen (Miss.) Hance (Texas) Fithian (Ind.) Anthony (Ark.) Panetta (Calif.) Stenholm (Texas) Huckaby (La.) Republicans Symms (Idaho) Hagedorn (Minn.) Kelly (Fla.) Marlenee (Mont.) Grassley (Iowa) Hopkins (Ky.) Not Voting de la Garza (D-Texas) Rose (D-N.C.) Johnson (R-Colo.) state statute. But unless county government acts by 1982, farmers may no longer qualify for the state income tax credit simply by signing a contract with the state and, indeed, must pay back all or part of the credits they have received. If county government does act, the amount of tax credit for which farmers may qualify doubles. This provision of the Wisonsin law gives county officials a powerful incentive to preserve local farmland-namely, the continued political support of their farm constituents. But Wisconsin does not thus encourage counties to preserve farmland and then simply ignore them. To assist local government in what is not only a political but also a highly technical task-involving soil mapping, selecting farmland for preservation and drafting ordinances-the state provides funds to counties for farmland preservation planning. To date, $800.000 has been distributed among Wisconsin’s counties for this purpose, with another $310,000 earmarked for assistance through the end of 1979. Financial assistance for county planning has also proved to be an incentive for counties to act. What about those signs of success? As of June 30.1979. approximately 9,400 farmers have become eligible for state income tax credits, either through contracts or because their counties have adopted agricultural zoning ordinances. More than 1.9 million acres of Wisconsin farmland have thereby been protected from sprawl development. with a total of $4.1 million in income tax breaks through the program. That breaks down to an average credit of $ 1,112 to approximately 3.057 participating farmers. Forty-seven of Wisconsin’s counties (65 percent) have either completed or are now preparing farmland preservation plans and ordinances. Asa result of this positive action by local government, 14.9 million acres of agricultural land will eventually be preserved. counties with farmland preservation stands in sharp contrast to that of many other states. Within a relatively short period of time, and with the expenditure of a modest sum of money. Wisconsin has given farmers a reason to stay on the land, encouraging them to participate in its farmland preservation program at a rate many times greater than in other states. Wisconsin officials are guardedly optimistic about the success of their program. PamelaG. Wiley, assistant director of the program, says. “What we’re counting on and what we’re seeing is an educational process.” The program. she says, is encouraging farmers to stick together to resist development pressure. J. Gray. executive director of the National Agricultural Lands Study, has called the Wisconsin partnership effort. combining state tax credits with local agricultural zoning. “perhaps the most effective” program in the nation. For additional information contact: James A. Johnson, Director, Farmland Preservation Unit, Wisconsin Department of Agriculture, Trade and Consumer Protection, 801 West Badger Road, P.O. Box 89 1 1, Madison. WiS.. The state has credited its qualified farmers The experience of Wisconsin and its Others are even more enthusiastic. Robert 6081266- 172 1. 3 Feds Need Farmland Criteria “Although the 1969 National Environmental Policy Act, an August 1976 statement by the Council on Environmental Quality. and (the USDA) current land use policy all call for federal agencies to consider prime farmland in planning and approving projects. GAO’s review of environmental impact statements and other environmental review documents for 25 projects of five federal agencies indicated that preserving prime and other farmland was given little consideration or low priority and was usually outweighed by other interests ... No uniform criteria exist to help federal agencies evaluate the impact of losing prime and other farmland and to balance this loss against other national interests.” ”Preserving America’s Farmland A Goal the Federal Government Should Support, US. General Accounting Office Report to Congress, September 20,1979 (Order No. CED-79-109). Available from the GAO, Washington, D.C. 20548 (72 pages) Effects of Rural Population Growth “The large-scale social and economic transition from an overwhelmingly agrarian nation 200 years ago to a megalopolitan superpower in the 20th century has constituted the thematic thrust of [US,] migration and population distribution. \But] a new prospect for population redistribution began to emerge In the early 19709 ... nonmetropolitan areas were. for perhaps the first time in our history, growing faster than metropolitan areas. “Many nonmetropolitan counties are where their big city cousins were at the end of World War 11: on the point of vast and irreversible change.” -Growth and Change in Rue1 America. G.B. Fuguitt. P.R. Voss and J.C. Doherty [ 1979). Available from the Urban Land Institute. 1200 18th Street N.W.. Washington. D.C. 20036. Price $13. (101 pages) Brochure Available The NACoRF Agricultural Lands Project has published a brochure that outlines the objectives and services of the project, and contains a discussion of the dimensions of the farmland loss problem. Copies are available from the Agricultural Lands Project, NACoRF, 1735 New York Avenue N.W.. Washington, D.C. 20006. National Assodation of Counties Research Foundation 1735 New York Avenue, N.W. Washington. D.C. 20006 NONPROFIT US. POSTAGE PAID Washington, D.C. 20006 Permit No. 41968 END OF PREVIOUS DOCUMENT. ANOTHER DOCUMENT FOLLOWS me 15 DEPARTMENT .OF AGRICULTURE . B. Agricultural Preaenration District E8tablishmnt- kdw. (1) Referrad vf Petition. (a) Upon rureipt of u petition to establish an agricul- td pmssrwtion district, the lnccrl gowrning body ahull mer the petition and accompanying materiala to both the cwricdturd pmw~tian adviamy bawd and to the county pfanning and mnh My. (6) Withie 80 doyt uf the nfird of Q petitinn, the wricultural mmwvation adviaoy bwrd shall inbrrn the county aoudmh body whether the hnd in the ptvymmd dhhicc mOd8 thr qudificotinru eatdlirhrd by the Fnun&- twn under Crc. kbw, and whether ihe a&- board rue ommcnl establishment of tht district. tc) Within 80 days of the mfirrul of a ptticion. the county planning and zoning body shall infbrm the ld gmwning body whether rrstablishmcnt of the district is comptibis with aM;ing and approuid county plans. pro- gram. and owdi count-y policy. and whether the planniw a4d mniw body recommends ustabiiohment of the &strict. In the gmar of rsuisw, the local ptcrnnrng andzoning body dhU conaider compatibility of datri& establishment with State and lml plaw and progrw. ' (9) If either the crgricultwal pmmrvation advisorj, bard or thr planning and zoning body rrcornmcndr tap- prwal, the county governing body shall hold a public haw ing on :ha pctitien. Adequate notice ofthe hearing #hall be given Lo df iandownrrs in the pmposed dish:, to landown- em at$axntto the prvpnsed district, QI fw 01 fhible, and (0 the Foundation. If neither body recommends approval of the petition, the bl perning body shall dercy the petition and not& the bndowner or iandtnunera and the Founda- tion, stating the mons for the cknaal. (S) Approud of Petition. (a) Within 120 days alter the recsipt of the ptition, tht county governing body shall rendw'tt derision on whether the petition rho8 be rrrcommended to thr Founda- tion fbr appmml. (SI If the county governing bwly &ides k, morn- mend approwt,of the petition, thu body shall 80 notify the Foundation and firwad to the Foundation the won and all accomponylng materials, including thr mommendo- tiona of the advisoy bvard and coun~y planning and wning body, and u compmitt pmperty boundary map of the pro- pod district. (c) If the gowrning body nmmmnda &nM ofthe petition, it shall w inform the Foundation ond the pr- t2ioner or ptitionern, rtating thc rrplon8 fi thir dmicrl. (4) The Foundation may appnm Q prtitiirn for the ea- aoblithrnent of an a@cuitud prcse&tion dirtrict only if: (al The land within the propcvcd district mcctd the prrcrllfyitq eritcria utaWhed under #6, &hw; . (&I Approwl of the petition han &en mmmended by the county gcrwrning body: and (c) Ertabliahmnt of the diotrict ir approved by a tnqjorit-y of the Foundation Board ,of Trustee8 &-large, the Suemtnry, and by the State Tnosunr. (6) The Founddon shall render it8 deciaion an a peti- tion to ntablhh agricultd pnestrwtion distriet within 60 daw of the rcnript of the petition, and shalt inform the county gorrorning body and tk petitioner or petitionern of itn decision. .- Lau -3- Id 1 he county goucming body or the Foundation may reuiew the me of fund within the diskict; Ib) The Foundation may approue alteration or abolishment of the district, if the Jbllowing occur: (i) The use of land within the district har ao crhcznged a to cawe land within the diatriet to fail to mett the qwlifiationn under W; (iil The Pounhtwn kaa asstaxed the potential im- pucta ofultemtiun on nmainiw lands in the &strict; (iiU The afterntion or abolition of the district haa beat noommed.d by the county governing body a&r re- view by the agricultural preservation advisory kcrd and corn@ planning and zoning body, and a pubik hsorrng hcu bn held; cmd (iv) The alteration or abolition ir appmwd a majority of the Foundation Board of Trustee# at-large,~by the Secretary, and by the State Trcaaurer. G. Continuation of Districts. Agricultud dirtrick #hall continue in efit indefinitely unless &rm&patcd in accord with my of the procrrdum pmvidrd in $E, abou6. .QI Eorenmb. A. Applicution to Sell Davelopmrni Righta h!asemcnt. An owner of agricultural land located within an agricdtuml 'preservation district established under thew regulations may offir. by written application, to sell to &he Foundation an tawmetat on the cntin mntigww acreage of tht agricd- turd land less 1 acre per exirting dwelling lncated on the 8ubject property. An application to sell may bt submintd at uny iima taper agricultud preservation district ertabtuh- mant. B. 'Rsquinmenta fbr Applicatwn to SeU. fl) To k conridered by the Foundation, an upplhtion la) Be nniwd by the Board of Trvtecs not later than July 31 of tiu fiscal par in which the applicatiorr io to be consibred; fbl lndude an usking price jbr which the wner is willing to ad1 an Corrment and: (C) Include a complete de$cription of the subject land (if M changea in drrrcriptbn haw oqtrred ab the eatu& lishmnt of the district, the same submitted description will met thls nqcuremmt). . 61 scu aha(1: 1. Atucgt Proparty Dncrlwlcm APvrrlmI (tf ciw tn rppucarim) C. Basis fw Offer to Sell. The basis for estimating the fair market and agricultural use values for an offer to sell an easement may be the landowner's es- timate of value or a land appraisal by the land- owner. D. Notice to Landowner of Receipt and Suficiency of Application to Sell. Within 30 &ys afker the receipt of an application, the Foundation shall notify the landowner of the receipt and sufficiency of the application. If the original application is insufficient, the Foundation shall specifi the reason for insuffiiency and the Foundation shall grant an additional 30 days for the landowner to remedy the insuficiency. If the application is made sufficient wcthin 30 days of the notifmation by the Foundation, the application shall be considered as if it had originally &en submitted in a timely and suficient manner. E. Approval or Disapproval of Application by County Gowrning Body. Within 30 days afrer the receipt of an ap plicatwn to sell, the Founriation shall notify the governing body of the county containing the subject land that an ap plication to sell has been receited. Within 90 days of the notification, the county gouerning body shall advise tk Foundation as to local approval or disapproval of the appli- cation. In deciding whether to approve the application, thil county governing body shall receiue the mcommendation of the county agricultural preservation advisory board. In makin# LLS recommendation, the county agricultural preser- uatwn advisory hoard shall take into consideration criteria and Ytundards adopted by the Foundcrtion under current local regulations. local patterns of land dewlopment, and any locatly established priorities for the presematwn of ag- ricultural land. The county agricultural preservation advi- sory board shall provide a public hearing concerning any applicution to sell if a hearing is requested by a majority of the county agricultural preseruation advisory board, or by a majority of the county governing body, or by the applicant. The Board of Trustees of the Founbtion may not approve an applicatwn to sell which has not been approved by the governing body of the county cuntaining the subject land. F. Value of' Easement. (I) The maximum value of any easement to be pur- chased shall be the asking price, or the difference between the fair market value of the land and the agricultural value of the land, whichecer is lower. (2) The maximum value of an eusement is determined at the tin= of receipt by the Foundation of an application to sell from the kandoccner. The marimurn value shall be de- termined by the Foundation based on one or mom apprais- als by the State appraisers. und on appruiscls, if any. by tke landowner. Appraisals upplicable to an application to sell shall be received by the Foundation within 60 days of the application. (3) If the landowner and Foundation do not agree on the value of the easement as determined by a State ap- praisal, either the landowner or the Foundation may re- quest that the matter be referred to the county board of re- view as established under Artirle 81. 11248, Annotated Code of Maryland, for arbitration as to the value of the ea~etnent. The value determined b.y that arbitmtion shall be binding upn the otuncr and the Foundation in a purchase of the rcrvemant made afrer the arbitration, for n period of 2 years. unless the lan&wner and the Foundation agree upon a less- er due or the iartdowner appeals the results of the arbi- tration to the cirruit court ofthe county in which the land is located. The lurtdowner may refuse any ofrer to buy. (4) The fair market value of the land is the price as of the valuation date for the highest and best use ofthe prop- erty which a vendor, willing but not obligated to sell, would mept for the property, and which a purchaser, willing but not obligated to buy. would pay for the property if the prop- erty was not subject to any restriction imposed under those regulntions. (5) The agricultuml, value of land is the price as ofthe valuation date which a wnrlor. willing but not obligated to sell, would accept fbr the property, and which a purchaser, willing but not obligated to buy, would pay for the property as a firrm unit. to be used for agricultural purposes.' G. Determination by Foundation of Applications to be Approved. In determining which applications to approue fbr the purchase of the easements ofled. the Foundation shall: (1) Appmue only those applications in which the sub- ject Land meets the qualihing criteria of Regulation .OK!, &w, on lands which a.re currently within an agricultural preservation district. h (21 ,~pprotw ap$ications for the sale'ijeasements 6n and in any one county under general allotted purchases in hxending order with respect to the proportion obtained by fiuding the fair market value less the agricultural value. ' !~sY- tb asking price by the fair market value less 'the ag- rkubural value. If proportions obtained am equai, the fd- !owing land characteristics ahdl u&ct priority of acguisi- tiom: highest pra[uctiue capability, greatest urban pres- sum, and largest parcel. (3) Approve only those appZicationa which how rc' ceiued approval ofthe applicable 14 gtmerning body. H. Tender of Offer to Buy Afier Approval ofdpplication. Upon approval of a majority ofthe Board members at-large, and upn the mmmendation of the Sta& TWurer and the secretcuy, an application b sell ahall be approved, and an offer to buy which contains the specifi terms of the pur- chase aha0 be ten- to the landowner. An fir to buy nay specify terms, contingencies, and conditions not eontuined in the original application. . I. Time of Tender: Acceptance or Rejection. , .(l) With respect to allotted pwchases, the Foundbtwn shall tender any offer t9 buy containing the specific terms of the purrhose an or before January 31 of the fiml yew in which the pudase is to be made. (2) 'With mpect to additionai offers to buy tendered, tlte Foundatwn..may mt tender these ofem earlier than 'April I or ia#r than May 29 of the fiscal year in which the purchase is to be made. (3) A landowner has 30 days mm the date of any offer to buy in which to accept or mject the offer. ./ (I! At the time of settlement of the purchase of, an easement, the landowner and the foundntion may agree upon and establish a schedule of payment suck that the landowner may receive consideration for tire easement in a lump sum. or in installments over a period of up to 10 years fmm the date of settlement: (2) If a schedule of installments is agreed upon, the Comptrolier shall retain in the Maryland Agricultural Land Preservation Fund an amount of tnnney sufficient to pay the lrnduwner according to the schedule. (3) The hdowner shail receive annuniiy interest on any unpaid hrrlance remaining afier the date of settiement. This interest shall he at the same rate as any interest-wrned on the finds retained pursuant to W(2), abduZ Cess 'Ib of 1 percent. J. Schedule of Payment. K. Notice of Rejection of Application: Reapplication. (1) On or before June 30, the Foundation shall noti& every iandowner whose application had been rejected dur- ing that fiscal year. The Foundation shali specify the reasons for that rejection. (2) A (andowner whose application has been qjected fir a reason other then insuBient Foundation funds my not re-apply to sell an easement on the same land on the same term until 2 years afler.the dare ofthe original appli- ciation. L. Use of land OR Which Easement Purchaaed. (I) Provisions to be Included in Easement and County Reguiatwns. Agricultural land preservation easementsmay be purchased for land In agricultural u80 which wets the qualifying criteria established under Regulation .&X if th easement and county nrgulatwns governing the use of the hnd inciude the following provisions: (a) Any agriclrlturol use of ?ad is pemirtrd; (bl Operation of machinery wd in form production or the processing of agricuitural prod~c~q is perntitttd. (c) Normal ugricultural opemtions ptrtkmed in QC- cordance with good husbandry practices, whkh do not cause bodily injury or directly endcrnger hunicrn kdh, am permitted, including sale of firm prodwt~ produced on the firm where the sales are made. (2) Dwellings. The wsement shall provide that sub- division fir residential and cornme& purposes is permitted. ~oweucr, upon written applicution to the Foun- dation. amveyance of1 acre or less for the owner who origi- nally sold an easement to the Foundation and f6r each of his children for the purpose of construction of one dwelling house intended for his or their we shall be permitted one time only for that owner and each child, and doas not constitute a residential subdivision for commrrcial pur- pses. The owner also may construct housing for tenants filly engaged in owration ofthe firm, but this construction may not exceed one knant house per 100 acms. (3) Public Not to Be Granted Right of Access DT of Use. Purchase of an easement by the Foundation docs not granf the public any right of uccess or right of use ofthe subjecb PrnPPtY . (4) Other Restrictions. qthr deed mtrictioru shall be substantially in @card wctk those provided in thr sample deea form, Repulatron .OIN. M. Termination ojEasoment. * (1) Intent. Eaements purchased shall be held by th Foundation for as long os profituble brming is feasible 0; the land under easerncnt, and an easement may be tenni nated only in the manner specified in this stctwn. (21 Request for Review. The landowner may reque: that the easement be reuiewed for possible termination of th easement, at any lime riper 25 years fmm the date of puq chase of the easement. (3) Inquiry and Decision. (a) Upon a request for nview of an easement fi termination, an inquiry shall be conducted by the Found tbn to determine the feaqibility of pmfitubk farming on ti subject land. (b) The inquiry shalt be concluded and a decisi~ reached by the Foundation within 180 days *er the requt for termination. curd shall inch& on-rite inspection of t, subject land, a pubiic hearing conducted by the Founddl within the county cwrtaining the subject land afler adrqur public notice, and a report documenting tho findings oft Foundatian. (4) Appro& by County Gouerning Body. An easemg may be terminated only with the upprovat of &he gowrni body of the county containing the subject land. in drcidi whether to appmw the request far termination, the mu9 gouerning body shall receive the recommendation of i county agricuttwul preservation advisvry board. The dr swn of the coturty governing body shall be ma& aflm public heuring required in SMt3). above. The county g erning body shall notify the Foundition of it.$ &cis: within 30 daya aAer the concluaion of the hearing roq~& in OAd13). abuw. (51 Approval by Foundation, Secretary, and St Treasurer. Upontheaflrmatiue uoteofa majorityofthcFor dation members at-large, and upon the approval of the E retar?, and the State Treasurer, the request for terminat shall he approved, and the landowner shall be notified. -\ (2) Maximum Amount to be Expended for Allotted Purchases. (a) Beginning with fiscai year 1979, and in each fis- cal year after, the Foundation shall determine the mtuimurn amount which my be expended for allotted pur- chases of easements on land located within each c0unt.y. (b) The maximum amount which may be expended for allotted purchase8 of easements in any county in any fis- cal year shall be: ti) An amount. to be used for general allotted pur- chases. equal to 1/23 of 112 ofthe total amount to be alioted plw any amount of transferred local open space funds des- ignated by the local gouerning body for general purchases. (id An amount, to be used for matching allotted purchases, which shall be computed for each eligible county by dividing ‘h of the total amount to be allotted equally among those counties having an approued local matching program. The maximum amount auaihble /?om the Found- ation for the Foundation’s share in matching allotted pur- chases may not exceed $1 million in any county in any fiscal year. (iii) Matching allotted purchas& may not be ap- prod for land located in any county which has not secured appmual Fom the Foundation for a local matching program of agricultural land preseivation in accord with Regulation .06. (3) Money Remaining at End of Fiscal Year. Money remaining in the Fund at the end of a fiscal year may not revert to the general funds of the State, but shall remain in the Maryland Agricultural Land Preseruation Fund to be used for the purposes specified in this subtitk. it is the intent that, to the extent feasible, the Foundation use the fill amount of money amilable for the purchase of easements in any fiscal year so as to minimize the amount of money re- maining in the Fund at the end of any fiscal year. (4) Additional Offers to Buy. (a) If the Foundation receives acceptances of offirs to buy in insufficient numbers to expend the total iZm.OURt to be allotted for allotted purchases, the Foundation, to the extent fewible, shall tender additional offers to buy in sufficient numbers to expend the total amount to be allotted. (6) Additional offers to buy shall be tendered: (i) To landowners who have applied to sell ease- ments on land which was otherwise acceptable, but who had not received an offer to buy solely bemuse of limitations on the amount of money to be spent for allotted purchases. (ii) To applicanb on a statewide basis in decreas- ing order with respect to the proportion obtained by divid- ing the fair market value less the agricultural value less the asking price by the fair market value less the agricuitural value. if proportions obtained are equal, the following land characteristics shall affect priority of acquisitions: highest productive capability, greatest urban pressure, and largest parcef. (iii) Only a@er the ezpiration of the period ailawed for acceptance of offers to buy under allotted general and matching purchases. E. Local Funds. (1) Transfer of Local Subdiuision’s Program Open- Space Funds. If authorized by law, a portion of a local sub- division’s allocation of program open space funds is trans- ferred to the Maryland Agricultural Land Preservation Fund pursuant to the prouisions of Natural Resources Arti- cle, 85-903, the Foundation may use these transferred fun only for purchases of easements on land located within tj boundaries of the subdivision which requested the tmnsfe of funds. These transferred open-space funds shall be ova: able in addition to any funds which would otherwise be c lotted under this subtitle for purchases of easements in t! county which requested the transfer of funds, and, at ti discretion of the local gowerning body, the transfer ope: space funds may be used far general purchases or applie as the local contribution in matching purchases. (2) Other Local Funds. Other local funds may 6 transferred to the Maryland Agricultural Land Preseruc tion Fund. .06 Local Matching Progranu of Agricultural Land Prea A. The Foundation may approve a local matching prc gram of ngricultural land preservation, provided that: (‘1) The county agrees to make payments up to I specified and Foundation-approved aggregate amount to th. Maryland Agricultural Land Preservation Fund to equal c least 40 percent of the value of an easement acquired by th. Foundation as a result of a matching allotted purchas, made during the ensutng fiscal year; (2) The county shows evidence that the local matchin) program for the acquisition of easemnts for purposes of ag ricultural hod preservation will not result in preservatio: of land which does not meet the qualifying criteria as estd lished in these regulations; and (31 The county request for approoal of a local matchin; program is submitted to the Foundation, together with an: necessary agreements, not later than 90 days before the be ginning of the fiscal year for which approval is bein$, sought. The required committmant of funds not later thai 90 days betare the fiscal year may 6e adjusted and resub mitted to the Foundntmn nt any time before the beginnrng c.. the fiscal year in accord with the amount formally commct. ted through county budget adoption. 3. Approval of a local matching program by the Foundo tion is valid only during the fiscal year following the fiscc year of the request for approoal by the county. C. Local matching programs shall be approved upon th afirmativc vote of a majority of the Board members a: large. and upon approval of the Secretary and the Stat. Treasurer. D. Local matching programs submitted k, the Found tion for consideration shall include: 11) An inventory of productive agricultuml land in the county baped upon the qualifying criteria of these regula- tions; (21 County agricultural land prt-servution goah; 13) Anniysis of alternntive local means of preserving pmductiw agricultural land; (4) Anulysis of the relationship between the Count3 Comprehensive Plan and agricultural land preservatior goals and program; and (51 Selected approaches to preserving productive ag- ricultural Land. E. Matchin.q allotted funds shall be available erclusiwi: for the acqursttion of easements. The Foundation may no1 approve matching allotted purchases of easements for land located in any county which has not secured approval fmm the Foundntion for a local matching program of agrieuf. tural land preservation. eraation. -9- END OF PREVIOUS DOCUMENT. ANOTHER DOCUMENT FOLLOWS 1 Disappearing Fmlands A Citizen’s Guide to Agricultural Land Preservation DisappearingFamdands A Citizen's Guide to Agricuhzral Land Preservation !' \r National Association of Counties Research Foundation I Bernard F. Hillenbrand, Executive Director Robert C. Weaver, Associate Director Edward Thompson, Jr., Director, Agricultural Lands Project December 1979 Disappearing Farmlands Clearly, there is a dramatic change taking place in U.S. agriculture-the ground is literally being excavated out from under it. i Every day 12 square miles of American farmland are converted to nonagricultural uses.zo That's three million acres a year. Over the past decade or so, the loss of farmland amounts to about 30 million acres-an area the size of Vermont, New Hampshire, Massachusetts, Rhode Island, Connecticut, New Jersey and Delaware combined, And this loss has touched every corner of America: New England has witnessed the disappearance of half her native farmland, the Mid-Atlantic States have lost 22 percent of theirs, and even the vast Midwest has suffered the loss of 9 percent of its cropland.' According to the US. General Accounting Office and the Soil Conservation Service, only 35 million acres of the potential cropland remaining in the United States could easily be put into production without expensive treatment to correct its soil, water and slope deficiencies." But this assumes that landowners would be willing to grow crops where there are now pastures and woodlots. At the present rate of farmland conversion, our cropland "frontier" could be closed within another decade. Clearly, there is a dramatic change taking place in U.S. agriculture-the ground is literally being excavated out from under it. But nobody seems to be starving. In fact, we read all the time about bumper crops and agricultural surpluses. Why should we be concerned about the loss of farmland? disappearing farmland is halted, it will one day deeply touch :> /- of our lives and those of our children. As Secretary of Agriculture Bob Begland put it, "Our land and water resources are being whipsawed between the demands for greater food and fiber production and the demands from commerce and a mass society for space and water for suburbs, roads and other development^."'^ Indeed, the effects of farmland conversion are already being felt in a variety of ways in local communities throughout America. As individuals and as a nation, we cannot afford to allow much more of our farmland to disappear-slowly, bit by irreplaceable bit-before it begins to affect our pocketbooks, the quality of our lives and, perhaps, even our national security. The answer is, simply, that unless the steady trend of 1 1 h Agricultural Productivity and Farmland How much longer can we continue to depend upon technology-the development of which has relied on cheap energy-and the always unpredictable weather, to keep agricultural production high while farmland disappears? Up until about a century ago, agricultural production was more or less limited by the amount of land under cultivation. Clear more acreage, plant more crops, feed more people. Then came the industrial revolution and, in the years following World War 11, the so-called "Green Revolution," which enabled the nation's farmers to grow progressively more food by substituting machines and energy for land. The tractor replaced the horse and, later, chemical fertilizer (made from petroleum) replaced the manure. occurred during the 1930s when drought and poor husbandry caused the ruin of 100 million acres of farmland, but generally the trend has been a steady increase in the per acre yield of American agriculture.6 Indeed, increasingly sophisticated technology, not to mention a period of benign weather, allowed us to double crop yields in the two decades after 1950.'l This helps to explain why, despite the dramatic losses of agricultural land, our food production capability has up until now remained practically undiminished. But how much longer can we continue to depend upon technology-the development of which has relied on cheap energy-and the weather, always unpredictable, to keep agricultural production high while farmland disappears? Is there, in fact, any substitute for good agricultural land, about 17 percent of which lies close to our expanding urban centers and is under the heaviest development pressure?' There have been some productivity setbacks, such as Energy After decades of advancement, agricultural technology now appears to be running up against economic and ecologic limitations. Foremost among these is the availability and cost of energy-according to one calculation, it now takes nine units of fossil fuel energy to produce each unit of food energy that comes from American farmland.3 The extraordinary dependence of modern agriculture on energy is not surprising, considering that farm machinery runs on diesel fuel, fertilizers are made from natural gas feedstocks, pesticides and other chemicals come from petroleum, natural gas is also used to dry enormous quantities of grain, and electricity is used to run the pumps for irrigation. With the dependence of agriculture on energy, what are . ' implications of an energy shortage for agricultural productivity? The use of fertilizer provides a good illustration: A study at the University of Illinois concluded that the amount of corn that can be grown on 100 acres, using 120 pounds of nitrogen fertilizer per acre, would require up to 300 acres to produce without fertilizer. ' shortage of natural gas feedstocks or because of prices that are out of reach, would limit productivity and make it essential that more acreage be put into production. That is, ifthe farmland acreage is still available. Multiply this example by the many other ways in which agriculture uses fossil fuel energy, and you begin to see why scarce and increasingly costly enera supplies limit our ability to maintain agricultural productivity by relying on energy-consuming technology to make up for the continuing loss of farmland. A cutback in the use of fertilizer, either because of an absolute Soil and Water But there are other significant limitations on agricultural productivity that place a premium on the preservation of our remaining farmland. Our soil and water resources, both vital to agriculture, are being depleted and degraded. Since 1935, about 100 million acres of farmland have been idled because of soil erosion.15 The annual loss of soil from U.S. cropland has been conservatively estimated to average about five tons per acre? Thus, in addition to the three million acres of farmland we lose 3 I1 I i i I, each year to nonagricultural uses, the equivalent of another three million acres is washed into our rivers.” An Iowa agricultural specialist put it more dramatically: “Farmers here are losing two bushels of soil for each bushel of corn they Agricultural productivity also depends quite heavily on irrigation, particularly in the semi-arid western states. A federal study showed that in the early 1970s about 12.percent of all harvested cropiand was irrigated, and that the production from this land represented 27 percent of the value of all U.S. crop prod~ction.’~ In some areas the percentage is much higher: 90 percent of the value of crops from California depends on ation, over 80 percent of the crop values in Colorado, Texas Florida, and almost 50 percent of the value of crops from Nebra~ka.’~ urban areas and energy development poses a threat to the viability of irrigated agriculture in the West. Depletion of groundwater resources in the high plains, stretching from Texas to Nebraska, and in the San Joaquin Valley of California is reaching critical level^.'^ And the misapplication of irrigation technology on some western croplands is causing the buildup of salinity in the soil, which may eventually destroy productivity.8 Competition for limited quantities of water from growing Climate Finally, there is the weather. Nobody pays more attention to the weather than the farmer, for the obvious reason that crop production depends, for better or worse, on its changing moods. Experts who study long-term weather trends believe the world climate is now emerging from a relatively mild od that dates back to the turn of the century, and is returning to a “normal” pattern of greater ~npredictability.~ The drought that gripped the West during 1974, and reduced crop production, is thought to be symptomatic of this trend. There is evidence too that the climate is cooling off, warning of a further drop in agricultural productivity: According to the American Association for the Advancement of Science, the temperature of the Northern Hemisphere has cooled about three degrees since 1945.’ With the cost of energy skyrocketing, the depletion of soil and water resources (caused in part by the side effects of technology), and maybe even the climate turning against us, 4 long before anything resembling it would occur, the shortage of fwd-caused ultimately by a shortage of farmland-would begin to squeeze consumers’ pocketbooks. An increase in food prices, dictated by supply and demand, would force low-income people to eliminate basic nutrients from their diets and cause the middle class to cut back on certain foods. Shortages of specialty crops like oranges, caused by the conversion of citrus groves to subdivisions, just as they are now caused by frost damage, would make these commonplace foods luxury items. If all of this sounds familiar, consider the fact that every time you there is a serious question whether American agriculture can continue to “replace” farmland losses through technology. The evidence is mounting that it cannot: Per acre’yields from U.S. croplands peaked in 1972 and have since then fluctuated rather widely at lower level^.^'^^ To be sure, new technology is being developed all the time, but it has been estimated that the lead time between the development of agricultural technology in the laboratory and its widespread application on the ground averages about 15 years. And new technology is expensive, since much of it relies on energy. Will new, productivity-stimulating technology-that is affordable-be ready in time to avert a crisis? A crisis caused by the steady, unrelenting disappearance of our most basic natural resource, agricultural land. The National and Global Farmland Losses Implications of -{ ’ From a diplomatic viewpoint, American agricultural exports contribute to the international reputation of this nation, perhaps even more than its military strength. What are the possible consequences of the continuing disappearance of American agricultural land? Or, to put it another way, what are the reasons, in the face of limits on agricultural productivity, why we should preserve farmland? It is self-evident that the strength and security of the United States would be jeopardized if it were unable to feed its own 1 people. Mass starvation in America appears highly unlikely, but I go through the checkout line at the supermarket on a weekly shopping trip, another 60 thousand acres of American farmland has disappearedz’ But we should not be concerned only about our domestic food supplies, for the United States can truthfully be said to be the breadbasket of the world. From a broader, global perspective the continued ability of America to produce sufficient quantities of basic foodstuffs is an economic, diplomatic and humanitarian imperative. The value of American agricultural exports in 1978 reached $27 billion, and this sum made about 20 percent, or one fifth of all U.S. exports.” The income we receive from agricultural exports is an important counterweight to help balance the payments America makes to foreign countries for imported oil. Some experts believe that, as our mineral resources are depleted and our older industrial plants become antiquated, agricultural exports will play an even larger role in maintaining the future economic stability of the United state^.^ From a diplomatic viewpoint, American agricultural exports contribute to the international reputation of this nation, perhaps even more than its military strength. There are both practical and humanitarian dimensions to this proposition. The practical importance of U.S. agriculture is that food helps cement international friendships and reduces tension among nations. For example, the Soviet Union has in the past relied on the United States for a sizable proportion of its grain and may in the future become more dependent, along with our neighbors in Canada, upon American agricultural exports if the cooling of the global climate reduces grain production in the more northern latitudes3 Of course, none of us would wish for such a prospect, because we regard food as more than an international bargaining chip-it is vital to human survival. America’s ability to produce food for export is the single most important weapon in the war against world hunger. The population of the globe is now over four billion people, a great percentage of whom inhabit developing nations. By .the year 2000, experts predict, we will add another three billion mouths to feed, most of whom, again, will be born in the countries least able to feed themselves.’* Ultimately, preserving its rich bounty of agricultural land is one of the most significant humanitarian gestures that America can make. 4 I CEREAL YIELD PER HECTARE. U.S. I v) z hh h 7 IS e The Effects of Farmland Loss At the Community Level There is no question whatsoever that farmland loss is having a powerful effect, right now, on the economy, social fabric and quality of life in local communities all over the country. The national and global questions raised by the continuing loss of American farmland are serious. Although, barring an’ unforeseen climatic or pestilential disaster, it may take time f 3 its most severe consequences to be felt. Some people may argue that the disappearance of 12 square miles of farmland a day does not yet constitute a crisis of national importance, but there is no question whatsoever that it is having a powerful effect, right now, on the economy, social fabric and quality of life in local communities all over the c0unt1-y.~ Let’s look at a “typical” community to see what is happening as farmland is converted to nonagricultural uses. The leading cause of farmland loss is unplanned suburban development, sometimes called “leapfrog” or “scattershot” development because it often skips over land close to town and sprawls out over the countryside in a random pattern. Such 5 development not only takes farmland directly out of production, but also tends to create conditions- that make it unpleasant for farmers and homeowners alike and, consequently, leads to friction between them. The odor of manure may offend homeowners, the noise from a tractor working before dawn may bother them, and blowing dust and agricultural chemicals may cause them more serious problems. On the other hand, dogs may chase livestock, teenage children may trample crops or vandalize fences and farm equipment, and suburban m A LOSS OF PRIME FARMLAND BY REGION (1987.19751, Thousands 01 Acres Source: N. Sampson, Development on Prima Farmland, Envlron. Comment, Jan. 1978 wners themselves may be led to complain to the rities about the "nuisance" that nearly farms are c:rt?ating. While the situation is unpleasant for both, it is the farmers who generally lose out, or simply give up, to the growing numbers of suburbanites. More agricultural land is thus allowed to lie fallow or is sold for additional de~elopment.~ But the chain of consequences does not stop there. As more and more farms succumb to development, fewer suppliers of farm implements, seed, fertilizer and other agricultural necessities can stay in business due to the decreased demand for their products and services. The agricultural businesses close up or move away, forcing the remaining farmers to travel greater distances and to pay more for supplies. Jobs and income are lost when the businesses go; their contribution to the local economy 0 is often appreciated only after it is too late. And the whole fabric of rurd life starts to unraveI.13 Farmers and supporting industries are obviously the most profoundly affected by this whole turn of events-which is being repeated all over the United States-but the rest of the community also shares the consequences. Open spaces that add immeasurably to the quality of life of a community gradually disappear. Natural resources and environmental amenities are often sacrificed. Those who once enjoyed locally grown produce are forced to rely on farflung markets and to pay higher prices. And, perhaps most importantly, the cost of providing community servces may increase dramatically. As development spreads out, sewers, water lines, roads and school bus routes must cover greater distances than if development were more concentrated. The cost of these extensions is, of course, met with tax dollars paid by local residents.'So everyone pays for "scattershot" development on agricultural lands. Federal Impacts on Farmland The vast programs and sweeping policies of the federal government exert a powerful influence on the use of agricultural land. Useful but single-minded public works and facilities often take farmland directly out of production. For example, about 21 million acres of land in the United States are now covered by highways, including one million acres of mostly rural land that was paved over during the construction of the federal interstate highway system.' such as the Army Corps of Engineers and Bureau of Reclamation, have drowned 10 million acres, much of it rich bottomland, and continue to do so at a rate of 300 thousand acres a year.' Airports, which come under the authority of the Federal Aviation Administration, take another 35 thousand acres of farmland annually.' While many of these federally sponsored or supported projects may be justified, they are often too large or poorly located and consume more farmland than necessary. Then there are activities that are regulated by, and to some extent subsidized by, the federal government. Sewage treatment plants funded and regulated by the Environmental Protection Reservoirs and other impoundments, built by federal agencies Age hi sen enc syst leac ultir and EI hP can watc the. 20 b don Ener coal- witl- of a Tb activ in in capit Spec' are t, conv on Prom farm! the ir patte desig Sirnil, farm may hdm Pli( pOliC colla1 rural for A Agency are often a key stimulus to sprawl development. EPA limitations on the amount of sewer capacity that can be added to serve growth in already built up areas may unintentionally encourage scattershot development in rural areas using septic systems. If the intensive use of septic systems in the countryside leads to water pollution, sewage treatment facilities may " ultimately be financed by the Farmers Home Administration and further encourage the loss of farmland.18 Energy development and generation is one of the most important activities regulated by the federal government that can consume agricultural land, if the regulators are not watchful. It is estimated that four million acres of rural land in the United States have already been stripmined, and that almost 20 billion tons of strippahle coal-a source of energy that federal policy favors-underlies 2.5 million acres of farmland in Illinois Electrical generating plants, regulated by the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, also take farmland; a single coal-fired 2800 MW power plant proposed in Kansas would, with its cooling lake and ash disposal areas, cover 13,500 acres of agricultural land.' These kinds of federally sponsored, funded and regulated activities and projects generally affect specific tracts of farmland in individual local communities. But there are other federal policies that may affect farmland everywhere. An example is the capital gains taxation of land sales, which makes land speculation a more attractive enterprise than investments that are taxed at a higher rate. Speculation, in turn, can stimulate the conversion of farmland to de~elopment.~,~ On the other hand, there are federal policies that hold promise as tools to help prevent unnecessary conversion of farmland. The Environmental Protection Agency has recognized the impact that sewer financing and regulations have on patterns of land development and has adopted a formal policy designed to protect significant farmlands from this impact." Similarly, the U.S. Department of Agriculture now has a farmland preservation policy and reviews federal projects that may result in the loss of agricultural land.I6 And the Carter Administration's urban policy, which seeks to promote compact urban growth and revitalize the cities, could have the mllateral effect of reducing the pressure for development of rural farmlands." Because of these federal efforts, there is hope for American farmland and all that depends on it. f .. 8’ Searching for Solutions: 1 State and Local Approaches to Farmland Preservation Some local governments and states are helping to solve community problems caused by the loss of farmland by adopting measures to combat it. While the federal government influences agricultural land, what happens at the local level is also very important. Sprawl development, of the kind that unnecessarily and prematurely converts farmland to nonagricultural uses, is generally the result of increasing pressure for urban growth and, often, the inability of local government to control it. The federal and state governments sometimes contribute to the problem as well through programs that unwittingly promote scattershot development and projects that directly take farmland out of production. Pressure for growth takes the form of population expansion and, consequently, an increased demand for new housing. Developers who attempt to meet this demand often bid up the market price of farmland to where selling the land becomes more attractive to farmers than growing crops, particularly if the farmer is aging or his operation isn’t very profitable. Once development gains a foothold in the countryside, nearby \ farmers may neglect to invest in necessary improvements and otherwise enter a “holding pattern,” waiting for the day when 1 they too will be made an offer that they can’t refuse. An uncertain future puts additional pressure on agriculture to give way to sub~rbanization.~ As all of this is taking place, the response of the community at large may contribute to the problem. Planner William Toner described what he calls a “series of self-fulfilling prophecies” that often confront local government: “First you project substantial growth in an agricultural area, then you build roads and water and sewer lines to accommodate the growth, then you switch the zoning from agricultural to residential, and, presto! subsidies in place, population fo~ows.~~’~ To avoid this turn of events, communities can get out ahead of the problem by planning for the logical management of growth. But growth management is a complex task that demands sophisticated technical groundwork, adequate financial resources and, perhaps above all, an understanding of the process and the stakes involved by the general public. Particularly in rural areas, communities often do not have the money to hire planning technicians, and the people who li there, having never experienced leapfrog development an consequences, may be unaware of just how quickly suburban sprawl can get out of hand. Some local governments and states are, however, helping to solve community problems caused by the loss of farmland by adopting measures to combat it. The growing number of local farmland preservation programs is starting to offer hope that enough agricultural land can be retained to avert a national crisis. But this hope is tempered by the fact that the farmland problems in your community can be solved only if you and your neighbors take action to keep the hope alive. The following experiences with state and local farmland preservation measures serve as examples of how the job can be done. 9 4 y 10 Tulare County, California Tulare County, located in south central California, is the third largest agricultural producer in the nation, with farm products contributing about $700 million annually to the local economy. Its land and climate are ideal for growing specialty crops that cannot easily be produced elsewhere. During the period from 1964 through 1969, Tulare County experienced the loss of 66 thousand acres of its farmland, mostly to suburban "ranchettes" and small lot development scattered through the co~ntryside.'~ establishes different minimum lot sizes, ranging from 20 to 80 acres, designed to protect agricultural operations that require different size farms to be profitable. Development is concentrated in those parts of the county, generally adjacent to its existing municipalities, where agricultural districts have not been established by the county under California state law. The Tulare program uses a system of suitabili?y points to determine where residential development is appropriate. For example, if a building site has superior agricultural soils, it qualifies for four points; if the building lot is too large and would take more farmland out of production than necessary, another four points can be added; if the surrounding lands are used for productive agriculture, three points may be tacked on; or if the building site is far from public services such as county roads and fire stations, add another point or two. In all, Tulare evaluates development on the hasis of 15 categories, each of which carries suitability points. If a proposed development accumulates too Tulare has adopted an agricultural zoning program that many points, it is disappro~ed.'"~~ advantage of providing detailed criteria-the suitability points-for determining when the character of an area has substantially changed from agricultural to residential, so as to allow what is in effect a change in zoning. The Tulare zoning program is based on a comprehensive plan that includes an agricultural lands component, and thus far seems to have been successful, since its adoption in 1975, in encouraging development close to existing urban centers, while preventing the premature subdivision and conversion of its large expanse of prime farmland. This system is flexible like traditional zoning, but it has the i.:$ Black Hawk County, Iowa Black Hawk County is situated right in the heart of the great American Corn Belt and surrounds the city of Waterloo which takes up about 10 percent of its total area. Almost 60 percent of the soils in Black Hawk are classified by the U.S. Department of Agriculture as Classes I and 11, the best that exist for growing crops. In contrast, only about 20 percent of the land nationwide falls into soil Classes I and 11. But in the early 1970s local officials in Black Hawk realized that the excellent soils in the county were growing television antennas instead of corn, and in 1973 adopted an innovative zoning program that is rooted in the soil itse~.'~,'~ The Black Hawk program is based on a detailed method of rating soils according to their agricultural productivity. The system is geared to the U.S. Department of Agriculture "cor? suitability rating," and dedicates to exclusive agricultural us -$ those soils with a CSR of 70 and above, soils that produce roughly 115 bushels or more of corn per acre. In those areas where the soil is less productive-about 30 percent of the total area of the county-development is guided toward buildable soils that are suitable for septic systems. In agricultural areas that are not zoned exclusively for this purpose, development can take place on lots that are a minimum of three acres in size, if 75 percent of the lot consists of buildable soils. The Black Hawk program is adapted to its own unique circumstances, but like its Tulare counterpart it seems to be working to preserve the best agricultural lands and to concentrate development around the perimeter of its principal 11 ! municipality. Both the technical groundwork that went into its development, and the flexibility of its administration, contribute to its success as a possible model for farmland preservation in areas of large-scale agriculture. State of Wisconsin Nearly all the states have adopted some kind of measure to try to preserve farmland. Most of these take the shape of special property tax breaks for farmers who keep their land in production, but this approach has been criticized as simply a ‘ng action” that encourages land speculation and is not v ly effective at preserving farmland.Ig The Wisconsin farmland preservation program, however, stands out along with a handful of others as a notably successful effort. iiP The Wisconsin program, adopted in 1977, gives farmers the benefit of a state income tax credit (and protection from special tax assessments for municipal services). The credit varies with farm income-it increases up to $4,200 annually, as income decreases-and serves as an “insurance policy” against crop failure or other factors that otherwise could financially cripple farm families. Unlike the property tax break used by some other states, the Wisconsin income tax credit does not cut into local revenues.28 To qualify for the income tax credit, the farmer and his local community must take a number of actions. Until 1982, the end irst phase of the Wisconsin program, a farmer may for the credit if he either contracts with the state to keep his land in agricultural use, or his land is zoned exclusively for agriculture by local government. After 1982, counties must either adopt exclusive agricultural zoning programs or, in the case of predominantly rural counties with less than 75,000 inhabitants, prepare farmland preservation plans as a less stringent alternative to zoning. Unless counties take these steps-the state helps them by providing technical assistance-farmers cannot qualify for the tax credit simply by signing contracts to hold their land off the development market. If a contract between the farmer and state expires, and is not renewed either because of personal preference or the failure of local government to act, the 12 accumulated income tax credits must be repaid completely or in part.28 Our description of the Wisconsin program has been simplified for the sake of brevity, but the fact remains that its two-phased approach has stimulated county interest in farmland preservation. In effect, the program attempts to harness the political support of farmers by giving them an incentive, namely the continuation of the tax credit, to encourage local government to adopt agricultural zoning or farmland preservation plans. During the first year of the Wisconsin program, farmws became eligible for income tax credits at a rate much greater than their entry into similar programs in other states. This seems to demonstrate that a program that requires the active cooperation of farmers, local government and the state itself holds great promise as a means to preserve farmland on a statewide basis. Suffolk County, New York Suffolk County is a prototype urbanizing area in the shadow of the eastern megalopolis, taking up the far end of Long Island. Its population has increased six-fold since World War 11, and during this period it lost over half of its original 120,000 acres of farmland to development. Still, gross agriculture sales in Suffolk total about $70 million per year, ranking the county first in New York State.25 In 1972, Suffolk County embarked on a program of purchasing the development rights to farmland. A “development right,” as the term implies, is simply the legal right to use farmland for nonagricultural purposes such as residential development. The county pays farmers, who voluntarily offer their development rights, the difference between the assessed value of their acreage for development and its value for agriculture, a price that has averaged about $3,000 per acre in Suffolk. By selling development rights, farmers retain ownership of the land itself and can continue farming on a more solid financial foundation, not only because they receive a cash payment, but also because their property tax assessment is reduced. The county selects parcels for purchase very carefully, trying to secure an agricultural core in each key area of its jurisdiction. Soil suitability, present land usage and development pressure also enter into the equation used to select farmlands from among those whose owners submit bids for purchase. To date, Suffolk has acquired the development rights to 3,200 acres of its best agricultural land, and has plans to double this figure. Funding for the purchase of development rights has come from general revenue bonds sold by the county. The Suffolk program-the first of its kind in any LJ.S. county-is a relatively conservative approach to farmland preservation that can get expensive where it is necessary to protect large areas of agricultural land. But, despite the expense involved, the purchase of development rights is attractive to farmers and can help obtain their cooperation and support for other multifaceted approaches to farmland preservation. I(, Suffolk County, it seems to have had an encouraging effect on the entire agricultural community, because it has demonstrated that local government cares about its native industry and wants to help ensure its survival. 9 Howard County, Maryland Located midway between the metropolitan areas of Baltimore and Washington, D.C., Howard County has experienced the same pressures for growth as has Suffolk, losing roughly half of its farmland since 1950. The existence of the planned "new town" of Columbia in the center of the county has somewhat mitigated the effects of sprawl development in Howard, but intensive subdivision activity continues. Howard, too, has adopted a local program of purchasing, development rights to farmland, funded presently out of re 9 estate transfer taxes. But what distinguishes this county is its diligent pursuit of farmland preservation, using all its available policy tools, and its close cooperation with the State of Maryland, which has a deve1opmc:nt rights purchase program inspired by Howard County officials. The county is actively encouraging the formation of agricultural districts under Maryland law, which qualifies farmers for sale of their development rights. The agricultural districts, once established, will become a formally constituted element of the county's comprehensive plan, now undergoing a major revision to achieve this goal. Cooperation with the state in what amounts to a joint development rights purchase program 13 gives Howard great flexibility and a broader financial basis for ensuring this permanent protection of its farmland.26 Other State and Local Farmland Initiatives Other jurisdictions have adopted farmland preservation approaches that are variations on the themes adopted by these local governments. Some of the more interesting are: The Blue Earth County, Minnesota zoning ordinance that calls for one dwelling unit per "quarter-quarter section" or 40 ao, but allows additional dwellings as a bonus if they are concentrated rather than widely ~eparated.'~' 22 zoning program that creates several exclusive agricultural districts and thus treats farming as a preferred use-like other industries in their respective zones-rather than simply as something that may occur until development is ready to take The Walworth County, Wisconsin comprehensive plan and The initiation in Chester County, Pennsylvania of an Agricultural Preservation Council that will take an active role in promoting agriculture much like the county development council promotes other business and indu~try.'~ The agricultural district program in New York State, and statewide purchase of development rights programs in Massachusetts, New Jersey, and most recently, New Hampshire. Conclusion: Where Do We Go From Here? These are but a few of the growing number of farmland preservation approaches that are being taken by states and counties throughout the United States. Citizens and public officials may have new ideas that are suited to the geographic, economic and political situation in your community. Considering the consequences for your locality and possibly the nation itself, it is well worth trying to preserve farmland no matter what the local circumstances may be. The experiences of Ware, Black Hawk, Wisconsin, Suffolk, Howard and other pioneers offer lessons to other communities that wish to preserve farmland: The early participation and cooperation of the agricultural community is essential to the success of any local farmland preservation program. The agricultural community-including not only farmers, but also county agricultural extension agents, representatives of farm organizations and agricultural businessmen-has the most to gain or lose from any local attempt to preserve farmland. The political support of agriculturalists for local ordinances, plans or bond issues is usually critical to the adoption of these measures for farmland preservation. Moreover, as land use specialist William Toner puts it, “Planners know how to plan, but farmers know how to farm.” Their experience on the ground puts farmers in a better position than any other group of citizens to provide common sense approaches to the related problems of preserving farmland and farming itself. Many communities have, as the first step in putting together a program of farmland preservation, established official agricultural advisory committees to document the agricultural problems in their locality and to propose solutions to farmland loss.22r26 Careful technical analysis of the local farmland situation, including surveys of soil types and land usage, is the basis for a reasoned choice about how much and which kinds of farmland should be preserved by a community. Very few state or local programs have set for themselves the illusory goal of protecting all their agricultural lands. The choice of which lands to preserve as a priority thus becomes an important question. Good technical information about the value and productivity of local farmland, and the uses to which it is being put, is the cornerstone of a responsible farmland preservation program. federal government agencies, notably the U.S. Department of Agriculture, whose Soil Conservation Service provides indispensable help with soil surveys. Some communities have, as part of their technical analysis, reviewed the statistics that demonstrate the economic contribution that agriculture makes to their locality; the publication of this kind of information has helped gain public acceptance for their farmland preservation Technical assistance is sometimes available from a number of programs. 1 Local farmland preservation works best when t. the tools available to government are used in a coordinated way, so that policies do not work at cross purposes. Any one approach to farmland preservation is not likely to be effective, if other government programs or policies are inconsistent with it. For example, agricultural zoning can be undercut, if the local capital improvement plan calls for the extension of water and sewer lines into prime farming areas, or if property taxes are not restructured so as to prevent the premature sale of farmland for development. Similarly, agricultural districmg and the purchase of development rights can help preserve farmland, but may not succeed in preserving farming itself, if state or local policies do not support agriculture as an ongoing enterprise. And state and local initiatives themselves may be rendered ineffective if federal actions are not consistent with them. A coordinated farmlar preservation strategy that meshes all the policy tools of government is the approach that is most likely to succeed. Communities that provide for a flexible balance between the preservation of farmland and the development of housing and industry are most likely to succeed. Farmland preservation is a sophisticated process that seeks to meet community residential and industrial development goals by directing such development onto lands where it is most appropriate, thus saving the most valuable farmlands and sustaining native agricultural industry. Communities cannot afford to ignore the “other side of the coin” in trying to preserve 1s farmland. Generally speaking, at least at the initial stages of farmland conversion within a community, it is not the extent of development so much as the improper type of development- sprawling “leapfrog” or “scattershot” development-that undermines local agriculture. Of course, there are places where so much farmland has been taken out of production that a community cannot afford to lose much more before agricultural support businesses have to close shop. But, in most communities, there is room for both development and agriculture, and the success of farmland preservation depends on finding an appropriate mix that will neither stifle reasonable development nor contribute to the ruin of the local agricultural economy. CI .. ..I The prospect of America running out of fardand is, perhaps, even more alarming than that of running out of energy. Just imagine what it would be like to stand for hours in a food line and then to pay higher prices for groceries than we do for gasoline. Our national energy problems have arisen, in part, because we were not foresighted enough to see them coming we did not conserve resources wisely, and now we cannot seem to produce enough to go around. But, unless we preserve agricultural land, there will be no way to “produce” more of it. In the words of Robert J. Gray, executive director of the National Agricultural Lands Study, “As a nation, we must come to the realization that prime farmland is no longer a surplus resource, if, indeed, it ever was.”zo With the recognition that America no longer has any farmland to waste must come a dedicated willingness on the f government to do something about it. As we have seen, Qa few state and local governments have taken the lead to come up with promising approaches to farmland preservation at the community level. But there is a need to devise new methods and techniques for preventing the loss of farmland: new variations on local zoning authority, innovative combinations of techniques such as transfer of development rights to farmland, along with ways of getting more out of the local farmland preservation dollar, and original approaches to the cooperation of states and counties in joint farmland preservation programs. The more approaches to preservation that are available, the greater will be the likelihood that al least one of them will be adaptable to the circumstances of your community. 16 To support local communities in their efforts to preserve farmland, the federal establishment must take a hard look at its programs and policies that can and do frustrate local preservation initiatives. The existing procedures specified by the National Environmental Policy Act and the A-95 review (through which local governments are notified of proposed federal projects) do not, as a matter of fact, guarantee that the impact of federal activities on farmland are adequately considered prior to their implementation or that these activities are compatible with local farmland preservation programs. Federal policies should be reexamined to determine how they can be changed to accommodate the goal of protecting our agricultural land base, and, most importantly, a fail-safe process should be established to ensure consultation with state and local governments whenever a proposed federal action might affect farmland. concern. In a nation where government derives its support from the will of the people, there is no substitute for citizen participation and private initiative when it comes to solving problems, whether they affect only the local community or the nation as a whole. Our elected and appointed government officials need our encouragement and support for conscientious farmland preservation measures, the positive benefits of which we all will share. Finally, we all must make farmland preservation our personal References and Sources of Additional Information 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Agricultural Retention: An Emerging Issue, by Dallas Miner, in Environmental Comment, Urban Land Institute (Washington: May, 1975) Background Paper: Conserving the Nation’s Farmland, by Jon Clark, Northeast-Midwest Institute (Washington: 1979) The Casefor Retaining Agricultural Land, by Charles E. Little, Papers from a November 8,1977 Workshop, Library of Congress (Washington: 1977) b Growth and Change In Rural America, by Glenn V. Fuguitt, Paul R. Voss and J.C. Doherty, Urban Land Institute (Washington: 1979) Land and Food: The Preservation of U.S. Farmland, by Charles E. Little, American Land Forum (Washington: 1979) Land Use, Reprinted from the Fifth Annual Report on the Council on Environmental Quality (Washington: 1979) Land Use Policy and Agriculture: A State and Local Perspective, by Melvin A. Cotner, USDA Economic Research Service (Washington: 1977) The Loss of Agricultural Land, by Roger Blobaum, Report to the Citizens Advisory Committee on Environmental Quality (Washington: 1974) a Preservation @Prime Agricultural Land, in Environmental - Comment, Urban Land Institute (Washington: January, 1978) Preserving America’s Farmland: A Goal the Federal Government Should Support, US. General Accounting Office, Report to Congress (Washington: 1979) President’s 1978 National Urban Policy Report, US. Department of Housing and Urban Development (Washington: 1978) Protecting Farmland: The Ethical Dimension, by R. Neil Sampson, National Association of Conservation Districts (Washington: 1978) 17 13 Saving Farms and Farmland: A Community Guide, by William Toner, American Society of Planning Officials (Chicago: 1978) : 14 Saving the Garden: The Preservation of Farmland and Other Environmentalfy Valuable Land, by Robert E. Coughlin, National Science Foundation (Washington: 19771 I ,' 15 State Agriculture Land Issues, by Leonard U. Wilson, Council of State Governments (1979) 16 Statement on Land Use Policy, Secretary's Memorandum No. 1827-Revised, U.S. Department of Agriculture (October 30,1978) j 17 , $icy on Agricultural Lands, U.S. Environmental Protection 1 . &jgency (September 8,1978) 4 i 18 Testimony of Gerald E. Fisher, Supervisor, Albemarle County, Va., before the House Agriculture Committee, May 17,1979 i ! 19 Untaxing Open Space: An Evaluation of the Eredveness of Dgferential Assessment of Farm and Open Space, by John C. Keene, Esq. U.S. Government Printing Office (Washington: 1976) 20 Where Have the Farmlands Gone?, by Shirley F. Fields, National Agricultural Lands Study, Council on Environmental Quality (Washington: 1979) e 21 The Woridwide Loss of Cropland, by Lester R. Brown, orldwatch Institute (Washington: 1978) Materials on Specific Preservation Programs 22 Agricultural Land Preservation in Blue Earth County, Minnesota, by the Citizens Advisory Committee on Agricultural Land Preservation (Mankato, Minnesota: 1976) 23 Agriculture Preservation: A Strategy.for Chester Count-v, Chester County Planning Commission (1979) 24 Agricultural Zoning in Black Hawk County, by Janice M. Clark, Zoning Administrator (Waterloo, Iowa: 1978) 25 Preserving Farmland on Long Island, by John V.N. Klein, Suffolk County Executive, in Environmental Comment, Urban Land Institute (Washington: January, 1978) 26 Report 1976, by the Work Force for the Preservation of Howard County Farmland (Ellicott City, Maryland: 1976) 27 Rural Valley Lands Pian, Tulare County Planning Commission (1975) 28 Wisconsin's Farmland Preservation Program, by Richard Barrows, University of Wisconsin-Extension (Madison: 1978) This booklet was written and produced by the Agricultural Lands Project of the National Association of Counties Research Foundation. The project exists to educate the public about the loss of farmland in the United States and to assist public officials and others in developing programs for farmland preservation. To obtain additional copies of this booklet, or to receive a copy of a brochure describing the services offered by the Agricultural Lands Project, write to: National Association of Counties Research Foundation, 173.5 New York Avenue, N.W. Washington, D.C. 20006. permission from the Agricultural Lands Project of NACoRF. Any part of this booklet may be reproduced or quoted without seeking 18 s END OF PREVIOUS DOCUMENT. ANOTHER DOCUMENT FOLLOWS GRAZING . I I1 DRY LAND GRAIN PRODUCING AREAS A*!-&!+ t 1. H I ! i I j t VEGETABLE CROP GROWING AREAS r t STRAWBERRY GROWING LOCATIONS 1 I I I I I ! i I . . .. .. CI 1.U 8 . .. GREENHOUSE PRODUCTION OF FLORAL & FOLIAGE CROPS P 4 n 0 'CITRUS PRODUCING AREAS EGG PACKING LOCATIONS 1.41 I -1 BEANS, DRY EDIBLE LIFlAS c , I 'I * 2 -m= NATURAL RESOURCES TITLE 14 1 011. STATE POLICY. The Legislature has declared that it is to: ain a high-quality environment now and all action necessary to protect, rehabilitate, and enhance the environmental quality of the State. (b) Take all action necessary to provide the people of this State with clean air and water, enjoyment of aesthetic, natural, scenic, and historic environmental qualities, and freedom from excessive noise. (c) Prevent the elimination of fish or wildlife species due to man's activities, insure that fish and wildlife populations do not drop below self-perpetuating levels, and preserve for future generations representations of all plant and animal corn- rY * $# n and nature can exist in productive harmony to fulfill the social and economic requirements of present and future generations. (f) Require governmental agencies at all levels to develop stand- ards and procedures necessary to protect environmental quality. (g) Require governmental agencies at all levels to consider qualitative factors as well as economic and technical factors and long-term benefits and costs, in addition to short-term benefits and costs and to consider alternatives to proposed actions affecting the environment. c l5Oll.5. ADDITIONAL POLICIES. The courts of this State have found the foming policies to be implicit in CEQA: (a) The EIR requirement is the heart of CEQA. (County of Inyo v. Yorty, 32 Cal. App. 3d 795.) (b) The EIR serves not only to protect the environment but also to demonstrate to the public that it is being protected. (County of Inyo v. Yorty, 32 Cal. App. 3d 795.) (c) The EIR is to .inform other governmental agencies and the public generally of the environmental Impact of a proposed project. (No Oil, Inc. v. City of Los Angeles, 13 C. 3d 68.) (d) The EIR is to demonstrate to an apprehensive citizenry that the agency has in fact analyzed and considered the ecological implications of its action. (People ex rel. Depart- ment of Public Works v. Bosio, 47 Cal. App. 3d 495.) (e) The EIR process will enable the public to determine the environmental and economic values of their elected and appointed officials thus allowing for appropriate action come election day should a majority of the voters disagree. (People v. County of Kern, 39 Cal. App. 3d 830. ) afford the fullest possible protection to the environment within the reasonable scope of the statutory language. (Friends of Mammoth Y. Board of Supervisors, 8 C. 3d 247.) (f) CEQA was intended to be interpreted in such manner as to 1501 1.6. AddiXianat secXiar. to be added. ** Ptrapased Novembeh 12, 1976 amendmenth atttached. h TITLE 14 NATURAL RESOURCES l5 c are essentially the same in terms of environmental impact. Further, the Lead Agency may use an earlier EIR prepared in con- nection with an earlier project to apply to a later project, if the circumstances of the projects are essentially the same. Lead Agencies may elect to write EIRs in advance for entire programs or regulations, in order to be prepared for project applications to come. Whenever an agency chooses to utilize any of these alternatives, however, it must find that the environmental effects of the projects are similar enough to warrant the same treatment in an EIR and that the EIR will adequately cover the impacts of any single project. If these tests are not met, an agency should supplement the EIR it prepares for a program to apply it to an individual project. 15068.5. USE OF A GENXRAL PLAN EIR WITH SUBSF,QUENT PROJECTS. e EIR on a general plan may be used as the foundation document r EIRs subsequently prepared for specific projects within the ographic area covered by the general plan. The subsequent EIRs y reference and summarize material in the EIR on the general an for the description of the general environmental setting and much of the description of the environmental impacts a8 applies the specific project. Detailed information in the EIR on the ecific project may be limited to a description of the project, e specific environmental setting and those impacts which are t adequately described for the specific project in the EIR on c e general plan. khen a subsequent EIR refers to an EIR on the neral plan for part of its description of the environment and e environmental impacts, copies of the EIR on the general plan all be made available to the public in a number of locations in community and to any clearinghouses which will assist in lic review of the EIR. The purpose of this section is not to trict analysis of environmental issues but is to avoid the cessity for repeating detail from a General Plan EIR. 15069. MULTIPLE AND PHASED PROJECTS. Where individual projects are, or a phased project is, to be undertaken and where the total undertaking comprises a project with significant environmental effect, the Lead Agency must prepare a single EIR for the ultimate project. Where an individual project is a necessary precedent for action on a larger project, or commits the Lead Agency to a larger project, with significant environmental effect, an EIR must address itself to the scope of the Larger project. Where one project is one of several similar projects of a public agency, but is not deemed a part of a larger undertaking or a larger project, the agency may prepare one EIR for all projects, or one for each project, but shall in either case comment upon the cumulative effect. 15069.5. STAGED EXR. (a) Where a large capital project will require a number of discretionary approvals from governmental agencies and one of the c approvals will occur more than two years before construction will Pages 16 and 17 are missing. NATURAL RESOURCES TITLE 14 analysis of its own laws, and each public agency should make such determination either as a part of its implementing regulations or on a.case-by-case basis. (P.R.C. 21080(b)). (b) In the absense of any discretionary provision contained in the relevant local ordinance, it shall. be presumed that the following actions are ministerial: I I$/ Issuance of building permits. Issuance of business licenses. Approval of final subdivision maps. Approval of individual utility service connections and disconnections. or ordinances, provide an identification or itemization of its projects and actions which are deemed ministerial under the appli- cable laws and ordinances. (d) Where a project involves an approval that contains elements of both a ministerial action and a discretionary action, the project will be deemed to be discretionary and will be subject to the requirements of CEQA. (c) Each public agency should, in its implementing regulations 15074. NOTICE OF EXEMPTION. (a) When a public agency determines that a project is exempt from the requirements of CEQA because it is an emergency project, a ministerial project or categorically exempt, and the public agency approves or determines to carry out the project, it may f"lr_le a notice of exemption. Such a notice shall include: A brief description of the project. A finding that the project is exempt, including a (3) A Brief statement of reasons to support the findings. citation to the State Guidelines section under which its found to be exempt. (b) Whenever a public agency approves an applicant's project, it or the applicant may file a notice of exemption. The notice of exemption filed by an applicant shall contain the information required in Subdivision (a) above, together with a certified document issued by the public agency stating that it has found the project to be exempt. This may be a certified copy of an existing document or record of the public agency. (c) If the public agency is a state agency, the notice of exemption will be filed with the Secretary for Resources. A form for this notice is provided in Appendix E. Copies of all such notices shall be posted on a weekly basis at the Resources Building Information Desk, 1416 Ninth Street, Sacramento, CA. Each such list will remain posted for 30 days. (d) If the public agency is a local agency, the notice of exemption will be filed with the county clerk of the county or counties in which the project will be located. Copies of all such notices will be available for public inspection and a list of such notices shall be posted on a weekly basis in the TITUE 14 NATURAL RESOURCES office of the county clerk. Each such list shall remain posted for a period of 30 days. 15075. USE OF REGISTERED PROFESSIONALS IN PREPARING EIRS. (a> A number of statutes provide that certain professional services can be provided to the public only by individuals who have been registered by a registration board established under California law. Such statutory restrictions apply to a number of professions including but not limited to engineering, land surveying, forestry, geology, and geophysics. Lead Agency should establish requirements or conditions on or enhance the environment. State statutes may provide that only registered professionals can prepare technical studies which will be used in or which will control the detailed design, construction, or operation of the proposed project and which will be prepared in support of an EIR. . project design, construction, or operation in order to protect, Articles 7. Evaluating Projects 15080. INITIAL STUDY. . (a) If a pro.-ject is subject to the requirements of CEQA and not bxempted- by- these guidelines, the Lead Agency shall conduct an initial study to determine if the project may have a signifi- cant effect on the environment unless the Lead Agency can . determine that the project will clearly have a significant effect. h -a7 - 20 NATURAL RESOURCES TITLE 14 If any aspects of the project, either individually or cumu- latively, may cause a significant effect on the environment, regardless of whether the overall effect of the project is adverse or beneficial, then an EIR must be prepared. All phases 'of project planning, implementation, and operation must be ,considered in the initial study of the project. To meet the requirements of this section, the Lead Agency may use an initial study prepared pursuant to the National Environmental Policy Act. ur oses. The purposes of an initial study are to: Identify environmental impacts. Enable an applicant or Lead Agency to modify a (b) project, mitigating adverse impacts before an EIR is written. significant environmental effects. design of a project. finding in a Negative Declaration that a project will not have a significant effect on the environment. (3) Focus an EIR, if one is required, on potentially (4) Facilitate environmental assessment early in the (5) Provide documentation of the factual basis for the (6) Eliminate unnecessary EIRs. (c) Contents. An initial study shall contain in brief form: 8" A description of the project. An identification of the environmental setting. An identification of environmental effects by use of c a checklist, matrix, or other method. ef'fects identified, if any. with existilig zoning and plans. participated in the initial study. (4) A discussion of ways to mitigate the significant (5) An examination of whether the project is compatible (6) The name of the person or persons who prepared or (1) The initial study shall be used to provide a written (d) Uses. determination of whe'ther a Negative Declaration or an EIR shall be prepared for a project. (2) Where a project is revised in response to an initial study so that potential adverse effects are mitigated to a point where no significant environmental effects' would occur, a Negative Declaration shall be prepared instead of an EIR. If the project would still result in one or more significant effects on the environment after mitigation measures are added to the project, an EIR shall be prepared. (3) The EIR shall emphasize study of the impacts deter- mined to be significant and can omit further examination of those impacts found to be clearly insignificant in the initial study. (e) SubrrAssion of Data. If the project is to be carried out by a prxvate person or private organization, the Lead Agency may require such person or organization to submit data and inf0.r- mation which will enable the Lead Agency to prepare the initial study. TITLE 14 NATURAL RESOURCES 21 (f) Format. Sample forms for an applicant's project descrip- tion and a review form for use by the Lead Agency are contained in Appendices H and I. When used together, these forms would meet the requirements for an initial study, These forms are only suggested, and public agencies are free to devise their own format for an initial study. 15081. DETERMINING SIGNIFICANT EFFECT. (a) The determination of whether a project may have a signi- ficant effect on the environment calls for careful judgment on the part of the public agency involved, based to the extent possible on scientific and factual data, An iron clad deflni- tion of significant effect is not possible because the significance of an activity may vary with the setting. For b example, an activity which may not be significant in an urban area may be significant in a rural area. There may be a dif- ference of opinion on whether a particular effect should be considered adverse or beneficial, but where there is, or anticipated to be, a substantial body of opinion that considers or will consider the effect to be adverse, the Lead Agency should prepare an EIR to explore the environmental effects involved . of a project, the Lead Agency shall consider both primary or direct and secondary or indirect consequences. Primary con- sequences are immediately related to the project (the construc- tion of a new treatment plant may facilitate population growth in a particular area), while secondary consequences are related more to primary consequences than to the project itself (an impact upon the resource base, including land, air, water, and enery use of the area b question may result from the population growth). (c) Some examples of consequences which may be deemed to be a significant effect on the environment are contained in Appendix G. be found to have a significant effect on the environment if: (b) In evaluating the significance of the environmental effect c 15082. MANDATORY FINDINGS OF SIGNIFICANCE. A project shall The project has the potential to degrade the quality of vironment, substantially reduce the habitat of a fish and wildlife species, cause a fish or wildlife population to drop below self-sustaining levels, threaten to eliminate a plant or animal community, reduce the number or restrict the range of a r endangered plant or animal or eliminate important es of the major periods of California history or prehistory. mental goals to the disadvantage of long-term environ- The project has the potential to achieve short-term goals The project has possible environmental effects which are individually limited but cumulatively considerable. As used in c 22 NATURAL RESOURCES ( TITLE 14 the subsection, "cumulatively considerable" means that the incre- mental effects of an individual project are considerable when viewed in connection with the effects of past projects, the effects of other current projects, and the effects of probable future Dro.iects. 15083. NEGATIVE DECLARATION. (a) General. A Negative Declaration shall be prepared for a project which could potentially have a significant effect on the environment, but which the Lead Agency finds on the basis of an initial study will not have a significant effect on the environment. the Lead Agency shall consult with all responsible agencies pursuant to Section 15066. (b) Consultation. Before completing a Negative Declaration, (c) Contents. A Negative Declaration shall include: Ombrief description of the project; including a (2) The location of the project and the name of the (3) A finding that the project will not have a (4) An attached copy of the initial study documenting (5) Mitigation measures, if any, included in the project commonly used name for the project if any. project proponent. significant effect on the. environment reasons to support the finding. ' to avoid potentially significant effects. (d) NotLce. ~ -((Notice of the preparation on a Negative Declaration shall be provided to the public within a reasonable period of time prior to final adoption by the public agency of the Negative . Declaration. Notice shall be given to all organizations and individuals who have previously requested such notice and shall also be given by at least one of the following procedures: Sectfon 6061 of the Government Code, by the public agency in a newspaper of general circulation in the area affected by the proposed project. off site in the area.where the project is to be located. to the project. Subsect ioli (1) s?dil not preclude a public agency from providing additional notice by other means if such agency so desires, nor shall the requirements of this section preclude a public agency from providing the public notice required herein at the same time and in the same manner as public notice otherwise required (A) Publication, no fewer times than required by (€3) Posting of notice by the public agency on and (C) Direct mailing to owners of property contiguous (2) The alternatives for providing notice specified in (., - by law for such project. TITLE 14 , NATURAL RESOURCES 23 (e) Public Review. The Negative Declaration shall be made available to the public with sufficient time before the project is approved to provide an opportunity for members of the public to respond to the finding. Special requirements for review of Negative Declarations review are contained in Sections 15161.5, 15162, and 15164. (f) Notice of Determination. (1) After making a decision to carry out or.approve a project for which a Negative Declaration has been prepared, the Lead Agency shall file a Notice of Detennination with a copy of the Negative Declaration attached. (2) The Notice of Determination shall include: (A) The decision of the agency to approve or disapprove the project. (B) The determination of the agency whether the project will have a significant effect on the environment. (C) A statement that no EIR has been prepared pursuant to the provisions of CEQA. (3) If the Lead Agency is a state agency, the Notice of Determination shall be filed with the Secretary for Resources. (4) If the Lead Agency is a local agency, the Notice of Determination shall be filed with the county clerk of the county or counties in which the project will be located. If the project requires discretionary approvals from a state agency, the Notice of Detemination also shall be filed with the Secretary for c Rcsources. . Secretary for Resources or the County Clerk starts a 30 day statute of limitations on court challenges to the approval under CEQA. (P.R.C. 21167(b)). (5) The filing of the Notice of Determination with the 15084, DECISION TO PREPARE AN EIR. (a) If the Lead Agency finds after an initial study that the project may have a significant effect on the environment, the Leady Agency must prepare or cause to be prepared an Environmental Impact Rep0 rt (b) An EIR should be prepared whenever it can be fairly argued on the basis of substantial evidence that the project may have a significant effect on the environment. (c) An EIR should be prepared when there is serious public controversy concerning the environmental effect of a project. Controversy not related to an environmental issue does not require the preparation of an EIR. 15085, EIR PROCESS. The following steps shall be followed (a) General. . When an agency decides that an EIR will be after ,i;he had Agency decides to prepare an EIR. required for a project, it shall follow the procedures contained in this section. formatiLn'specified in Section 15141, 15142, and 15143 of these (b) Early Consultation. 1 Before completing a draft EIR consisting of the in- c. .I c .. i- !. " AREACLIMATES I MARITIME x COASTAL TRANSITIOWL INTERIOR 9 DESISRT MAP I AREACLIMATES I MAQITIME zr .COASTAL DS TRANSITIONAL INTERIOR Y DESCRT ! M Y rp (" END OF PREVIOUS DOCUMENT. ANOTHER DOCUMENT FOLLOWS RENSTElN ,tlr Teil eines grosseren Systems ist, kann mmen Relationen zwischen den einzel- cs somit fur eine bestimmte Kategorie +eitsn-Test gibt, konnen wir dennoch liiquanz dieser Theorien priifen. hsst werden als Systeme partiell inter- , innerhalb eines sich Indernden Rah- h zuverlksig sein; wichtig kt, dass sie citsfrernden Hypothesen basieren. Diese Bczichungen bestimmter Problemkreise oKh, dass sie wenigstens soweit zusam- irtd, Diagnosen bestimmter Probleme zu nahmen formulieren konnen. Wir durfen 1 gultig sind, doch konnen sie immerhin riiber Auskunft geben kcnnen, in welcher lt. SV.\If. bptitude B permettre des pronostics semble sont souvent dtpoumes de cette qualite. e derive pas du fait, que la science nous rxpkrience. Sptcialement pour les theories , ce test est inapplicable. Pour cette raison, ger une theorie comme correcte ou incor- t' le phenomtne, qu'une thtorie essaie d'ex- ci systtme, il est impossible de determiner Bien qu'il n'existe pas un seul test compe- hiories, nous pouvons quand-mtme juger c d'un nombre de considerations. vcnt &re considertes comme des systtmes :t.s operant dans un environnement chan- ~ croyables; il est important, qu'elles soient hypothbes non vCrifiables. Ces relations couvrir des relations specifiques dans des I mZme temps esptrer qu'elles soient lite I. ttre capables de poser des diagnostics sur .der des mesures correctives. Nous ne ~OU- ne portke universelle, mais qu'elles operent per frequemment la direction de la cor- *. -. . - ' .. . ... . . . . .. . THE TYRANNY OF SMALL DECISIONS: MARKET FAILURES, IMPERFECTIONS, AND THE LIMITS OF ECONOMICS* The perennial problem of the appropriate role ofgovernment in eco- nomic life has been subjected to increasingly intense consideration by American economists in recent years, as part ofthe active political controversy over the proper balance of resource allocation between 'private wants and public needs". In particular, strenuous efforts havc bcen made on the one hand to identify and analyze defects in tlw rcsource allocation effected by an unregulated market, such as might be rcmedied by government intervention; and, on the other, to clrvisc economic criteria for allocating resources, alternatively, via ~c~t.rrrlrIIcnt spendingz. The present essay falls in the former cate- Rwy: it defines and analyzes a particular inherent characteristic of thc markct, not to my knowledge hitherto identified as such, that is capable under certain circumstances ofproducing a defective or pos- ublp objectionable allocational result. 23 . ALFRED E. KAHN The short- and long-run determinations by business men are gov- erned by decisions of customers involving a corresponding range in size and time-perspective-to buy a single candy bar, a camping trip, an automobile, a house, or to enter a rental contract of short or long duration. Still, the 'size' or importance of the individual choices by customers is typically less than of those made by the business man, so that each of the latter's decisions reflects a prospective adding up of the consequences of a large number of customer actions taking place over a period of time. A critical task in appraising the allocative efficiency of such an economy, then, is to determine whether and under what conditions the total effect of these small decisions will be optimal. The 'tyranny of small decisions' suggests that it may not be, mereb because the decisive determinations are individually too 'small', in the sensc above indicated. It suggests that if one hundred consumers choosc option x, and this causes the market to make decision X (where X equals 100 x), it is not necessarily true that those same consumers would have voted for that outcome if that large decision had ever been presented for their explicit consideration. If this is true, the con- sumer can be victimized by the narrowness of the contexts in which he exercises his sovereignty. Now, welfare economists have long ago exposed various reasons why indeed these individual decisions may not add up to a collectivc micro-economic optimum. These reasons fall essentially into two categories: (a) market imperfections and (b) market failures. The significance of imperfections of competition is obvious: if even the individual choices are short of optimal, because, Iet us say, of con- sumer ignorance or monopoly, there is no reason to expect their total to be optimal. As for (b), it is by now commonplace that even per- fectly competitive markets may fail to achieve Pareto-optimal results in the presence of such phenomena as externalities (economies or diseconomies, unpaid social costs, privately inappropriable social benefits) or internally increasing returns (when a price equated to marginal cost, as the Pareto optimum would require, will not be adequately remunerative to a private entrepreneur)s. In addition, economists have long recognized the possibility of objections to con- 3. See, c.g., BATOR, 'The Anatomy of Market Failure', Quurterb Journal .f Economics, LXXII (August 1958), pp.351-79. 24 sumcr st possil with the PARETO dtcmcd The thii list wmctir the def that it of thost in whic I>?;cd i catrgo conscq capab' But dccisic It see1 morc sccnrs hki I posit dccisi Of CiT Of COR > E. KAHN kinations by business men are gov- involving a corresponding range in y a single candy bar, a camping trip, ;er a rental contract of short or long Irtance of the individual choices by If those made by the business man, ms reflects a prospective adding up number of customer actions taking the allocative efficiency of such an whether and under what conditions isions will be optimal. The 'tyranny t it may not be, merely because the lividually too 'small', in the sense tt if one hundred consumers choosc mket to make decision X (where X ily true that those same consumers ome if that large decision had ever consideration. If this is true, the con- Cuness of the contexts in which he exercises Je long ago exposed various reasons isions may not add up to a collective :se reasons fall essentially into tv.0 ztions and (b) market failures. The competition is obvious: if even the optimal, because, let us say, of con- here is no reason to expect their total ,)I now commonplace that even per- '41 to achieve Pareto-optimal results ma as externalities (economies or ts, privately inappropriable social ; returns (when a price equated to )timum would require, will not be rivate entrepreneur)s. In addition, .I the possibility of objections to con- :ny of Market Failure', Quarterly Journal of I. 35 1-79. THE TYRANNY OF SMALL DECISIONS lunrer sovereignty itself, on 'non-economic' grounds. This category dpossible objections to the functioning of the market, in contrast with thc first two, questions or rejects the value judgments underlying PARETO'S definition of optimality, and raises considerations generally dccnlcd to lie outside the particular competence of economics. The 'tyranny ofsmall decisions' does not add a fourth category to this list. As the ensuing discussion will show, its manifestations fall lometimes in one, sometimes in another of the familiar three; and the defect of, or possible basis for objection to, the private market that it identifies can in principle be conceived of in one or another of those familiar terms. Thus Part 11, below, will consider situations in which it may cause authentic market failure. The problems ana- ipcd in Parts 111-Y will prove to involve mixtures of all three Categorics: sometimes the real culprit proves to be an imperfection of colllpetition; sometimes what seem to be involved are dynamic COtlSrquences of the market that welfare economics is simply in- ca@h of appraising. But in all instances, I believe, the 'smallness' of the governing dtciJions is in one way or another an additional explanatory element. It WCms in some instances to illuminate the problem better than the familiar market failures or imperfections; and it sometimes *cnu to have the virtue of more clearly suggesting the necessity of bking at the process in broader terms than does the market, and pclssibly substituting a 'large' for a piecemeal accumulation of 'small' dehions, if the results of the market are to be intelligently appraised Ot Cffcctively improved. If. The phenomenon as an instance of market failure Ih cwnt that first suggested the phenomenon to this writer was the dhppcarance ofpassenger railroad service from Ithaca, a small and c*mPGdvely isolated (since that time even more SO!) community in upstate New York. It may be assumed the service was withdrawn ~PUC over a long enough period of time the individual decisions bavCllcrs made, for each of their projected trips into and Out of ?&GI and the other cities served, did not provide the railroads total revenue to cover incremental costs (defined over the -C Wiod). Considering the comparative comforts and speeds of 25 I . ALFRED E. KAHN competing media, those individual decisions were by no means ir- rational: the railroad was slow and uncomfortable. What reason, then, was there to question the aggregate effect of those individual choices-withdrawal of the service? The fact is thc railroad provided the one reliable means of getting into and out of Ithaca in all kinds of weather; and this insufficiently-exerted option, this inadequately-used alternative was something I for one would have been willing to pay something to have kept alive. This way of looking at the result suggests a simple, though unfortunately subjcc- tive and hence not necessarily practical, test of whether the rail- road's closing was economically correct: let each traveller or po- tential traveller have asked himself4 how much he would have been willing to pledge regularly over some time period, say annually, by purchase of prepaid tickets, to keep rail passenger service in Ithaca. . So long as the amount he would have declared (to himself) would have exceeded what he actually paid in that period-and my own introspective experiment shows it would-then to that extent thc disappearance of passenger service from Ithaca was an incident of market failure. The cause of the failure was the discrepancy between the time perspective of the choices I was given an opportunity to make- deciding, each time I planned to travel, whether or not to go by train-and the relevant decision of the railroad, which was a long- run, virtually all-or-nothing and once-for-all decision, to retain or abandon passenger service. When each traveller or potential traveller chose between the local airline, his own automobile, and the rail- road, his individual choice had an only negligible effect on the con- tinued availability of the latter; it would therefore have been ir- rational for him to consider this possible implication of his decisiorl. 4. If instead he had been asked by someone else--say the raiIroad company- he might not have answered honestly. This is because the mere availability of rail- road service to a community is what PAUL A. SAMUELSON has termed a public good : so long as the railroad remains, it costs nothing additional to keep it available for B as well as A; and as long as it is available to A, it is automatically available also to B. This is the kind of situation in which each person approached to con- tribute to its continued availability is under systematic temptation to understate the intensity of his demand, in hope that the pledges of others will suffice to preserve the option for him anyhow. 'The Pure Theory of Public Expenditure', Review of Economics andStatirtics, XXXVI (November 1954), pp.388-9. 26 i . IN ssions were by no means ir- omfortable. :,tion the aggregate effect of r the service? The fact is the 1s of getting into and out of nsufficiently-exerted option, something I for one would have kept alive. This way of hough unfortunately subjec- al, test of whether the rail- ct: let each traveller or po- #W much he would have been ime period, say annually, by I passenger service in Ithaca. declared (to himself) would in that period-and my own uld-then to that extent the jrn Ithaca was an incident of Liscrepancy between the time n an opportunity to make- <vel, whether or not to go by .\e railroad, which was a long- e-for-all decision, to retain or traveller or potential traveller >wn automobile, and the rail- ,ly negligible effect on the con- Nould therefore have been ir- Sle implication of his decision. : else-say the railroad company- because the mere availadiliy of rail- A. SAMIJEL~~N has termed a public othing additional to keep it available ,le to A, it is automatically available :lich each person approached to con- r systematic temptation to understate the pledges of others will suffice to Pure Theory of Public Expenditure', November 1954), pp.388-9. THE TYRANNY OF SMALL DECISIONS 'rlIr ract remains that each selection ofx overy constitutes also a vote Tor eliminating the possibility thereafter of choosing y; if enough pplc Vote for x, each time necessan'ly on the msumption thaty will continue, f may in fact disappear. And its disappearance may constitute a pnllinc &privation, that customers might willingly have paid some- thing to avoid. The only choice the market offered us travellers to influcncc the longer-run decision of the railroad was thus shorter in iu timc pcrspcctive, and the sum-total of our individual purchases of railroad tickets necessarily added up to a smaller amount, than our actual combined interest in the continued availability of rail service. \Vc wtc victims of the tyranny of small decisions. ' But if most of the travellers who felt a sense ofloss at the railroad's dcrnisc had in fact patronized it, though infrequently, when it was still available, could not the railroad company have tested their tvduntion of its continuation in service by charging them higher Tkcs than it did on those few occasions? It might have tried, and to Some extcnt succeeded: apart from administrative and regulatory Inconveniences, railroads could for example charge higher passenger on rainy days, when the airplanes are grounded, or in the wjntcr, and in this fashion appropriate a share of the consumers' lu~hs dcrivcd from their continued availability for just such emer- tpcid. But such a policy could not escape the basic difficuIty. At tXl1 such time, the individual traveller would still be deciding whrthcr or not to pay the higher price on the basis of the costs, pains Wd hncfit, facing him in thatparticular instance. The higher fare might Caw him simpIy to postpone his trip. He would still have no oppor- tunity to express or convey to the railroad-and, on the contrary, %Quid still have an incentive to conceal-his full appraisal of the ''pl~c to him of having the service available at all times. As ha already been suggested, this instance of the tyranny of small ckcijiOns can be conceived in more familiar terms. As has frequently kn noted, when some of the economic effects of individual trans- &tiom do not enter into the calculations of the transacting parties, effect of individual optimizing decisions may fall short of a fotlectivc optimum. The essential flaw is precisely the one empha- ' Oa Of the difficulties, see BURTON A. WEISBROD, 'Collective-Con- awion swica of Individual Consumption Goods', Quarfcrly JOUT~ of h- urLt, WvIII (August 1964), pp.475-6. . ALFRED E. KAHN sized here : the individual transaction is 'too small' if it has external, unconsidered effects. Conversely, if, as in the present instance, thc larger result, representing a summation of smaller decisions, is not optimal, it must mean that the component transactions involved ex- ternal economies or diseconomies. The specific externality involved here has been very clearly iden- tified by BURTON A. WEISBROD~. WEISBROD'S argument concerns thr possible failure of the market to provide services part of the demand for which is the desire of potential customers to keep open the pos- sibility or option of enjoying them, when (a) the option is not (or not always) in fact exercised, (b) revenues from actual purchasers are or become insufficient to cover the costs of continued operation, and (c) 'expansion or recommencement of production at the time [in the I future] when occasional purchasers wish to make a purchase ... [is] difficult or impossible". As WEISBROD points out, provision of the option to non-users is a costless (external) byproduct of supplying actual users; underallocation of resources to this endeavor occurs only when condition (b) prevails. So the external benefit in our ex- ample is the mere availability of the service to non-users, the con- tinued ability to satisfy as-yet unexerted 'option demand', as he terms its. The concept of externalities is however in some situations inade- quately descriptive of what we have in mind here. Thus, it has not until WEISBROD (to my knowledge) suggested to economists the tend- ency of the market to underrate option demand. While MILTON FRIEDMAN recognizes that because of their great 'neighborhood ef- fects' city parks would be supplied in inadequate quantities by the private market alone, he rejects this case for governmental initiative in the provision of national parks. Surely, he reasons, the only people benefitted by the latter are those who actually travel to them : distant, 6. Op. d., pp. 471-7. 7. Ibid., p. 474. 8. The simplest case of the WEISBROD phenomenon is where the option demand is not exercised at all during the period over which revenues must cover cost if service is to be continued. But, as he recognizes (op.cif., p.476) and our foregoing discussion demonstrates, the problem may arise also if the option demand merely exercised infrequently-insufficiently for the revenues from usem on the one hand to cover costs, on the other hand fully to reflect consumers' aggregate evaluation of the continued availability of the service. 28 i :N too small’ if it has external, n the present instance, thc of smaller decisions, is not nt transactions involved ex- has been very clearly iden- ~D’S argument concerns thr services part of the demand :mers to keep open the pos- (a) the option is not (or not from actual purchasers are of continued operation, and +eduction at the time [in the to make a purchase ... [is] ,)oints out, provision of the 131) byproduct of supplying ces to this endeavor occurs e external benefit in our ex- mice to non-users, the con- ted ‘option demand’, as he xr in some situations inade- mind here. Thus, it has not ested to economists the tend- on demand. While MILTON heir great ‘neighborhood ef- nadequate quantities by the e for governmental initiative y, he reasons, the only peoplc l ally travel to them: distant, 1mon is where the option demand rhich revenues must cover cost if (op.cit., p.476) and our foregoing rise also if the option demand 3 for the revenues from users on the .Jly to reflect consumers’ aggregate 2 service. . .. _. ~ ’ _” .. . , .. . . “. ~~. i‘. . . . .. I i.%. $-j ‘ “. THE TYRANNY OF SMALL DECISIONS UnsrCrl parks can generate no external benefits. Why not then leave k to the market to ascertain by a system of user charges to what (xtcnt the users or potential users are willing to pay the opportunity cats ofproviding these servicesD? The point is, however, that there arc other, economically interested parties who would not be con- srrjtrd in this determination-the people who may never travel to OIC parks yet for whatever reason derive satisfaction from their availa- bility, and who would feel a loss if they were to disappear. The wilderness is a particularly apt example, because it most clearly mnrrts the irreversibility requirement, (c), above: once ‘production’ has ccnscd it cannot ever be resumed! ,Sa in our railroad example: externalities are usually understood fo rcfcr to the effects of a transaction on other parties, or on the transactors in other roles. In the present situation it is in large mrxurc the interests of the same parties, railroad passengers as such, that arc inadequately considered. The offenders are also the un- kitring-ar, if witting, none the less helpless--victims. One might orcotlnc still maintain that the potential rail passenger on a wintry might when planes are grounded is in economic terms a different Pmfl than the one who decides to take the plane on a sunny June day. Thc effect of the latter’s decision on his own welfare in the former 6tWion is an authentic externality. But it has a special character. \vhcrcas it would never pay the individual that imposes external on othcrs to alter his course of conduct unless compelled or b&dl’ to do so, it would pay travellers and commuters to take into ’ WCOUnt, and be influenced in their travel choices by, the ‘external’ tacct-on thcrnselves-of their combined actions, if only the market ga’c them the opportunity. III. Invention as the mofher of necessity % Philosopher Moms R. COHEN, I have been told, used to chal- kqc his Classes with something like the following question: ‘Sup- -, WentY-fivc years ago, some being from outer space had made ‘,*X+>* L? thii ’ Proposition: “I know how to make a means of transportation 29 & d" - . ." "_ - ." " ". ~ . .- .. A L X" .. . . . ALFRED E. KAHN c that could in effect put 200 horses at the disposal of each of you. It would permit you to travel about, alone or in small groups, at 60 to 80 miles an hour. I offer you this knowledge; the price is 40,000 lives per year.'' Would we have accepted?' If there is a possibility WL' might have refused the offer, thus presented-a 'big' decision-then our having reached the same result gradually, unwittingly, by a series ofindividual purchases could represent a product ofthe tyranny of small decisions. It may be instructive to sift out the various pos- sible reasons why, or criteria according to which, the market may not have produced optimal results in this historical process. First, who are the 'we' in this experiment? The way in which the question is posed would seem to require some sort of collective de- termination, ending in a simple 'yes' or 'no' response, rather than- as the market does it-x yeses andy nos, perhaps at the cost of an equivalent proportion of 40,000 lives. If one feels 'we' as a collec- tivity-rather than as a simple aggregation of separate individuals- would have been better off had we had the opportunity to make the ('big') decision, politically, on an all-or-none basis, one may, of course, be simply rejecting the standards of welfare economics. This view, while defensible, is one about which the economist has com- paratively little to say. But perhaps the implication is, instead, that individual ConsumeS may have made the wrong decisions, in the sense that at least some of them would have decided otherwise had they known the risks. Then we have a simple case of market imperfection-inadequate knowledge. This interpretation would be valid, of course; only if the risks (and other costs) were costs to the motorist alone. To the extent that the decision of X to buy a car increases the risks of injury Or lung cancer to Y, whether or not Y buys a car, we have an external cost and genuine market failure, though of a familiar kind, and not particularly reflective of the tyranny of small decisions*'. The spread of the automobile takes on the peculiar quality of the phenomenon expounded here if, as well may be the case, there is some threshold level oftraffic density or air pollution below which there are no such risks, or beyond which these external costs mount di5- proportionately with subsequent individual purchases. It then takes 11. Except in the special sense, already suggested, that any decision from con- sideration of which external costs are excluded is ipso facto too 'small'. 30 . KAHN at the disposal of each of you. It done or in small groups, at 60 to owledge; the price is 40,000 lives ed?' If there is a possibility wc $resented-a 'big' decision-then Ilt gradually, unwittingly, by a mepresent a product ofthe tyranny ictive to sift out the various pos- t-ding to which, the market may in this historical process. periment? The way in which thc :quire some sort of collective de- s' or 'no' response, rather than- I y nos, perhaps at the cost of an 'ves. If one feels 'we' as a collec- rcgation of separate individuals- had the opportunity to make the I all-or-none basis, one may, of idards of welfare economics. This it which the economist has corn- nstead, that individual consumen tis, in the sense that at least some 5rwise had they known the risks. iiarket imperfection-inadequate iuld be valid, of course, only if the I the motorist alone. To the extent nr increases the risks of injury Or ybuys a car, we have an external sough of a familiar kind, and not iy of small decisions". kes on the peculiar quality of thC s well may be the case, there 3 )r air pollution below which thefl h these external costs mount dis- ndividual purchases. It then take ily suggested, that any decision from con* cluded is ipso fucfo too 'small'. 9 4: 2. . THE TYRANNY OF SMALL DECISIONS 8 cumulation of small, i. lividually riskless or comparatively riskless &itions to the autom le population to develop a major external mi. Any possible conse,.ient market failure would still be the result d the externality, however: if the interests of all affected parties, ptptrators and potential victims together, were to be consulted in tach consccutive small decision, the sharply mounting social costs of CCqwcutive automobile purchases would be adequately reflected in tbt price, and no market failure need occur. Oiic moves beyond the familiar externalities, however, when one tt~t~ tfic cumulative effects of individual purchase decisions on the Wructurc of consumer wants themselves. PIGOU long ago identified en\.). an external cost of consumption, and saw that it was a pos- dbk source of market failure. r may want a car merely because x ant1 .( have purchased one; and 5 may then want a newer model huse B has one. But such externalities are not confined to envy, h 'Jrrnonst ration effect', or vicarious or altruistic pleasure12. rmay have a car because more and more of his friends are enabled b thc cars they have purchased to live on the outskirts of town, and bC to be able to continue visiting his friends; or because p@cV stores have moved to shopping centers; or he may feel im- Plkd to move to the suburbs himself because now the schools are ktkt than in town. Invention, VEBLEN noted, is the mother of wwit).. And the process is gradual and cumulative: it takes the "coy3Qg ofnlore than one friend or one grocery store to require the woncd r to move too and fall victim to the garage-man and the *mhr who charges portal-to-portal; and 2"s move adds its small patr 40 the pressure on W. So what we have is a situation in which kria of apparently free, individually welfare-maximizing purchase dcritioma made in the context of a given way of life and given 'lffQti% has such a cumulative effect on those parameters that 'Ulrbtyucnt choices can no longer be made in the same atmosphere mkrruy a well as figuratively: the very atmosphere in town is pol- ktd can). In a real sense the decision is less free than it was. * * invCntion has bred a need; and to the cumulative process of ' 42% 9% +- needs and then satisfying them one can not apply the C 31 . -i . ! I i " I ALFRED E. KAHN t traditional welfare-maximization criteria constructed on the basis ri the assumption that that economy serves best that best satisfies wvnr~!l that are given and unchanging-or, if changing, that change untl~l influences exogenous to the economic system that satisfies them's. I! would seem we have two distinct phenomena here: one, markr: failure, within the criteria ofwelfare economics; and second, a chansr in tastes that welfare economics is incapable of adjudging14. The process of converting inventions into necessities by changittx the parameters of individual choice consists in part in the setting ir. motion of a gradual but cumulative and irreversible (or reversiblr only at great threshold cost) destruction of alternatives. The rise of . the automobile gradually undermined the profitability of the pas- - senger (and commuter) railroads, making it progressively more difli- cult for the latter to attract either capital or enterprising managrn The comfort and convenience of rail service therefore deteriorntd. both absolutely and relative to emerging alternatives. This in tur:! made it progressively more rational to prefer the latter, and thcsr choices in turn gave another twist to the screw. (This process is f.ir 13. See JOHN MAURICE CLARK, Economic Znstitutions and Human Wevare (Nc* York, Knopf, 1957), Chapters 2-3, and pp. 113-14; also his Competition US * Dynamic Process (Washington, Brookings, 1961), pp. 38-9; and MOSES ABR.*~(~ VITZ, 'The Welfare Interpretation of Secular Trends in National Income and Prcduct', in 77~ Allocalion .f Economu Resources (Stanford, Stanford Unived? Press, 1959), pp. 13-21. extent the other. WEISBROD has suggested to me the desirability of distinguishin5 'the aggregate effects of a large number of independent decisions in a static sefl from the final effects of a series of decisions taken through time', his point bcivl that the clearest case of market failure 'would be one in which time was irrelev3n' and yet the simultaneous and independent decisions ofa large number ofdecision' makers produced consequences which they, as a group, would vote (with dolhfi' to undo'. The processes described in Part ZZ meet this test: though as a matter historical fact they may work themselves out over time, they are not dynamic in the economic sense; they do not require changes in taste or technology or sed decisions for them to produce their poor result. The present instance is obviously more complicated. It involves change in taste, in wants, and information. The fact remains that to some extent the than@ in T's 'wants' were the external consequences of Z's actions; to that extent, para. doxically, though a change in tastes is involved, the phenomenon is authenticall!' static. 14. I am not able to discern to what extent precisely it is the one, to what . 32 1 i 1 .. ".* B~S into necessities by changing onsists in part in the setting in and irreversible (or reversiblt Eon of alternatives. The rise of d the profitability of the pas- iing it progressively more difi- lital or enterprising managers. service therefore deteriorated, :ing alternatives. This in turn .O prefer the latter, and thcsc the screw. (This process is far htilutionr and Human Weware (Ne\,* 1.113-14; also his Competition as a I), pp. 38-9; and MOSES ABRAMO- r Trends in National Income and 'res (Stanford, Stanford University :nt precisely it is the one, to what IC' .'le desirability of distinguishing e; xdent decisions in a static sense !+ i through time', his point beins xt' one.in which time was irrelevant ions of a large number ofdecision- group, would vote (with dollan) t this test: though as a matter of er time, they are not dynamic in :S in taste or technology or serial :Iplicated. It involves changes in 11s that to some extent the change f Z's actions; to that extent, para- , the phenomenon is authentically ~.. . . ? I c b...”” ALFRED E. KAHN IV. Skimming the cream and the destruction of associated services In the transportation field particularly, the argument is often ma& for restrictions on competition, and particularly on entry, that other. wise aggressive competitors would ‘skim the cream’ of the traffic, and in so doing make it impossible for the established, common carricn to continue the less lucrative services-conducting regularly schcd. uled operations in bad seasons as well as good, on thin as well as rid routesl’. A similar case is often made for resale price maintenancc: that unrestricted price competition on popular, fast-moving brands (best-selling books, whiskies, toothpastes or appliances) would drivr out of business the small, conveniently situated, low-volume retailer, the merchandiser who offers service, the diversified book store’*, th neighborhood pharmacist, all of whom, it is alleged, survive in pnrl because of the protected margins on the former items’O. These arguments find an important part of their support in tht fact ofconsumer ignorance and the threat ofdestructive competition. familiar market imperfections, and to this extent do not concern w 17. See e.g., D.PHIL.IP LOCKLIN, Economics of Transfirtation, 5th ed. (Home wood, Irwin, 1960), pp. 702, 820-21 ; DANIEL MARX, Jr., Zntemtionaf Shipp+4 Carfels: A Study of ZndmtrialSelf-Regulation by Shipping Conferences (Princeton, PrhCe ton University Press, 1953), pp.4, 56-7, 187-98. 18. ‘Christmas shoppers wishing to buy J. D. Salinger’s best-seller “Franny and hey” may now buy it for 84 on Fifth Avenue ... and for 162.79 at most big department stores and discount houses. The literary price war in New York h* reached its zenith ... Besides bringing bigger bargains for shoppers ... the corn petition has [hurt] merchants who sell mostly books and cannot fall back 0” revenue from television sets or vacuum cleaners. In fact, such long-establish4 bookstores as Brentano’s, Inc., fear for their existence, according to a spkw man ... “We supply knowledge, stock and book atmosphere”, Theodore Wilcrl’ of the Eighth Street Bookshop, said, although he admitted the shop had suffed some loss of revenue on best-sellers this year. An editor of Publishers’ Weekly Who has made the rounds of discount houses said the other day: “YOU can go in and browse, but you won’t find anything you don’t know about ... Last week I heard one lady ask, “Is this book O.K. for a 9-year-old?” And the clerk answed. “Look, lady, all I know is the list price is $3.50 and our price is 8 1.98”’ ”k Nts rork Times, December 1, 1961, pp.31, 58. fcnancc Re-examined (London, Macmillan, 1960), pp. 51-2, 66-76, for a cogent statement. 19. See P. W. S. ANDREWS and FRANK A.FRIDAY, Fair Trade, Resale Price 34 f .......... I- ..... ”_ “” _. ... -. -_ €I N 3n of associated service$ the argument is often madt 1 icularly on entry, that other. 1 the cream' of the traffic, and stablished, common carrier1 conducting regularly schrd. good, on thin as well as rich )r resale price maintenancc: popular, fast-moving bran& s or appliances) would driw ituated, low-volume retailer, : diversified book store's, thc , it is alleged, survive in part e former items's. part of their support in tht kt ofdestructive competition. his extent do not concern UJ ~ 3z=-;-. ., .~ I.. :- 'i THE TYRANNY OF SMALL DECISIONS j&m, But they also implicitly or explicitly invoke the principle we hen expounding, If unrestricted competition prevailed, it mki bc irrational for each consumer to choose where to make each irldividual purchases on any basis except price and convenience, rwJ, whcrc these considerations so dictated, to buy his toothpaste 4d hhiskcy at the supermarket, his best sellers at a discount by mail, fi xppliances from the discount house, to travel on a non-scheduled &nc if it offered bargain rates during the peak season. His indi- %kh~~l, amdl decision to do otherwise would not in itself make a J)Chifir\nt contribution to keeping the corner drug, book or Iiquor atrc in business, or the off-peak flights on the schedule. And yet the kh! tkt of these individual decisions might be to kill off not only * ft.jrctcd alternative but the auxiliary services it alone provides- IwrU that buyers might, if given the explicit opportunity, have kR Willing to pay something to keep alive. IltC problem can be illuminated, though not resolved, by the WJrbniics orintegration. The drugstore, scheduled airline and mari- &C dlipping conference member are integrated firms, purveying a *uitrY ofproducts or services. There are only two possible effects of hption on the ability of these firms to compete with inter- Or price competitors who confine themselves to skimming the . , .~ .I .Ctsrmat': 35 . . .... . ALFRED E. KAHN It may give them an advantage-in which event, it woLI, rbz unit costs un, &uld go up, , sib1 ? seem' they can make no for protection. The telephone compn, ~~~-~imc rate. , for needs no artificial barriers against the entry ofspecialist firms seekir, ' to take away its apparently more lucrative day-time, long-distan, : telephone business, in order to ensure its continued provision I, night-time service. Its rates for the former would have to be evr: 1 higher than they are were it not also in a position, with the SXI e' equipment, to supply off-peak, night-time service at rates in excc of incremental costs. Indeed, in such a situation it is in a sense in! possible to say which part of the business is the 'cream', which p3r the 'skimmed milk', because the bulk of the costs are common. !C competitor could survive on the cream alone, unless the incumbrr, company is inefficient, or charging extortionate rates, or using I! ' outmoded technology-no one of which reasons constitutes a soci2' justification for limitations on entry. (2) The integration may not confer an advantage in the lucratilr part of the business sufficient to offset the advantages potential trants may enjoy (perhaps because of their enterprise, abilities, vd ume ofoperations, or their particular kind ofintegration22), in whk! event, it would appear, they still deserve no protection. Suppose, fof example, some firm outside the Bell System found a new way I@ transmit long-distance telephone messages using the rays of the sun- i.e., during the day time only-at total unit costs less than currd day-time rates. Would the incumbent company then deserve protW tion against the undermining of those high rates on the ground that otherwise night telephone service would disappear? The correct 3p swer is that no class ofcustomers should be required to pay more than the total cost of serving it alone23. Whether by competition or b! regulation24 the day-time rates should be brought down at least lo fore practiced, these interlopers enter (according to the advocates of pde ~hpwtantpa~tofth ' 'k"br~ rb~ appmpri: tiongrn) or operate as specialists, handling only best sellers, or fat-movi# La rot XKpan' proprietary drugs. f :; 2). Uh or mu 22. See note 21, immediately preceding. f' i, c*r;th, tnpr2rCtion! 23. HARRY GUNNISON BROWN, Principles of Commerce (New York, Macmilbf!, ' d-; Acwb, WC 1916), Part 111, pp. 172-3. p .;+ *Ttu*?9ckcd boo 24. Competition may of course be a wasteful means of bringing about the ,.,jht-cll\g economically proper result. If so, this would be because of market irnperfectionJ/ ; causing excessive entry of new capital, destructive competition, and so on--O'' because of market failure, strictly defined. Thus, central to DANIEL MARX'S SW *,:ark oc)rcr rcn4ccl ,: CU ~dvantngn am '-. ?I. %u: Kf aotc 36 hH N t e-in which event, it would Lion. The telephone company .' ntry of specialist firms seeking ative day-time, long-distance .e its continued provision of mner would have to be evcn in a position, with the samc time service at rates in excess a situation it is in a sense im- less is the 'cream', which part of the costs are common. No n alone, unless the incumbent xtortionate rates, or using an ich reasons constitutes a social ~ an advantage in the lucrati\*r :t the advantages potential cn- f their enterprise, abilities, VOI- kind of inteption"), in which 'rve no protection. Suppose, far ;1 System found a new way to :sages using the rays of the sun- 3tal unit costs less than current ct company then deserve protec- x high rates on the ground that 3uld disappear? The correct an- .11d be required to pay more than Whether by competition or by .!Id be brought down at least tC :ording to the advocates of protfl Ig only best sellers, or fast-mox*i*c ; ofCommerce (New York, Macmilla** I wasteful means of bringing about * Id be because of market imperfections" ' estructive competition, and so on-d 1. Thus, central to DANIEL MARX'S THE TYRANNY OF SMALL DECISIONS &C total unit costs under the new technology. If this requires higher nlght-time rates for the joint service to continue, then night rates &auld go up, possibly to the point where this business covers the bulk of the common costs. The advantages of integration may then nil1 &'ice to keep the old, established telephone company in busi- BCU, perhaps retaining its monopoly-this would be our case (1). they may no longer suffice-our case (2)-in which event night (tkphonic communication is no longer economically feasibIe, and huld disappcar*S. . Thc policy issues here under consideration would seem to involve OR (2) rather than case (1) situations. It is evidently possible with- Out competitive handicap to sell whiskey and not delivery service, @Othp;ute and not the filling of prescriptions, New York to Miami and not New York to Ithaca flights, appliances and not quick re- Wintr. The cream and the skimmed milk are separable; that is why wweyon of both ask to be protected in the former part of their hbncss, In these circumstances, it would seem, competition ought t~ bc allowed to drive the prices of the separable services down, and Wt UJ their respective long-run marginal costs2'. Otherwise, pur- c~~fo of cream are being forced to subsidize devotees of skimmed atilk. .. . -. . ALFRED E. KAHN phone service later regret-that is, experience a sense of loss thr t would willingly have paid something to avoid-the disappearat.,.' of night service that results from these individually rational, snr.:. decisions? To this consideration it would seem a sufficient respow ? in most cases, that the market will ordinarily give customers thc 0;. portunity to keep the skimmed milk flowing. The price will have I rise to a truer reflection ofits opportunity cost, and if enough pntro:: are willing to pay the price it will flow; if they are mt, it ought not8 If prices are not correctly adjusted, we have market imperfcctio:. not market failure. In what circumstances, then, may such an outcome reflect 30. thentic market failure? As WEISBROD suggests, two conditions haw . to be met: (a) it must be infeasible to charge the required price Ls the separate service, and (b) resumption of service, once suspendrd must be difficult (;.e., costly) or impo~sible~~. But these conditioa are rarely absolute; different markets will satisfy them in varyin! degrees. Whether, then, we may have market failure because of thl tyranny of small decisions in bookstores as well as railroads, drug stores or local service airlines as well as national parks, is a questic of fact to be confronted in each situation separately. As for condition (a), for example, it is impossible for public parb to levy charges on patrons who never actually visit them. This is thr extreme case. But even when the option is sometimes exercised, it by preservation of the alternative. We have aIready suggested ~h! this might be so for passenger railroads. Similarly, it may be in- feasible for the well-stocked bookstore to charge for the privilege d 28. It should perhaps be reemphasized that the kind of market failure COW sidered in this essay is not the only possible kind. There may be external benefio even ifsales revenues prove insufficient. sideration in another situation of possible market breakdown, destructive petition. One of the main circumstances in which unrestricted price rivalry m3!' be undesirable is in the presence of temporary excess capacity, where a tendenq for price to be driven to out-of-pocket costs of some producers (and below th@ of others) may cause the dismantling or inadequate maintenance of productisT capacity and going organizations that will in time be needed, and can at such times be reconstituted only at markedly higher cost. 38 i I. i' may be infeasible to collect the entire consumer's surplus generat4 ~ 1 I flowing from a continued provision of service that may justify its continuatic" , 29. Op. cit., p. 476. The reader will recognize the relevance of the second cop 11 ~ I i KAHN experience a sense of loss thcy lg to avoid-the disappearance .ese individually rational, small rould seem a sufficient response, rdinarily give customers the op flowing. The price will have to unity cost, and if enough patrons IW; if they are not, it ought not28. , we have market imperfection, ay such an outcome reflect au- ID suggests, two conditions haw to charge the required price for ption of service, once suspended, npos~ible~~. But these conditions rets will satisfy them in varying tve market failure because of the ;tares as well as railroads, drug. I1 as national parks, is a question lation separately. :, it is impossible for public park er actually visit them. This is the Iption is sometimes exercised, it ire consumer's surplus generated We have already suggested why lroads. Similarly, it may be in- we to charge for the privilege Of d that the kind of market failure con- e kind. There may be external benefin Nice that may justify its continuati& gnize the relevance of the second con. : market breakdown, destructive cow n which unrestricted price rivalry ma! rary excess capacity, where a tendene' ts of some producers (and below thd nadequate maintenance of productib' 11 in time be needed, and can at sd' igher cost. t,fc,\\.singJO. On the other hand, it is difficult to see why druggists can not charge to the filling of prescriptions as much of the common costs at competition in toothpastes and patent medicines requires; why liquor stores cannot charge separately for delivery; and why feeder airlines cannot charge the travellers and communities they serve the full costs of that service. Finally, even if competitive skimming of the cream did in fact cause the disappearance ofdesired associated services, we would have n case for government intervention only if condition (b) were met as Wll. It is very questionable that most of the cases discussed in this Wtion meet this test nearly as well as those analyzed in Part 11, above. f%t wilderncss, once despoiled, can never be a wilderness again.The Ching down of a neighborhood drug and liquor store, diversified book stores, even feeder airline service on thin routes, on the other hand, probably do not represent such 'large' decisions that they can- Rot bc reversed in the future, should demand warrant it. For these Cam, then, the social costs of restricted competition probably out- weigh the costs of eventually rectifying market failure, when and if ncccWry. Whatever case can be made for fair trade, for maritime hipping conferences and for restricted entry into airline transport mwt therefore be based on the imperfections of unregulated com- Flition, rather than, importantly, on the tyranny ofsmall decisions. 39 .. . - . ,. -. ALFRED E. KAHN 1 1 product quality, so that each can register a free and tolerably WII. informed monetary appraisal of quality differentials and changu ' Product inflation could by this test be said to have occurred only i! ' quality competition had operated in such a way as to eliminate or '. to fail to develop lower quality-price combinations that consumtn would willingly have purchased (or continued to purchase) in quan. : tities sufficient to cover the cost ofproviding them. The question from ': the standpoint of this essay would then be : may there be something in the process ofday-by-day or year-by-year choosing among quality price combinations, each chcjire typically involving rather modes! differences-i.e. a 'small' decision-such that while consumers makc the proper (from their standpoint) individual short-term choices, ir. * so doing they pay an aggregate cost over time that they would hat< I deemed excessive had they ever been given the opportunity to mnkr decisions is eventually to produce a range of choice from which dv sired and economically feasible lower price-quality combination, have either disappeared or have failed to appear? The answer ((' these questions may be yes; product inflation could therefore bc 3 manifestation of the tyranny of small decisions. But, the subsequent discussion will attempt to show, it is not principally an evidence of market failure: the principal culprit seems to be imperfections competition. There are two aspects of product inflation that may indeed cSt doubt on the optimality of the competitive market outcome; havinS already been discussed, they need detain us but briefly. One is thc tendency quality variations have ofgenerating external diseconomie ofconsumption-envy. The other is their contribution to the proc6 of want creation : the mere appearance of new models inculcates in consumers dissatisfaction with the ones they have. These two effecu can involve households in a self-defeating spiral of model changm each at one and the same time creating dissatisfaction and (temp rarily) removing it, at a cost that buyers might well deem excesi\*C piece-meal, family-by-family, year-to-year basis32. This is not to sa!' 11 such an over-all assessment? Or such that the total effect of thcs I I if the question were ever put to them on something other than 32. There might also be an element of market imperfection here, with con; sumers short-sightedly failing to practice the kind of 'anticipatory retardation that FELLNER points out would be rational for producers in deciding whether @ . 40 E. KAHN register a free and tolerably wcll. quality differentials and changcs. st be said to have occurred only if 1 in such a way as to eliminate or mice combinations that consumen or continued to purchase) in qunn- providing them. The question from 1 then be: may there be something x-by-year choosing among quality typically involving rather modest ,"such that while consumers makr i) individual short-term choices, in xt over time that they-would haw teen given the opportunity to makr such that the total effect of thcsc : a range of choice from which dr- lower price-quality combinatiorlc failed to appear? The answer luct inflation could therefore be J nall decisions. But, the subsequcnf it is not principally an evidence Of lprit seems to be imperfections @f uct inflation that may indeed ~351 mpetitive market outcome; havinF d detain us but briefly. One is tht afgenerating external diseconomifi c is their contribution to the procr* lrance of new models inculcates in e ones they have. These two effeca lefeating spiral of model changfi eating dissatisfaction and (temp buyers might well deem exced\" them on something other than ' c.a,c can bc sure consumers would necessarily have had it any other CAY, whether in automobiles, refrigerators, women's dresses or books. thcy would undoubtedly appraise many of the quality changes uncquivocal and unidirectionally improvements, and willingly pf thcit cost, even if offered the choice over a much longer period .. ;dtimc'. Second, they might derive sufficient pleasure from the : FCU itsclf of buying, discarding and buying again, and willingly ' p). Its costs (consider, for example, the changing 'models' of books). :. But, apart from the two foregoing considerations, it is ineffective Wqxtition that must be blamed for product inflation. The difficulty b Rot that consumers, ofered the relevant short-term alternatives, make ur( dopt the latest in a series of cost-reducing innovations. 'The Influence of hbt Structure on Technological Progress', QunrterZy Journni ofEconomics, Lxv (I%l), m reproduced in American Economic Association, Readings in Industrial @&ekation and Public Policy (Homewood, Irwin, 1958), pp.287-8. 33. !kc Ihe interesting attempt by Zvr GRILICHES to measure to what extent 0'' in automobile models have in fact mct this test, by taking as the measure Cwicrc qudity improvement Over time the (cross-sectional) price differentials ~fli;\tnpointsoftirne between models embodying comparable quality differences. Rice Indexes for Automobiles: An Econometric Analysis of Quality -, in 7hs Price Statutics of the Federal Government (National Bureau of Em- &*k Rwarch, Number 73, General Series, 1961), pp. 173-96, and 'Notes on ?k Alt*cut'cmcnt of Price and Quality Change', in National Bureau of Economic '5Yuth Conference On Research in Income and Wealth, Models of Income h*-iQn, studies in Income and Wealth, Vol. 28 (Princeton, Princeton University ,$I-~)D pp.381-404. It should be clear, however, that this ingenious calcu- 41 9 . .. _. ... j ALFRED E. KAHN rational choices setting in motion a course of development that pro. duces a less-than-optimal end result, for which they would not votc ifgiven the opportunity: that would be market failure. It is that an ' inadequately competitive market often fails to present them in the first place with the proper small choices. They are often not offered a choice between unchanged and changed models at a price differ- ential fully reflecting the cost-saving made possible by sticking to thc former. The recognition among oligopolists that competition probing the price elasticity of industry demand tends to be self-defeating, whereas 'quality' competition :hat moves that curve to the right is mutually beneficial, tends to make the choice rather between a new model of seller A and a unchanged model of seller B at the same Price. The consumer is thus deceived about the social cost of satisfying his taste for variety and change, and hence votes to satisfy that taste morc often than he would in a market characterized by more effectivr price competition. It is concentrated oligopoly with high barriers to entry that makrs the leading American automobile manufacturers comparatively un- interested in aggressively developing and promoting economy"of initial purchase, operation and repair-durability, or safety34. An- other market imperfection reinforcing this tendency, also mentioned 34. For a particularly incisive and convincing exposition and explanation of the systematic, consciously parallel tendency of automobile manufacturers pm gressively to incorporate embellishments on a non-optional basis, at progressivrh rising (and concealed) costs, see the statement of RUBY TURNER MORRIS, U.S. Senate, Subcommittee on Antitrust and Monopoly, Committee on the Judiciae". Administered Prices, Hearings, Part 6, 85th Cong. 2nd Sess., 1958, pp.245570. * also ROBERT F. LANZILLOTI~, 'The Automobile Industry', in WALTER ADA* (Ed.), 77u Structure of Amnicon Industry, 3rd ed. (New York, Macmillan, 1961)t pp. 342-5; PAUL W. GARNEY, 'How Safe Are the New Cars?' Harper's Magazifl. CCXIV (February 1957), pp.38-43. Also JOHN A. MENGE, who supplies a per- suasive explanation of why style competition and frequent model changes recom- mend themselves to the major producers, and accentuate the industry's concen- tration. 'Style Change Costs as a Market Weapon', Quarferb Joml of Economb- LXXVI (November 1962), pp.632-47. The contributions of American Motoe and the Volkswagen in at least temporarily checking product inflation do not Of course disprove but instead support the <=LARK and MENCE analysis: it would the smaller companies that might find it in their interest to emphasize price. durability, stability of style and economy, with the major producers introducing their so-called compact cars only defensively and with a lag. 42 -. LAFIN mrse of development that pro- for which they would not vote be market failure. It is that an en fails to present them in the ces. They are often not offercd mged models at a price differ- nade possible by sticking to thr ?olists that competition probing .md tends to be self-defeating, aoves that curve to the right is le choice rather between a new lode1 of seller B at the same price. t the social cost of satisfying his :e votes to satisfy that taste more ' aracterized by more effectivc tigh barriers to entry that makes anufacturers comparatively un- g and promoting economy4f &--durability, or safety34. An- tg this t ndency, also mentioncd vincing exposition and explanation of ICY of automobile manufacturers p* I a non-optional basis, at progresiveh nent of RUBY TURNER MORRIS, U.S. onopoly, Committee on the Judiciar)'. ong. 2nd Sess., 1958, pp.245570. nobile Industry', in WALTER ADA* 1 ed. (New York, Macmillan, 1961)- \re the New Cars?' Harpct's Maguifl- OHN A. MENGE, who supplies a pr- and frequent model changes recorn Id accentuate the industry's concen' eapon', Quart& Journal ofEconomirJ* le contributions of American Motof' y checking product inflation do not d ARK and MENGE analysis: it would be in their interest to emphasize price* with the major producers introducing :ly and with a lag. .. J. r 1 THE TYRANNY OF SMALL DECISIONS t~ CLARK, is the difficulty consumers have in appraising, hence their &wnru in shifting their patronage in response to, claims along these &lm''. . . Similarly, it is oligopoly plus the limitations on entry and dis- Ccwlrdgcnrcnt of price competition in passenger air transport, do- ctmlic and international, that have caused competition to take ,~~nw"notably emphasizing newer and faster equipment, frequency A:: .fmt cwts upward toward price rather than price down toward cost- . ,'", t.:mabcr ., i instance of product inflation36, Or, to take a homelier but ' plbly more irritating example, it is significant that when the .> hlrod~cc trading stamps, it stated it did not expect to have to raise bccause it anticipated the increased volume resulting 'without CmWpnding increases in fixed costs' would absorb the added Cat*''. It is not clear whether the company rejected the alternative .- 1 ..,&xhcduling, I' inflight entertainment and luxurious meals-that ad- r- ,*';A ..: .. & P company at last succumbed to the competitive pressure to 43 9 . i .,.* .- d_"yLs""-.- this significant incident in our national reversion to barter was eithrr , of the first two, then this further spread of trading stamps was x. ' instance of product inflation attributable to market imperfection. : In each of these instances, the consumer may have been offcrrd an excessively small range of choice, unreflective of all the consc- ' quences of this or that decision-to phone the airline with the nlart or the fewer flights scheduled, to patronize the grocery offering trad- ing stamps or the one that did not, in both cases with no apparcnf price differential between the rival suppliers. Naturally, in each t instance he chose the former, in numbers sufficient to force compcti. tors to 'improve' their service in the same way, at mounting costs dl around9*. To consider the latter example alone, it remains an intcp esting question how shoppers would now respond if they were given a once-and-for-all choice for or against trading stamps, in ternLC clearly setting forth how much groceries and gasoline would cost with and without them. Whether through market imperfection or markt failure, we may here again have been victims of the tyranny of small decisions. VI. Conclusion It is an inherent characteristic ofa consumer-sovereign, market econ- omy that big changes occur as an accretion of moderate-sized steps, 38. There is a clear analogy here to the case of competitive and self-defeating advertising. It pays each individual company to advertise, whether aggressivcb or defensively; and the expectation of a favorable customer response and thC presence of either excess capacity or economies of scale may permit the advertkd product to be offered at the same price as the unadvertised one. Yet the net e&<' of such a cycle of competitive moves and responses may be nothing more than higher costs for all. If consumers are never presented with a clear-cut choice bc- tween advertised and unadvertised brands at prices reflecting their respecti\* costs, or are deterred by ignorance from choosing the cheaper, unadvertised brand we have a case of product inflation attributable to market imperfection. SO, Of course, even if A & P's anticipation of higher sales and hence no-higher total unit costs were justified-and in fact it was not, universally; some A & P sto@ i did in fact raise prices when they introduced stamps (Waf1 Street Journal, SCV tember 17,1963)-that anticipation would not have been correct for the indusW , as a whole. ! 44 t i . .. . :AHN f. r, because it felt (a) such a com- xceptible to customers, or (b) , .itors, or (c) consumers really ~ luctions. But if the reason for ' I reversion to barter was either ' ead of trading stamps was an lble to market imperfection. ' sumer may have been offercd unreflective of all the consc- 'lone the airline with the mort jnize the grocery offering tmd- I both cases with no apparcnt suppliers. Naturally, in each Iers sufficient to force compcti- ime way, at mounting costs all lple alone, it remains an intcr- low respond if they were givcn P inst trading stamps, in ternu es and gasoline would cost with market imperfection or marker victims of the tyranny of small don sumer-sovereign, market econ- retion of moderate-sized steps, ase of competitive and self-defeatin!: ~y to advertise, whether aggressivrl!' vorable customer response and thr J of scale may permit the adverthd madvertised one. Yet the net efl.c' ,mnses may be nothing more thfl esented with a clear-cut choice it prices reflecting their respectitf mg the cheaper, unadvertised brad zble to market imperfection. So, 0' ler sales and hence no-higher tom' not, universally; some A & P sto@ cd stamps (Wall Street Journal, SW lot have been correct for the inddp' THE TYRANNY OF SMALL DECISIONS ihch of thcm the consequence of 'small' purchase decisions-small ,-'b firir individual size, time perspective, and in relation to their -~1( cornbincd, ultimate effect. Because change takes place in this &&ion, it sometimes produces results that conflict with the very vafr~rs thc market economy is supposed to serve. In some instances, &is wtns to be because certain kinds of economically significant %4e~ nrwr gct taken in the ballot box of the market place. In others, dkhich economists have long been aware, because the individual Ulwctions have consequences extending beyond the transacting pia thcmsclves, so that the sum-total of economic costs and bene- &%$ do not get calculated by the market. In others, not because of k'ttrrrnt dckcts of the market system itself but because of imperfec- tk@ Ofcompetition. All have these characteristics in common: that %fgC' changcs are effected by a cumulation of 'small' decisions; that ~~'~l~~l~~n ncvcr get an opportunity to vote with their dollars on the kfV clr.rngcs as such; and if they were given the opportunity, they @k,r&llt 1101 approve what they have wrought. ". , ALFRED E. KAHN SUMMARY . ALFRED E. KAHN be an uneconomic spiral of product quality changes over time so-called 'prodw: inflation'. Finally, the cumulation of individual choices may have the u1tinu:t ' effect of changing consumer preference function themselves, in which event it il ' not possible for welfare economics to judge the optimality of market performanc, i These possible defects of the market may be conceived in the more familu! 'I terms-as attributable to externalities, market imperfections or the defectc d consumer sovereignty itself. Emphasis on the contribution influence of th smallness of the controlling decisions has the virtue of suggesting the possibl, necessity of substituting a 'large' for a piecemeal accumulation of small decisior I , if the results are to be intelligently appraised or improved. i ZUSAMMENFASSUNG Allokation und Reallokation der Resourcen werden in der Marktwirtschaft ad der Grundlage der aufsummierten individuellen Markttransaktionen vorgc. nommen. Bei der Untersuchung, ob eine solche Wirtschaft auch effizient arbeitrt. ist es vor allem schwierig, genau zu bestimmen, wann und unter welchen Bc* dingungen dieses Aufsummieren zu optimalen Ergebnissen fiihrt. Der Pusscn! geringe Umfang und die begrenzte Reichweite der einzelnen Transaktion kans nach Ansicht des Autors in dem Sinne Fehlallokationen hervorrufen, dass dir Konsumenten - konnten sie explizit dafiir oder dagegen stimmen - mit den Fd- gerungen aus ihren aufsummierten individuellen Transaktionen nicht einvrr. standen wzren. Unter Umstlnden kann der geringe Umfang der relevanten Entscheidungcn sogar zu einem richtiggehenden Versagen des Marktes fiihren, etwa dann, wenn der Wunsch der Konsumenten nicht bewertet wird, eine bestimmte Diem*. lcistung - trotz augenblicklich zur Deckung der Beschaffungskosten nicht aw reichender Nachfrage - auch in Zukunft angeboten zu erhalten. Es ist auch dent. bar, dass eine <<irrationale>> Nachfrage entsteht, sobald nlmlich der gerin% Umfang der einzelnen Transaktion die Beschaffung von ausreichenden Mark[- informationen nicht gerechtfertigt erscheinen lkst. In andem FPllen werdca durch monopolistische Erscheinungen die effektiven Kosten konkurrierendc' Giiter nicht mehr richtig wiedergegeben, was die Wahlmoglichkeiten der K11lfC' venerrt; im Extremfall kann daraus sogar eine qualitative aProduktinflation* entstehen. Schliesslich ist es auch denkbar, dass sich durch die Aggregierung dcr individuellen PrSerenzen die Prserenzfunktionen der Konsumenten gndern: es ist dann nicht mehr mbglich zu beurteilen, ob der Markt im Sinne der Welfs Economics optimal funktioniert. Diese potentiellen MSngel des Marktmechanismus konnen zwar den kannten Erscheinungen, wie aterne Elemente und Unvollkommenheiten de Marktes, sowie den Nachteilen der Konsumentensouverinitiit selbst zugeschrle ben werden. Sobald man jedoch auch die durch den geringen Umfang dcr kontrollierenden Entscheidungen entstehenden Effekte beriicksichtigt, ergib' 46 . ., j : THE le so-called ‘product y have the ultimate , in which event it is narket performance. in the more familiar or the defects of on influence of the ;gating the possible .on of small decisions Marktwirtschaft auf Iransaktionen vorge- uch effizient arbeitet, d unter welchen Be- n fuhrt. Der lusserst en Trarlsaktion kann hervorrufen, dass die men - mit den Fol- ctionen nicht einver- nten Entscheidungen :en, etwa dann, wenn le bestimmte Dienst- mgskosten nicht aus- lten. Es ist auch denk- nlmlich der geringe iusreichenden Markt- ndern Flllen werden ten konkurrierender “chkeiten der Kiiufer : nProduktinflation>> lie Aggregierung der msumenten Hndern; m Sinne der Welfare 6nnen zwar den be- ollkommenheiten des litst selbst zugeschrie- geringen Umfang der beriicksichtigt, ergibt . .. THE TYRANNY OF SMALL DECISIONS sich - will man rationale Ergebnisse erhalten - die Notwendigkeit, unter Um- stznden die Schritt-fur-Schritt-Aufiummierung der einzelnen Transaktionen durch ein umfassenderes Nachfrageaggregat zu ersetzen. RbSUMfi Une tconomie du marcht fait ses allocations et reallocations des resources sur la base d’une addition de <<votes>>, que les consommateurs font sur le marcht. L’examen de l’efficacitt d’une telle tconomie est alors une t%che difficile, car il faut dtterminer quand et sous quelles conditions, ce procb d’addition produit des rtsultats optima. c<L’ttroitesse>> des transactions individuelles dtcisives et leur dimension, ttendue et perspective temporelle limittes peuvent, selon l’auteur, amener des allocations mal orienttes dans le sens, que les consommateurs pour- raient dtsapprouver les rbultats, s’ils avaient la possibilitt de voter explicitement pour ou contre. Sous certaines circonstances, l’ttroitesse des dtcisions importantes peut en- trainer une vrai dtfaillance du marcht. Cela peut &tre le cas, lorsque le dtsir des consommateurs pour un service sptcial - qui pour le moment n’est pas demandt et ne couvre donc pas les coQts de procuration, mais que les consommateurs dt- sirent utiliser dans le futur - n’est pas considtrt. Sous d’autres circonstances, 1’6troitesse des transactions individuelles peut encourager une demande irration- nellc du consommateur, car les transactions sont trop petites pour justifier l’ac- quisition de bonnes informations sur le marcht. Dans d’autres cas, des tltments monopolisateurs empechent les consommateurs d’avoir une notion correcte des prk cffectifs de marchandises concurrentes. Ceci peut mener au cas extreme B une *inflation du produit,, qualitative. Finalement, l’accumulation des prtftrences hdividuelles peut entrainer un changement des fonctions de prtftrence des con- Mmateurs; dans ce cas, il est impossible de juger si le marcht fonctionne de favn optimum dans le sens des Welfare Economics. Ccs dtfauts potentiels du marcht peuvent deriver d’tltments exttrieurs et des hprfections du marcht ou des dtfauts de la souverainett des consommateurs. si l’on veut tgalement considtrer les effets produits par l’ttroitesse des decisions de contrble, il est necessaire de substituer l’addition piEce B piece de petites dtci- par une ((macrod6cision)> si l’on veut obtenir des rtsultats rationnels. 47 . i. P- YY 3 In February of 1975, a State Court of Appeal decision was announced in the case. of Elizabeth Burger v. County of Mendocino, 45 Cal. App. 3rd 322 (1975), in an imp- casmiz with environmental impact reports. The decision was expected to deal with the issue of whether there is a duty for public agencies to prevent environ- mental damage. The Court,however, decided the case on a more limited' basis dealing with the need for a reviewable record and sufficiency of evidence to support the decision of a local govern- ' mental agency. The Supreme Court declimd to review the case, so the Court of Appeals decision is final, The Resources.Agency bel.ieved that- the case is of sufficient importance to people wko deal with environmental impact reports, that a brief report on the decision would be in order in the EIR Monitor. FACTS OF THE CASE .. The case arose when a developer proposed to build an 80 unit motel five miles south of Fort Bragg on the ocean side of Route One near the Pygmy Forest Ecological Staircase. Mendocino County had approved . . a lot split and issued two building-permits authorizing;.'the developer ,_ .. / '. ,. .. .. . . .. . to proceed with the motel. The lot split was approved before the Friends of Mammoth decision was announced, End the building permlts . . were issEd shortly after the Court decision. iu'o E13 'm.6 been pre- pared. On September 29;1972, Elizabeth Burger, an adjacent property owner, filed suit to stop the motel. The trial court granted a temporary injunction and. directed that an environmental 3,mpact report presented to the Court. The draft EIR was completed and sent to the County Planning Commission on Rovember 7, 1972. On December ll., 1972, .the EIR was completed by the County Plannfng Commission and'sent to - the Board of Supervisors. The EIR: / c>. ' $. .be prepared, be acted upon by the appropriate agencies and then be, 1. Noted that the Project would have a significant adverse 2. Urged that the additional studies be conducted on Geology impact on the environment. .. and ground water problems. .. 3. Recommended that the Board approve one of. the alternatives shown in the EIR which would reduce -the size of the catel, rearrange structures and have a less adverse impact, . 4, Declared that the Project as P~OpOser! was the worst of " - ali .the alternatives. .. Some of the comments attached to the XU3 psinted out additi.ona3.' tank and leech field for the motel would be inadequate to- handle the load and would result in water pollution in adjacent areas. .. After a public hearing on the EIR, the Board of Supervisors adopted resolutions finding that. the EIR-was sufficient and that ' the general welfare and public interest would be best served by - approval of the motel pro,ject as originally proposed. Three days later, Burger again went to court. to stop the motel construction i -f *and to reverse .the County decision. . At this stage, Burger raised two main .issues for reversing the County's decision. .The first claim was that the County's finding that the EIR was sufficient was erroneous because the EIR.contained . nothing about the impact of the Project on water quality. The - second argument was that the County's finding that the original proposal would be in the best public interest was not supported by the evidence because the EIR showed that there would be a signicant adverse impact from the original proposal, that the original pro- .. posal was the least satisfactory of several listed in the EIR, and ... that approval of one or more alternatives to the original plan -. . .would substantially mitigate the adverse impact on the environment. .. The Attorney General and the Sierra Club joined the case as friends ' . of the Court. The Attorney General's brief supported Burger and raised for the first time in this case the "Footnote 8 issue". This issue involves the interpretation of Footnote-8 in the Friends of ,Hammoth Decision which stated that 'if an EIR shows a , less damzing but still feasible alternativs to the Project, the. decision makers should choose that alternative instead of approving Club brief raised the Footnote 8 issue along with many other issues. San Francisco and the appellate decision was finally announced on February 14, 1975. 0 I. the Project as proposed. 8 C. 3rd 21C7 at 263 (1972). The Sierra .. Tne case was argued before the District Court of Appeals in . .. . _. ._ I . .' . .. .. . . DECISION .. .~ .. / In deciding the case, the Court did not discuss Footnote 8. Instead, the Court phrased the issue as whether the resolution of the Supervisors confirming the building permit is adequate and is sup- ported by the evidence before the Board. ,. I. the Board of Supervisors and was critical. of the Board procedj.ngs .. ' and conclusions in number of ways. -The relevant language from the . I. decision is as follows: , . . ..- - . .. .. .. "Al&ou&k: the resolution recites that the Board "has made a full consideration" of the EIR, it nowhere refers in any way to 'the adverse environmen.ta1 effects clearly pointed out. by that report. It nowhere suggests that such adverse e.fJ'ccts -. . .. ... I .......... ... , .- . .. ., . 1 4. .. .:( in fact are nonexistent, nor does .it.point, even in the motel.. The legislative intent was "that environmental considerations play a significant role in governmental decision-making (citation) and that such an intent was not to be effectuated by vague or illusory assurances by state and local entit;-es * that the effect of 2. project on the environment had bee3 'taken into considerat.ionf" (Friends of Mbmnoth v. Board of Supervisors, 8 Cal. 3d 247- This guideline seems. particularmppropriate where a Board of Supervisors overrides the adverse recommendation of an EIR, buttressed by like objections from the County Planning Department. We do not, of course, suggest that "findings".must be made 'with the formality attached to that term in Judicial pro- ceedings, but here there is no hint, however remote, Gf any reason for rejecting the adverse recommendations. Judicial review, specifically provided for, cannot be had in such a void. ..... ..Moreover, there is no .evidence to meet the mass of engineering and other data supporting the EIR.' Counsel for. ' the developer did state to.the Board that the alternative principally recommended by the EIR and the Planning Depart- ment was hot feasible economically, and one witness assumed the same, although- disclaiming any experience or expertise in that field. There is no esthate of incone or expendi- tures and thus no evidence that reduction of the motel Trom 60 to 64 units, or relocation of some units, would make the Project unprofitable. -generality, to overriding economic or social values of. .- -c 4 - . .- .. .. .... .-. .. .. 0 .. *. .. ._ . .. . AHALYSIS ' .. .. .. .- ' The Burger case is interesting because it is one of the first cases , .- dealmith a public agency's actions after an EIR has been com- pleted, The Burger case underscores the mpor.2ance of responding to'the rnattcrmained in an EIR. It shows, as does People v, County of Kern, that the courts will not countenance a-c agency lgnorlng an EIR. - " ._. 'The Eurger decision reflects a cautious approach by the Court. &&y. k gxwant enwiromwmtal damge an#. .chose ins&ead h:::d,ecU& m:~$4E%EGid -art TqipaP*#n$$y: -.GO .m,@lr€@ :a. JEk @#4&?@-, We case on the more narrw issue of mfficiency of evSdm.aB. The Court used reasoning developed in other cases to decide this case,. The only new departure in Burger is the clear implication that the Court will- examine the declsxon of" a public agellcy on a project invo2.vi.ng arl EIR to determine Wether the agency actually weighed the evidence before it and whether there was factual information "r; , to support its conclusion. . I The me.ior polnts in this case are as follows: ... .... .. .. .. I. c 4. t .. i:d .&flamW~t%~am~ ccmtat-ned in the EX,& and in the comments on the EIR. Discussing this concern, the Court seems to focus on the need to have some solid evidence in the record that would support the conclusion of the County. .The Court did not say that it would be satisfied if there was merely sone evidence in the.record to support the conclusion or whether the evidence supporting the Countyls deci- sion would have to out-weigh the other evidence before the Board of Supervisors. The important point here, is that the Court appears to be follow- ing the Topanga decision in which the Supreme Court stated that it would no longer presume that there was evidence in the record to support the findings of a public agency. Topanga Association for a Scenic Community v. County of Los Angelesz c. 3d .. 3?5'6Tg.=e Cou-nTuested that findings had become a hollow formality and announced that .it. would require that there be evidence in the ' %W .a .record to support the.findings, . . -.. . Burger seems to apply the rational of Topanga to rec'lons involving EIRs. This suggests that although the Court may not second guess local governmental agencies in their decisions on EIRs, it will reqaire that there be evidence in the . record -to support the decision of the public agency. The Court may not exercise its own judgment on the evidence, but the Court will require that the local . agency actually have evidence to support a decision. .. . 'C >.'.. .. Following this reasoning, a. simple statement of .overriding considerations would not satisfy the 'Court, There woulcj have to be factual evidence rn in the record to support the r'easoning in the -. '. . . statement, .. . .. CONCLUSIONS The short opinion in this case does not reveal which one'of these concerns was most Important to the Court. The decision does show, .however, that the Court will insist that governmental agencies have evidence to su port their conclusions. It appears to the Resources .. . > ~~~~~~~~~.'~~~~ ~~~~~~~~~~ $S ..*a ewxy 4 ecisian wauld.'e,e! to USE .p1 # t of. memt#&Qi of comments oz9 ,an....EIR identify adver # aeuld .be eqxicted from the ProJcdtd The recorc' would have to contain evidence to back up the conclu- . considerations fs discussed in Section 15088 or the Guidelines and also in an article in the EIR Monitor dated January II', 1974. - sions in the statement. Use of the statement of cwerridiw .C ,. .* .. J pfY3 (1 The 'opinion in the case of Burger v. County of Mendxino is by no rneans clear, The Resources Agency will-welcome comments on the decision and on this article-discussing:the decision. If wc believe that any comnents we receive would be valuable to the subscribers to the Monitor, we will publish them in subscqaegt issues, .. , .). ... .. ._ .. . I .. .. .. .i .. .. 'i .. ... .. .. m- .. ... >p* ... . 4" ." c J THE “NEW” COMPETITION FOR LAND AND SOME IMPLICATIONS FOR PUBLIC POLICY* s. v. CIRIACY-WANTRUP~ I CHANGES IN THE COMPETITION FOR LAND One of the central problems for public land policy is economic change. Of particular interest at the present juncture are changes in the competition for land that are related to urbanization and industrialization. In the West, demands for land by urban-industrial developrncnt and by irrigated agriculture must be regarded for economic analysis as “rival” or “competitive” demands.’ The level alluvial valleys and plains are the only-and usually scarce-location for irrigated agriculture. Agriculture has created and supported high land values relative to the surrounding areas not suited for irrigation becausc of topography and soils. Still, in terms of private economics, under the existing ground rules set by public land policy, these same valleys and plains are the most desirable location for subdivisions-es- pecially those consisting of assembly-line dwellings-and for in- dustry, transportation, and communication. In net value product per acre, these are “higher” land uses than irrigated agriculture- except greenhouses and certain horticultural enterprises. Thus, at thc margin of urban-industrial development, irrigated agriculture is quickly priced out of the land market. Since World War 11, only a small part of the rapid urban and industrial expansion in California has taken place on the five least productive land classes, which are not suited for irrigation.2 Most of the expansion has taken place on the three best land classes, which c Giannini Foundation Paper No. 255. An earlier version of this paper was Prc- sented under the title, “Toward a California Land Policy for the 1980’s” at the Goa- ference on Man in California: 1980’9, Sacramento, January 27-28, 1964. ?Professor of Agricultural Economics and Agricultural Economist in the ExPeri- ment Station and on the Giannini Foundation, University of California, Berkeley- 1. Because of the occasion for which this paper was first prepared, the focus ;’ on California. But the problems dealt with are acute-or soon will be-in most other western states. 2. Based on the eight land capability classes employed by the U.S. Soil Conservr- tian Service. AND .ICY" ; economic re changes cation and .velopment ic analysis ialleys and irrigated and values 3n because ics, under me valleys Islons-es- Id for in- ce product .iculture- 'hus, at the iculture is urban and : five least on.2 Most ses, which .. :r was pre- at the Con- the Experi- lerkeley. :he focus is most other '1 Conserva- mseR, 19641 NEW COMPETITION FOR LAND 253 8rC suited for irrigation, and especially on Class I-the prime ir- rigable land. On this land, the leapfrogging of subdivisions has rendered far more land unusable for irrigated agriculture than is actually used for urban development. A good illustration is the Santa Clara Valley, just south of San Francisco Bay. Until recently, this valley was famous for its pro- duction of high-quality fruits and vegetables. It is estimated that if urban expansion since 1947 were placed in one continuous parcel, that parcel would consist of twenty-six square miles. In actuality, there exists not a single square mile in a 200-square mile valley that has not been invaded by at least one subdivision? Irrigated agricul- ture has largely been replaced. The impact on the organization of water management has recently been investigated.' Most irrigated coastal valleys and plains between San Francisco and San Diego are in a state of development similar to that of the Santa Clara Valley. The Central Valley, backbone of California's irrigated agriculture, is in the initial stages of urbanization, es- pecially around Marysville, Sacramento, Fresno, and Bakersfield. Even the irrigated desert valleys, such as the Antelope and the Coachella, have become susceptible to urbanization because of the rapid growth and improvement of air conditioning. Freeways and airports are increasingly important competitors for irrigated land-both directly in terms of their own land require- Fents and as factors encouraging the leapfrogging of urban and Industrial development. Freeways and airports have a strong pre- ference for level topography. In California, such level land exists as alluvial valleys and plains. Efforts which have been made by agricul- tural interests to locate the main freeways in the Central Valley outside the prime irrigable land have not been successful. Irrigated land is significant for the economy of California be- Cause of the high productivity per acre possible through irrigation as compared with other types of agriculture. The net value product Pcr acre of irrigated land is about four times that of cultivated non- irrigated land and about twenty times that of rangeland.5 Through feed production, and in several other ways, irrigated agriculture 3. Wood k Heller, California Going, Going . . . Our State's Struggle to ::?main &autiful and PrGductive (1962). 4. S. Smith, The Public District in Integrating Ground and Surface Water Lfanagernent: A Case Study in Santa Clara County (University of California, Gian- aini Foundation Research Report No. 252, 1962). 5. Ciriacy-Wantrup, Mujor Economics Forces Affecting Agriculture with Portic- .'m Refrrrncc to Culiforniu, 18 Hilgardia 1 (Giannini Foundation Paper No. 121, 19-w). . .. . .- 25+ K.-ITUK/lL RESOURCES JOliRSdL [VOI.. 4 contributes to the productivity of nonirrigated land. Irrigated land is the foundation for California's highly developed processing in- dustries. In addition to increasing the competition for land between ir- rigated agriculture on one side and subdivisions, freeways, and air- ports on the other, urbanization and industrialization have brought about a great increase in the demands for land for various types of outdoor recreation. Potentially, this demand for land has com- plementary, as well as competitive, relations to the demand for land by agriculture, forestry, and grazing.* Under present land policies, competitive relations predominate. One implication for land policy of these changes in the competi- tion for land relates to the needed type of land-use planning. &n- ning for urban development can no longer be seuarated from plan; pine for agriculture, forestry, water, and ot-al resources. There is little contact and no co-ordination, either academically or administratively, between urban and natural-resources planning. A new breed of planner needs to be added who is not merely con- cerned with the internal problems of metropolitan regions but also is fully cognizant of the problems of the nonurban hinterland. By the same token, those concerned with natural-resources planning must first consider the land hunger of the megalopolis. This new breed of planner is already emerging. They may come from various backgrounds in the applied natural sciences, such as landscape design, engineering, architecture, and geography, but their com- mon denominator is a thorough understanding of the tools of the social sciences-especially economics and law. Another implication for land policy which follows from the in- creasing competition for land by urban and industrial uses is the irreversibility of the results. Previously, when competition for land meant merely that one agricultural use replaced another, or that agriculture replaced grazing, or that grasslands replaced forest and chapparal, these results were not necessarily irreversible. Before the large-scale use of concrete in subdivisions, freeways, and air- ports, the landscape was not irreversibly changed even by settle- ments and roads. Irreversibility in the results of the "new" comDetition for land 6. Ciriacy-Wantrup, Multiple Use as a Concept for Water and Range Policy, in Water and Range Resources and Economic Development of the West 1 (Report No. 9, Conference Proceedings of the Committee on the Economics of Water Resources De- velopment and the Committee on the Economics of Range Use and Development of the Western Agricultural Economics Research Council, 1961). MOBER. 1 raises sc the pub1 irrigate( losses ir land? If industri; would b the pub1 of land to ansu framew Let I policy. betweet urban z and gr: this sta operate land m ways : Lanc determ the prif and th of lanc! the "ir forces other c tools.'' land n dinanc decisio domail APa .” CVOL. 4 Irrigated land processing in- ?d between ir- :ways, and air- 1 have brought arious types of land has com- mand for land t land policies, n tt*e competi- 11.. irlg. Plan- ted from plan- Ira1 resources. :ademically or ‘s planning. A It merely con- gions but also linterland. By lrces planning )lis. This new 5 from various as landscape ut their com- c tools of the from the in- a1 uses is the ition for land ither, or that placed forest rsible. Before ’ays, and air- .cn by settle- on for land lnge Policy, in (Report No. 9, Resources De- eloprnent of the , ”” __ . . . . . ~BER, 196-13 NEW COdIPETlTlON FOR LAND raises some interesting and significant questions fo 255 .and policy: Do the public and the private interests coincide in the replacement of irrigated agriculture by urban-industrial development? Are social losses involved in the irreversible urbanization of prime irrigable land? If a decision were made by public land policy to divert urban- industrial development away from the prime irrigable land, what would be the costs? What about the allocation of such costs among the public and the private sectors of the economy? Are there tools of land policy to bring about and guide such diversion? An attempt to answer these questions requires a careful examination of the framework, the objectives, and the tools of land policy. I1 THE FRAMEWORK OF LAND POLICY Let us start with the framework, the basic assumptions of land policy. Control of California’s 100 million acres is divided equally between private and public land managers.’ However, nearly all urban and agricultural uses and use of the most productive forest and grassland lie within the private sector. We may assume that this state of affairs will continue. It follows that land policy must operate to a large extent through influencing the decisions of private land managers. Such influence can be accomplished in two major ways : Land policy can operate through the economic forces which determine private decision makinp. Such forces are, for example, the price system, credit, taxation, highway and water development, and the institutions governing the ownership, selling, and leasing of land. Purposeful modification of these forces will be called here the “indirect tools” of land policy. At present, these economic forces are too often obstacles rather than tools of land policy. Apart from these “indirect tools,” the policy maker has available other devices which, as a shorthand expression, we will call “direct tools.” These do not operate through the profit motive of private land managers, as do the-indirect tools, but through laws, or- dinances, and regulations which constralfi or directly compel private decisions. Zoning, easements, pest-control regulations, and eminent- ZEKproceedings are examples. Administration of public lands “l.“.- acres; private ownership50 million acres. ’1. Federal governrnent-47 million acres; state and local governments-3 million ,,." "- _. .-. 256 NATURAL RESOURCES JOURNAL [VOL. 4 in federal, state, or county ownership can also be regarded as a direct tool of land policy. Frequently, when land policy is discussed, attention is focused on the direct tools and especially on the fee-simple acquisition and the administration of public land. Such a narrow point of view amounts to an abdication of land policy because it neglects the most impor- tant sector of land-use decisions and the most important set of policy tools. On the other hand, the significance of indirect tools requires that the motivation and behavior of private land managers be thoroughly understood. This is why familiarity with the social sciences was suggested above as a prerequisite in the training of the modern land-use planner. 111 THE OBJECTIVES OF LAND POLICY Let us turn now to the objectives of land policy. The general ob- jectives of all public policies are usually expressed as maximizing of some value or quantity such as national income, social net benefit, or public interest. As a first aDDroximation. we may say basic obiective of California land Dolicv is to bution of all land uses to the social welf- The apparent simplicity of such a formulation, however, hides significant complexities. In order to maximize a quantity-the con- tribution to social welfare-it must be expressed in measurable and comparable units. For some of the social benefits associated with land use, values are established in monetary terms in the marketplace. But the system of market prices has several basic defects which make prices un- reliable as indicators of social welfare. These defects are not simple; they are difficult to remedy and cannot be discussed here:* Frequently, market prices are difficult to obtain. For example, how can one measure the contribution to social welfare of outdoor recreation and compare it with that of types of housing or systems of communication? The public interest in one area may conflict with that in another. For example, the maximum income from all land uses may not be obtainable with the income distribution and size of farms which may .. -~ 8. The implications for resource policy are discussed in Ciriacy-Wantrup, Phi- losophy und ~6jerlives of Watershed Poky, in Economics of Watershed Planning l (Tolley & Riggs ed. 1960); Ciriacy-Waotrup, Conservution and Resource Progrum- ming. 37 Land Economics 10s (1961). -DER, 19643 be desirabl usually mas straints. Bu The pro1 policy objec Such reseal rocial bene sources del developmer reational 01 Apart fr meazureme terns of la] tions over 1 land policy with the 19 This bri relation to certain tha change in ( added to t tives of lar difficulties There i formulatic game theo and of rn; objectives quantitatil definite qt benefits in As a spec present pc future 10s of policy.' as for the 9. For 10. See tc 11. Cirir Wuter, in ? 12. Fol Resource Cc 13. Id. a . . .. . . " . . . [VOL. 4 :egarded as a is focused on sition and the view amounts e most impor- It set of policy tools requires managers be ith the social raining of the he general ob- maximizing of 1.1 net benefit, say that the ize the contri- -. owever, hides tity-the con- 2asurable and ;Id use, values But the system Ike prices un- re not simple: .ere.* For example, re of outdoor ng or systems 1.t in another. may not be IS which may r-Wantrup, Phi- shed Planning 1 fourre Program- -" -*. ~~BER, 19641 NEW COlZIPETlTION FOR LAND 257 be desirable, To deal with this problem, a policy objective is usually maximized under institutional, tecnological, and other con- straints. But this device has conceptual and operational weaknes~es.~ The problem of quantitative definition and measurement of a policy objective is an area where more research is badly needed. Such research should ascertain to what extent various forms of social benefit-cost analysis, which have been applied to water-re- sources development, can also help in problems related to urban development. The planning of communication systems and of rec- reational opportunities are prime examples. Apart from the difficulties inherent in quantitative definition and measurement of the social contribution by various alternative pat- terns of land use, there is the issue of the extent of such contribu- tions over time. We are concerned here not with the contribution of land policy to social welfare in the present or the next decade but with the 1980's and beyond. This brings immediately to mind the problem of irreversibility in relation to projections of future social needs.'O The latter are so un- certain that only the directions of change and possibly the rates of change in ordinal terms can be projected." In view of this difficulty, added to the ones just mentioned, one may suggest that the objec- tives of land policy should be reformulated in a way that takes these difficulties explicitly into account. There is no need to go into the technical aspects of such a re- formulation, which lie in the field of uncertainty economics and game theory.l* Suffice it to say that the objectives of land Dolicv- snd of many other public policies-can often be compared to the objectives of an insurance policv against serious losses that resist' " " " " . . . .. . . . . . . . -, . " ".- 258 NATURAL RESOURCES JOURNAL [VOL. 4 IV AN ILLUSTRATION : THE CONSERVATION OF CALIFORNIA'S PRIME IRRIGABLE LAND An illustration may help to clarify this reformulation of the objcc- tives of land policy. The land-policy problem with which this paper is mainly concerned is the irreversible loss of prime irrigable land when agricultural use is replaced by subdivisions, industries, free- ways, and airports. Some questions were already raised" regarding whether and in what way the conservation of prime irrigable land for agricultural uses should be regarded as an objective of land policy. The answers are by no means self-evident. At the outset, one needs to make assumptions with respect to future water supply. It is very difficult to make meaningful state- ments about California land policy without considering, at the same time, water policy. Let us consider two alternative assumptions re- garding future water supply. First, we may assume that, in view of limited water SUDD~V. agri- cultural use of water will have to be curtailed in favor of urban and industrial useg It has long been recognized that the marginal value product of water in these latter uses is higher than in irriga- tion uses. Under this assumption, the gradual encroachment of urban development on irrigated agriculture can be regarded as a self-regu- lating adjustment to water scarcity. Average per-acre water require- ments of irrigated crops and of subdivisions are not great!;. differ- ent. This adjustment is also painless to individual irrigatiort enter- 3 prises. In fact, they generally will make a capital gain in the adjust- $ ment process. The gain per acre will tend to increase as use of the remaining irrigable land is intensified. In conclusion, under our first assumption, land policy must be concerned not so much with the conservation as with orderly transformation of irrigable land into urban and industrial useg. Alternatively, we may assume that future wu e sufficient for urban-industrial development atzd for of agriculture on the mime irrivable land. This assumption is in accord with the projections of future water supply by the California Department of Water Resources. There is some doubt whether such projections can be based solely on the transfer of northern California water to the south-even if such transfer is regarded as 14 See text at 253-55, rupra. ~BER, 19641 desirable and especially the desalinization popularity of may accept he supply- Acceptance existing projc future water- ment of some because of thc irrigable land issue cannot k Under our celerating di: avoidable sot affect the eco indirect socia A valid quar a saturation reached, WOK formulation ( in the order ' with that of against them possible lossc The insur necessitated alluvial plail otherwise in rounded by these lands ; head for flc, portant 11 off s poorer" sit tive estimatc questionable balance, the future. 15. The pro and the effects the amount of \ IVOL. 4 .i OF 0 on of the objec- .hich this paper : irrigable land ndustries, free- ;ed“ regarding ! irrigable land jective of land vith respect to aningful state- lg, at the same ssumptions re- *r supply, agri- i 1 avor of urban ; : the marginal than in irriga- ment of urban ’ as a self-regu- I water require- greatly differ- i igation enter- in the adjust- as use of the nder our first luch with the !ble land into i upply will be , maintenance , .rnption is in P California ! bt whether Jf northern !’ regarded as i I ! ~BEK, 196+] NEW COJfPETITION FOR LAND 259 desirable and politically fea~ible.’~ But in view of other sources- especially the Columbia River-and technological developments in desalinization and reuse of water, and in view of the increasing popularity of a “public utility concept” of water development, we may accept here this alternative assumption regarding future water Acceptance of this assumption does not imply acceptance of some existing projections regarding the timing in the construction of future water-supply systems. On strictly economic grounds, defer- ment of some features of these systems may well be desirable. But because of the irreversibility already stressed, conservation of prime irrigable land is a present issue for land policy. A decision on this issue cannot be deferred. Under our second assumption, a continuing or, more likely, ac- celerating disappearance of prime irrigable land will lead to an avoidable social loss-or benefit foregone-which would seriously affect the economy of the state. The loss consists of the direct and indirect social net value product of California’s irrigation economy. A valid quantitative estimate of this loss, decade by decade, until P saturation point of urbanization and industrialization has been reached, would be rather difficult. But, in accordance with our re- formulation of the objectives of land policy, we are mainly interested in the order of magnitude of maximum possible losses as compared with that of the “insurance premium” that must be paid to guard against them. There can be little doubt in this case that the maximum possible losses are high. The insurance premium consists of the higher construction costs necessitated if urban-industrial development is diverted from the alluvial plains to the benches, to the foothills, and to rocky and otherwise inferior soils. Irrigated valleys in California are sur- rounded by ample land of this type. Higher construction costs on these lands may be partly or fully offset by savings in social over- head for flood control, drainage, and sewage disposal. Other im- portant offsets are the greater amenities made possible by the poorer” sites for many aspects of urban life. Here also a quantita- tive estimate of costs and offsets over several decades would be of questionable validity. There is, however, some evidence that, in balance, the costs are not too high and are likely to decrease in the future. 15. The problematic aspects concern the California “Area of Origin” legislation and the effects on fishery resources. Adequate solution of these problems will reduce the amount of water available for transfer. ruPPlY- lt 260 NATURAL RESOURCES JOURNAL. pot. 4 In California, some of the better housing developments on the benches and in the foothills have proved quite profitable for sub- dividers. Admittedly, the alluvial valleys will remain the most profit- able land for the dismal sprawl of cheap, assembly-line, individual dwellings. But in other parts of the country, p.rivate enterprise has successfully provided attractive low-cost housmg of a land-saving type. In a special case which the author had occasion to study recently, conservation of prime irrigable land is the deliberate result of pri- vate decision making. Land-use planning on the 90,000-acre Irvine Ranch in southern California involves conservation of a contiguous large tract of prime irrigable land for agriculture. On the same ranch, urban development is intensified on the benches, the foothills, and the inferior soils. Such planning appears profitable from the private viewpoint. But most private enterprises in land management are not large enough to plan “as if” they, were a public body. Planning for urban development on the Irvine Ranch includes industrial parks. These parks of light, technologically highly de- veloped industries are located on the benches and foothills not suited for irrigation. If present trends continue, future industrial develop- ment in California will emphasize this same type of industry. Its location outside of the prime irrigable land presents no difficulties and many advantages. Equipment and techniques to move earth cheaply and on a Iarge scale are rapidly developing. Sometimes this technological develop- ment has not resulted in conservation-for example, when scenic values are destroyed in highway construction. But through lowering the costs of diverting subdivisions and freeways away from the prime irrigable land, conservation benefits will accrue from this de- velopment-as has already occurred through lowering the costs of terracing and leveling, both of which are important aids in soil conservation. In conclusion, under our second assumption, one may suggest that the insurance premium to be paid is of such an order of magni- tude as compared with that of benefits that it can well be considered a rational present and continuous social investment. In order to avoid misunderstanding, it may be well to add that the reasoning presented here does not necessarily favor conservation of agricultural or wildland islands within metropolitan regions. This is a problem of “green belts’’ and other types of “lungs” as an integral part of urban development. It is an entirely different ob- :, ! :4 ‘ _” . - OCTOBER, 19641 jective of lar of economic are concerne of prime irr tions of the tinuing urba land resour1 hand, is scar If a land arises : “W premium?” struction co tenant? Wt have to for lic particip: Which pub what prop( petent peo] To a la1 type of to1 urban and tion next tc Within to conside which hav to take u present p direct to( praised w tion of la] A. Taxat Many use taxat transforr Wantrup, 1 16. See - ”” ,. -. "1 -._ . -.." "- [VOL. 4 ~lents on the able for sub- le most profit- 'ne, individual enterprise has a land-saving ;tudy recently, result of pri- 30-acre Irvine I f a contiguous On the same , the foothills, tble from the i I management ic body. :anch includes Ily highly de- lills not suited ;trial develop- ' industry. Its no difficulties nd on a large gical develop- , when scenic )ugh lowering ;ay from the from this de- ing the costs It aids in soil may suggest der of magni- be considered add that the servation of sgions. This ungs" as an different ob- OcrnseR, 19641 NEW COdiPETITION FOR LAND 261 jcctive of land policy, which should be supported by a different kind of economic reasoning and carried out by a different set of tools. We are concerned here with the conservation of large contiguous blocks of prime irrigable land as one of the permanent economic founda- tions of the state. Such conservation need not interfere with con- tinuing urbanization and industrialization; California has abundant land resources for these uses. Prime irrigable land, on the other hand, is scarce. If a Iand-policy decision along these lines is made, the question arises: "Which sector of the economy should pay the insurance premium?" To what extent, for example, should increases in con- struction costs be allocated to the subdivider, the homeowner, or the tenant? What about equity to the owner of irrigable land who may Ewe to forego a private capital gain? Is there justification for pub- lic participation in bearing the burden of the insurance premium? Which public should be involved-federal, state, or local-and in what proportions? These are questions to which research by com- petent people should be directed inlmediately. To a large extent, the answer to these questions depends on the type of tool employed by land policy to influence the location of urban and industrial development. Therefore, let us turn our atten- tion next to the tools of land policy. V THE TOOLS OF LAND POLICY Within the space limits of a single paper, it is clearly impossible to consider thoroughly all tools of land policy or even merely those which have been mentioned as examples.'* I should like, therefore, to take up two tools which appear especially significant for the present purpose. Taxation, one of the most important of the in- direct tools, and easements, a promising direct tool, will be ap- praised with respect to their helpfulness for influencing the alloca- tion of land between agricultural and urban-industrial uses. A. Taxation in Cotnbination with Zoning Many attempts have been made in California and elsewhere to use taxation as a tool to prevent, to slow down, and to direct the transformation of agricultural land into subdivisions. The general 16. See text at 255-56, JU~~U. For a more comprehensive discussion, see Ciriacy- wantrup, Resource Conservation: Economics and Policies, at chs. 7-15 (2d ed. 1963). 262 NATURAL RESOURCES JOURNAL [VOL. I procedure is to set up special tax districts in connection with zoning ordinances. More recently, deferment of taxes on agricultural prop- erties for a certain number of years, under certain conditions, has been proposed without relation to zoning.” This proposal was defeated at the polls. The best-known example in California for the taxation-zoning approach is Santa Clara County, comprising the valley of the same name. Santa Clara County was the first county in California that adopted a master plan (1934). Zoning ordinances with the objec- tive of maintaining green belts were enacted in 195.3 and 1955 on the basis of the then existing state enabling laws. In 1955, the state enacted the more specific “Green Belt Exclusion Law”ls and in 1957 the closely related “Agricultural Assessment Law.”1e The main objective of these measures of land policy in the Santa Clara Valley was not the conservation of prime irrigable land but an orderly transition from agricultural to urban land use. Still, several conclusions can be drawn from this experience with respect to the taxation-zoning approach to the conservation of prime irri- gable land. First, constitutional Drovisions make rt &&& to assess at a lower level those amicultural DroDerties which are most affected In California, the general constitutional provisions requiring uniformity in taxation are applied in the laws through the “no reasonable probability” limitation. This limitation provides that land in order to qualify for lower assessment mst have no reasonable probability of changing from agricultural to urban use. Some states-Connecticut, Florida, Maryland, and New Jersey-have recently tried to remedy this situation by statute or constitutional amendment. Similar proposals have been discussed in California. It is difficult, however, to define permanent, bona fide agricultural use in such a way that lower assessment does not merely reduce the carrying charges for land speculators. Second, zoninp does not prevent eventual urbanization becrause farmers themselves usuallv favor a repeal of z- when expected capital gains from urbanization become attractive, fn other words, zoning has proved a politically unstable protection of agricultural use in the path of urban expansion. While zoning .. ” to Ilrhanrxatlnn. .. i. i .- 17. Proposition 4 on the California state ballot of November 6, 1962. 18. Cal. Gov’t Code 5 35009. 19. CaI. Gov’t Code 5 402.5. ~EIER, 19641 ordinances a districts are Third, th rcvcral othe ture in the r incentive to In surface ir system. Thi tion, and ro the use of il pass, and vi sufficient co is an obsta This obstac pect that 5 objectives. In concl Santa Clar is the cons B. Social C Urbatliz~t It is s( strengther and public Social ovc that with: zoning 01 of local g private e sive to tl be regarc in urbani The q on the st ization F Proposa of south tion of n Therc the pro. .. . IVOL. 4 :ith zoning Lural prop- iitions, has posaI was ion-zoning f the same ornia that the objec- 1 1955 on , the state Id in 1957 the Santa * land but use. Still, th respect prime irri- SeSS at a t affected arnia, the taxation >bability" dify for changing Florida, ledy this xoposafs to define at lower for land because dinances [active. tection zoning ~EER, 19641 NEW COMPETITION FOR LAND 263 ordinances are in effect, they encourage leapfrogging if the zoning districts are discontinuous. Third, the burden of property taxes is only one factor among sevcral others which make it difficult to continue irrigated agricul- ture in the rural-urban fringe. Impending urbanization reduces the e to invest in proper maintenance of irrigation sv-. ce irrigation, each individual enterprise is a part of a larger, xstern. This system is disrupted bv leapfroggin?, urban scatters- tion, and roads. An urban neighborhood Duts serious limitations on the use of insecticides and fertilizers. Crops suffer from smog, tres- pass, and vandalism, Tax relief, therefore, is a necessary but not a sufficient condition for continuity of agriculture. Taxation at present is an obstacle to the objectives of land policy we are discussing. This obstacle should be removed, but it would be an illusion to ex- pect that such removal by itself would bring about the desired objectives. In conclusion, the experience with taxation and zoning in the Santa Clara Valley is not encouraging if the land-policy objective is the conservation of prime irrigable land for agricultural uses. In urbw. " The auestion mav be raised of whether this situation holds also "" ,... I i ’1 264 NATURAL RESOURCES JOURLVAI. [VOL. 4 pitious conditions, is strategic for economic development. Many illustrations for this could be cited. But for a highly developed region with strong metropolitan areas and important urban nuclei outside of these areas, development of water-supply systems must be regarded economically and politically as a dependent rather than independent variable in urbanization. Furthermore, for the ob- jectives of land policy we are discussing, it is meanindess to suncest that urbanization could be controlled through the water supply; as Shown elsewhere, the water supply available through displacement of agriculture is one of the major economic attractions for the ur- banization of prime irrigable land.20 C. Eascntetzts Let us turn, therefore, to another tool of land policy which pro- vides tax relief, which is politically more stable than zoning, and to which constitutional and other limitacions apply in different ways than to taxation. This tool is the acquisition of public easements over private land. Use of easements in connection with communication systems, air- ports, and public utilities is well established. Easements for open space, parks, and highways are common.21 Some states, especially Wisconsin, have pioneered with recreational easements for hunting and fishing.22 Conservation easements are mentioned in the litera- ture in connection with open-space easements.= But, so far as I am aware, such easements have not been used for the conservation of large blocks of prime irrigable land. Such easements may be acquired by the state or by local governments under state enabling laws. For the purpose under discussion, the planning and guidance of acquisition are best undertaken on the state level. Conservation easements may be acquired through voluntary sale 20. Ciriacy-Wantrup, Projections of Water Requircmrnts in the Economics of Water Policy, 43 J. of Farm Economics 197 (1961). 21. In California, the “Open Space Act“ of 1959 [Cal. Gav’t Code $$69SO-S4] authorized cities and counties to acquire land outright or the development right or easements to provide open-space areas. Such areas are defined as: any space characterized by (1) great natural scenic beauty or (2) whose exist- ing openness, natural condition, or present state of use, if sustained, would enhance the present or potential value of abutting or surrounding develop- ment, or would maintain or enhance the conservation of natural or scenic resource$. 22. Jordahl, Conservation and Scenic Earemrnts: .4n Exprrirncr Rrsumr, 39 Land 23. Whyte, Securing Open Space for Urban America: Conservation Easements 45 Economics 313 (1963). (Urban Land Institute, Technical Bulletin No. 36, 19S9). ~OFIER, 19 or throu: challenge making interest r 3 public i tion of p It is SI of the fe the publi tion of permane belts) 01 latter ca: and sim] crease ir public. I continue In our c quire ea: For tt be purct purchase higher ti Conse problem affected be no lo ally be inducern Volur value pl is the rr real cha professi rights tl lems, hc must be I I APPr 1 24. Fa Spaces Ti 1960). i . Many reloped n nuclei ns must Ler than the ob suggest xement the ur- .,ply; 3s ich pro- . and to It ways its over ms, air- )r open , ecially hunting : litcra- 1s I am tion of cquired 1 laws. .nce of ry sale - Irnirs of 6950-541 right or ist- 'y- 9 Land ents 45 .l IC mEER. 19&] NEW COMPETITION FOR LAND 265 or through eminent domain. In California, voluntary sale is open to challenge because the constitution prohibits the legislature from making gifts of public funds.*' In both cases, therefore, a public interest must be shown to exist. It is the argument of this paper that a public interest exists if the purpose of land policy is the conserva- tion of prime irripable land for agricultural uses. It is sometimes suggested by urban .planners th.at the-acquisitFon of the fee-simple right is less complicated, of greater advantage to the public later on, and not much more expensive than the acquisi- tion of easements. This is quite true if the acquisition concerns permanent open space without much private development (green belts) or space to be developed later under public control. In the latter case, the fee-simple acquisition would assure effective control and simplify the problem of compensation. Furthermore, the in- crease in land value due to the development would accrue to the public. In the present case, however, important private uses will continue. High land values are created and supported by these uses. In our case, therefore, it is more economical for the public to ac- quire easement rather than fee-simple rights. For the objective of land policy under discussion, easements must be Purchased in perpetuity. Experience tends to indicate that the purchase price per acre of a perpetual easement is not significantly higher than that for a twenty-year easement. Conservation easements would go a long way to solve the tax probleq for individual irrigation enterprises when land values are affected by potential urbanization. Since development rights would be no longer vested in the private owner, he could not constitution- $1~ be assessed for them. This, in itself, will constitute a strong Inducement toward voluntary sale of conservation easements. tary sale would, of course, be influenced by the economic vaeced on the development rights which are given UP. This is the most crucial problem of conservation easements. It poses a real challenge to economics as an academic discipline, to the legal Profession, and to the practical administrator. Appraisal of individual strands of the bundle of private property rights that relate to an acre of land is not uncommon. Special prob- lems, however, are created by the fact that conservation easements must be acquired simultaneously for large blocks of irrigable land. 24. For a more detailed discussion of these problems, see PreJeroufion of Ottn SPaces Through Scenic Eurrments in Green Belf Zoning, 12 Stan. L Rev. 638 (1959- 1960). I i. t; i, ; -1 ” 266 NATURAL RESOURCES JOURNAL [VOL. 4 Should allowance be made for different dates at which individual parcels would have become ripe for urban development? Should geographical factors, such as distance to existing urban centers, be taken into account in combination with market transactions as bench- marks? In what way should other basic factors-climate, soils, and groundwater supply-be taken into account in valuation? What legal, political, and administrative safeguards should be built into the procedures of appraising and taking conservation easements? Should such safeguards be developed in analogy to those already existing in the procedures used to establish special public districts with the powers of taxation and eminent domain? Research by the social sciences is badly needed to answer these questions. Such research would also benefit the use of other types of ease- ments. Recreational easements are an example. It would be rather wasteful if California should neglect the contribution private lands could make in satisfying the increase in the demand for outdoor recreation that can be expected during the coming decades. Such contribution will not be forthcoming without reimbursement to the private land manager. The purchase or lease of recreational ease- ments by the state is one of several alternative approaches to this problem. The state could recover these costs through fees charged for recreational uses. California has been backward in this area of land policy as compared with other states such as Wisconsin. CONCLUSION In the West, a “new” competition for land is becoming of far- reaching social significance. This is the competition for prime ir- rigable land between agriculture on one side and subdivisions, in- dustries, freeways, and airports on the other. At the margin of urban-industrial development, irrigated agriculture is quickly priced out of the land market by these “higher” land uses. This change in land use is irreversible. In California, the replacement of irrigated agricuIture has progressed farthest and raises some acute and in- teresting problems for public land policy. If the general objectives of land policy as formulated in these pages are accepted, and if the more optimistic of two alternative assumptions regarding future water supply discussed here is ful- filled, conservation of large contiguous blocks of prime irrigablc land for agriculture appears in the long-run public interest. The social costs for diverting urban-industrial developmcnt to land classes not suited for irrigation are of such an order of magnitude _.’- - - c W~ER, 19 as compa by the co these coc for avoic ing wate irrigable dustrial Sever effective prime iI era1 ser urbaniz: ness in 1 been us1 But tht and the policy s serving ture. CVOL. 4 !ich individual rnent ? Should an centers, be <,ions as bench- climate, soils, uation? What be built into n easements? those already ublic districts search by the ypes of ease- dd be rather private lands for outdoor ecades. Such ’ment to the tional ease- ches to this fees charged this area of :onsin. >. ning of far- x prime ir- livisions, in- margin of lickly priced rhis change of irrigated ute and in- d in these lternative re is ful- irrigable rest. The . to land xagnitude 1 OCTOBER, 19641 NEW COMPETITION FOR LAND 267 as compared with that of maximum possible social losses threatened by the continuation and probable acceleration of present trends that these costs can be regarded as a rational present social investment for avoiding such losses in the future. Under our assumption regard- ing water supply, conservation of large contiguous blocks of prime irrigable land for agriculture does not interfere with urban-in- dustrial development. Several tools of land policy are appraised with respect to “ir effectiveness in diverting urban-industrial development from :he prime irrigable land. The usual taxation-zoning approach has sev- eral serious shortcomings for this purpose. Likewise, controlling urbanization through social overhead appears of doubtful effective- ness in the present case. Thus far, conservation easements have not been used for the particular objective of land policy discussed here. But the economic-legal characteristics of conservation easements and the experience with them in realizing other objectives of public policy suggest that they may be well suited for the objective of con- serving large contiguous blocks of prime irrigable land for agricul- ture. Environmental Quality As the human population grows and as technology develops, pollution and other deleterious changes in environmental quality have increasingly severe effects on economic activities, including food production, aside from the general quality of life. The chief areas of concern about environmental quality associated with food production include: -- Effects on the environment of potentially polluting materials from agriculture, such as crop-protection chemicals, fertilizers, and solid wastes. -- Effects on agriculture of environmental degradation caused by population growth and industrialization, such as effects of urbanization on farmland, and crop damage from urban-generated air pollution. -- The effects on agricultural production of necessary environmental monitoring, management, and regulation. Agricultural Xesidues and Wastes Technologically advanced intensive food production--whether in developed or developing countries--generates wastes and residues in amounts and concentrations that threaten environmental quality. These may be either unwanted by-products of agricultural activities or substances which have served their intended purposes. Pesticide residues. In recent years, crop-protection chemicals have become far more- numerous and diverse and have been used in far larger amounts. Many are highly toxic to man and other animals. Some persist in the environment and accumulate in food chains. Specific environmental side-effects from the use of pesticides--particularly insecticides-- include possible residues in foods, poisoning of agricultural workers, killing of nontarget organisms, and residues in soil and water. There also is danger of decreasing the effec- tiveness of pest control, through destruction of beneficial organisms and the development of resistance in target species. Fertilizer residues. Environmental questions are raised by the rapidly expanding use of chemical fertilizers in the U.S. and other developed nations, as well as the trend toward more fertilizer use, particularly nitrogen, in developing countries. Nitrates in excess of those used by the crop can appear in drainage water from some croplands, and may enter groundwater supplies. Food production and harvest of forest products in the U.S. in 1970 resulted in a biological turnover of nitrogen--soil to plant and return to soil--of about 40 million metric tons. Of this, about 20% was introduced into the cycle as manufactured fertilizer nitrogen. Animal and crop wastes. Large-scale intensive production units for beef and poultry have created waste disposal problems on a new scale. Large amounts of manure concentrated on a small area are problems both because of their bulk and because of their content of nitrogen, salts, and organic matter. If the trend to intensification of animal production continues, it will involve increasingly complex waste disposal and pollution problems. Solid wastes from crops and food processing are an environmental problem primarily in relation to cities and other population concentrations. Most of these wastes are highly " I '- degradable, so they can be recycled rapidly by biological action or burning. However, the disposal process may create problems of smoke, odors, water pollution, and pests. Environmental Effects on Agriculture Agriculture's resource base of land, water, and air may be threatened by environmental degradation, particularly in heavily-populated and industrialized areas. Water. Metropolitan areas must dispose of large volumes of liquid and solid wastes. Most constituents of typical municipal effluents are either harmless to crop production or actually beneficial. Hence, there is a promising possibility of recycling vast amounts of urban wastes through farmland. The chief problems are transport and distribution of the effluents, and removal or management of pollutants such as heavy metals and viruses. - Air. In regions where man-caused air pollution is substantial, food production suffers. California may be the world's leading example. Oxidants are responsible for most air- pollution crop damage in California today. If the energy shortage leads to more use of sulfur-containing fuels, sulfur dioxide also could become a serious threat. Oxidants have been shown to significantly reduce yields of cotton, citrus, and grapes. Their effect on individual crops of leafy vegetables has at times been disastrous. - Land. In addition to the worldwide problem of availability of arable land, there is a specific problem of urban effects on farmland. California also provides a dramatic - example of this environmental constraint on food production. Agricultural operations are hindered not only by actual loss of land to urbanization but by urban-generated higher tax rates and by competing land uses such as power plants. The problem is made worse--at least in the western U.S.--by traditional patterns of lavish use of land for residential, industrial, and commercial development. - ,. Effects of Environmental Management Food production, as well as other sectors of the economy, may be constrained by public policy to protect environmental quality. In California, restrictions on agricultural production have resulted from controls on land use, solid waste disposal, use of crop- protection chemicals, air quality, and water quality. It seems likely U.S. and California agriculture will operate within an increasingly complex framework of policies and procedures designed to achieve two goals simultaneously--protect the environment and increase food production. Energy Energy, like land and water, is an underlying resource crucial to worldwide food production. The energy shortages and price increases of 1973-74 have emphasized the per- vasive impact of this resource on all nations and all economic sectors, including the food production-processing-marketing system. 35 ing impact on energy supplies after 1980, and by 1990 should account for 22% of total U.S. energy consumption. Beyond 1990, new conversion technologies, including breeder reactors, will be more important in nuclear power generation than natural reserves of uranium and thorium ores. Presently unconventional sources of power--solar, wind, geothermal--also may well pro- vide small but significant percentages of the total energy in 2000. It is estimated that 3% of California's energy requirements will be met with geothermal power by 1985. Energy use in agriculture is as intensive in many other industrialized nations as in the U.S. In fact, per hectare use of fertilizer--which requires large amounts of energy in its manufacture--is higher in Japan and many European countries than in the U.S. However, the substitution of mechanical power for human labor has advanced farther in the U.S. than anywhere else (Figure 11). Fie. 11 REPLACEMENT OF FARM LABOR BY INANIMATE ENER 1120-1970 '- 1920 0 1940 \ 0 1945 0 1947 0 1950 \ I I I I 0.5 10 1.5 2 ENERGY INPUT TO FOOD SYSTEM ( 1015 kcal) The developing nations have much smaller inputs of mechanical and chemical energy into agriculture. One result is, paradoxically, more apparent efficiency in total energy use when outputs of food energy are compared with inputs of mechanical and chemical energy. Relatively primitive food-production systems yield about 16 calories of digestible energy for each calorie of energy from humans, animals, and fossil fuels. On the other hand, U.S. farmers produce only about a single calorie of food energy for one calorie input of fossil-fuel-based energy. Further, when the entire U.S. food system is considered, the ratio is 6 or 7 calories of fuel energy expended for each calorie of food energy produced. 38 In the U.S. food-production system, the three largest energy-consuming sectors are meat animals (39%), poultry and eggs (20%), and dairy products (20%). However, these products are relatively efficient in converting energy to protein. In most primitive countries, the yield of digestible energy per hectare is small. Under these circumstances, fossil fuels dramatically increase crop output per hectare, even though there may be a great change in the ratio of food t'nerzy produced to fuel energy consumed. An additional amount of energy applied to agriculture will provide an increase in human productivity and food output that is greater in a developing country than in a developed one. As industrial growth takes place in a developing country, however, agriculture's share of total economic activity declines, and competition for energy resources increases. For that reason, mechanical energy in agriculture is confined at first to the items with the highest potential payoff--fertilizer, tillage, water pumping, and transport. Energy shortages and higher energy prices will probably be more harmful to countries in intermediate stages of development than to either industrialized nations or those with subsistence agriculture. A critical area of concern is energy to manufacture fertilizer, particularly nitrogen. Because many developing nations have surplus labor--manifested in unemployment and poverty--labor-displacing technology may be a social disservice. A desirable alternative would be the development of tools and technologies that still use large labor inputs, whi crop production per hectare is increased by methods such as machinery for heavy tillage. le - Effects on Food Production Costs Even if agriculture receives sufficient energy to produce, process, and market crops (through government allocation or through market forces), increased costs of energy must be reflected in higher food prices. Higher energy costs will affect some crops more than others. For example, 78% of all natural gas required for California field crops in 1972 was used by sugar beets, mostly at the processing stage. Obviously, increases in natural gas prices will have a larger impact on sugar beets than on processed food products with relatively lower energy requirements. , Human, Economic, and Institutional Forces In general, developed countries have certain institutional and economic patterns influencing the supply and consumption of food, and developing countries have others. There also are important differences within the groups. For instance, Japan has many -small farms 39 WORLDWIllE IMPLICATIONS ! Based on this analysis, a response is now in order to the question posed in the introduction--whether current food shortages are a result of temporary or permanent phenomena. There are both short-run and long-run aspects of the world food situation as projected to 1985 and beyond. Population growth rates in excess of food production increases, expected to continue for at least to 1985, will compound food supply problems in several regions. Thus, the distribution of world food supplies will remain a more serious problem than total world crop and animal production. Short-run market surpluses--i.e., actual supplies in excess of effective demand--are likely to recur in those countries capable of producing food in excess of their consumption requirements. Given the limited purchasing power of many consumers in less developed nations, the world food dilemma will continue: malnutrition and starvation in some areas, while food surpluses accumulate in other regions. The world's food shortages will continue to be centered in the developing regions of Asia, Africa, and Latin America, but in a broader sense the food problem is worldwide. Effects of human suffering and unrest in the developing regions inevitably will be felt elsewhere. In addition, potential solutions to the world's food problem have their origins in industrialized nations, or at least will require their cooperation. The food situation beyond 1985 is more uncertain. While no attempt was made in this - study to assess food balances after 1985, certain key issues bear emphasis. World popu- lation is projected to increase by another 1-2 billion people from 1985 to 2000. At the upper population variant this means feeding about :.wice as many people in 2000 as existed in 1968. At the lower variant the world population in 2000 would still be 50 percent larger than it is today. The amount and quality of the world's undeveloped arable land creates further un- certainty for food production beyond 1985. For obvious reasons the best and easiest land was developed first. It will be increasingly difficult to mobilize the necessary human, institutional, and economic resources rapidly enough to keep pace with food demand in countries where the need will continue to be most critical. Technology and research requirements for the 1985-2000 period present even greater challenges. Much of the yield-increasing technology assumed in our projections for the 1970-85 period is currently available for adoption or is in the advanced stages of de- velopment. But meeting food production needs during the last 15 years of the 20th cen- tury will depend upon accelerated adoption of known methods, development of new technology, and, indeed, some real "breakthroughs". Planning, basic and adaptive research, and the development of effective vehicles for international cooperation are imperative if food production technology is to be available when and where needed. Improved methods for timely monitoring of world food production and utilization will also be required for effective planning. A final word of caution for the 1985-2000 period relates to those parameters over 50 which man has the least control, making him most vulnerable to the unexpected. The more intensive the food system becomes, the more vulnerable it is to adverse dynamics from physical and biological factors. Possibilities of genetic failures, diseases, global weather disturbances and sudden crucial input shortages make the world food system more precarious. It behooves both developed and developing countries to allow for a margin of safety through technological development and food reserves. Developing Countries Although the developing regions are mostly in the tropics where potentials exist for high levels of food production, their food requirements are expanding faster than their agricultural production. These nations expanded food production as rapidly as the developed world from 1950 to 1.970, but their food demand has grown even faster--at 3.5% yearly, compared with 2.5% in the industrialized nations. Most of that difference is the result of higher population growth rates. Almost 85% of all births occur in the less developed countries; their share of total world population is projected to increase from 75% in 1970 to 80% by 2000. The only potential long-term solution to food problems in the developing countries is a reduction in population growth. Current rates widen the gap between rich and poor nations, tax the limited food-producing resources of the developing nations, increase the likeli- hood of malnutrition and/or famine in these countries by 2000, and contribute to problems of environmental quality. Policies and programs to reduce population growth in developing countries must be vigorously pursued by the governments of these countries and by the United Nations and other international organizations, with assistance from the developed world. If population growth patterns continue, it will probably be necessary for developed countries to continue food aid and technical assistance programs to reduce nutritional and other socioeconomic problems in the developing world. Since population control policies, even if vigorously pursued, will require some years to reduce population growth rates, increased food production is the only immediate approach. However, even with recent improvements in agricultural productivity--mainly resulting from application of research by the international agricultural institutes--food production will be an in- creasingly serious problem in developing countries through 1985 and beyond. Indeed, limited evidence suggests that agricultural production growth rates have slowed in many developing countries during the past three years. Because of its dense population, low crop yields, limited undeveloped land and water, and limited capital resources, Asia will be particularly hard-pressed to meet the food needs of a rapidly growing populace. A strategy of rapidly increasing crop yields must be followed in Asia because other options, such as development of new land, are limited. In Latin America and Africa, two approachesto increased food production are feasible: yield-increasing technology and new land development. Most emphasis should go to increas- ing yields on large production areas because returns probably would be greater per unit 51 of investment. At the same time, the obstacles to developing millions of hectares of arable, productive land in these two continents should be attacked. When new land settle- ment schemes are planned and implemented, research should accompany the development. Some of the poor returns from past irrigation and land development projects were caused by inadequate knowledge and application of yield-improving technology to cultural conditions in the area. In all developing regions of the world, the human condltions in agricultural areas must be enhanced. Programs to overcome poverty and large income disparities must be developed. Land reform as well as improved credit and marketing facilities will be needed. Applied research and extension, major contributors to increased agricultural productivity in develop- ed nations,also should be supported. New technology to increase production, if patterned after developed countries, is capital- intensive and labor-saving. This approach is not directly applicable in densely populated countries that depend on subsistence agriculture. The kinds of technology developed should be specific to local economic and social structures, and be designed to maintain a high level of employment within the agricultural sector. Newly introduced technology also should use inputs that can be obtained or produced locally as far as possible. The projected widening gap between worldwide food production and demand suggests that developed nations will supply large quantities of agricultural commodities to less developed regions. by 1985. Whether these transfers take the form of commercial trade or food aid will depend upon the purchasing ability of developing countries. Thus, economic growth in all sectors of developing economies is a prerequisite of vigorous international food trade. Developed Countries The world's developed countries are not expected to encounter major problems in meeting their own food consumption requirements during the next decade. Economic demand will exceed adequate nutritional requirements by a significant margin, though distributional problems will remain within each country, including the U.S. Population growth rates appear to be declining. In fact, the total population of several developed nations is expected to stabilize by the year 2000. The highly-industrialized countries of Western Europe and Japan, with their populations nearly stabilized, should be able to produce or purchase their food requirements, which will continue to shift toward higher-value products (meat, fruits, and vegetables) as incomes rise. North America and Oceania will produce large quantities of food commodities, particu- larly cereals, for export as long as international market prices provide production incen- tives. In fact, projected 1985 cereal production above the domestic demand of North America and Oceania would be sufficient to cover projected deficits in Asia, Africa, and Latin America. Even so, food production must increase in these deficit areas as a long-run solution to their problems, because they will proosbly not be able to generate sufficient foreign exchange balances to continually purcllase sucil large quantities of food. 52 i Expected large increases in the demand for animal products, in both developed and developing nations, will continue to exert pressure on production resources for livestock and the feed grains, oilseeds and forages they require. A recent U.N. study projects food demand to grow at a 1.6% annual rate in the developed world through 1985, compared with 3.71 in the centrally planned countries of Eastern Europe and the USSR. Those differences are consistent with the projections made by this report. Trade Policies These vast differences in outlook for human food supply between the developed and the developing regions emphasize the crucial role of the industrialized nations. In several areas, their decisions and their policies will have profound effects on the future world food supply. As the major participants in agricultural trade, the developed countries lead in the formulation of world trade policies. Current trade negotiations pit the protectionist policies of the EEC against the more market-oriented current U.S. trade policy. Increased protectionism would inhibit world food production efficiency and could adversely affect many developing countries. The industrialized nations comprise the principal markets for agricultural commodities exported by the developing world. Trade in these commodities (coffee, cocoa, rubber, - bananas, etc.) ericourages economic development for those countries with a comparative advan- tage in their production. Bilateral or multilateral trade agreements may be necessary to ensure developing countries continued access to food commodity markets in the developed economies. Reserve Stocks The developed nations also are in a position to assume leadership roles in formulation Of world food reserve policies. This issue is particularly urgent as a result of recent worldwide developments. From 1950 through 1970, large surplus grain stocks were held by the major exporting nations, including the U.S., Canada, Australia, and Arhentina. However, unfavorable weather conditions in the USSR, Asia, Australia and Argentina reduced grain production by 41 from 1971 to 1972; and at the same time world grain demand increased by 6% as a result of population growth and rising consumption of grain and grain- fed livestock. These events seriously depleted world grair~ stocks, and have renewed interest in the need for adequate managed world food reserves. Two important objectives should be considered in a reserve stocks policy: 1) mainten- ance of emergency reserves against the threat of famine in developing countries; and 2) management of stocks to mitigate undesirable swings in world cereal prices and trade volumes. Cost and control of a food reserve program should be shared equitably by all developed countries. This issue is particularly important to the U.S. as the principal world pro- ducer and exporter of grain. 53 Aid Programs Aid in the form of food is a desirable short-run method of dealing with catastrophic crop failures. In the longer run it should be used only to supplement a developing nation's food needs as it moves toward self-sufficiency through domestic production and commercial imports. Concessional food sales or gifts must be carefully managed to prevent discouraging aomestic prcduction. An alternative type of aid is commercial overseas development of agricultural production enterprises on a basis that provides mutual benefit to the developed and the developing country. The success of several such arrangements now underway still is to be determined. Risks are involved on both sides. The overseas investor risks nationalization or expropriation; and the developing country risks exploitation. International agreements should be drawn up to minimize these risks. Developed countries also are investing large sums of public money in agricultural development in food-deficit countries. Recent efforts to coordinate the planning of these activities on an international basis are commendable. These international development efforts--particularly the research components--are essential and should be expanded. Agricultural development projects arranged directly between the developing country and commercial agencies in developed countries are increasing. Some of these projects involve complete development from the building of dams and irrigation systems on through to assisting in-the organization of research and educational programs to insure successful management. The net flow of financial resources from developed to developing countries was estimated at $19.5 billion in 1972. This is a responsibility and opportunity which all developed countries should continue to share. Animals vs. Plants Much has been written about another dimension of the world food problem--the relative productivity of plants and animals per unit of arable land. By almost any calculation, it can be shown that plants will yield more protein and energy per unit area than any form of animal production. While dairy cattle may be more than four times as efficient as beef cattle in supplying protein, they still produce much less per unit of land than the starchy grains. Compared to legumes, cattle appear even less efficient. However, these comparisons tend to mask several important points: Amino acids, which are the sole digestive product of proteins, are in better balance in animal products than plant foods such as soybeans. Sucn crops as soybeans and potatoes are restricted by climatic limitations to the areas where they are now grown; whereas various forms of livestock are adaptable to almost all the climatic zones. Perhaps most significant of all, livestock are adapted to utilize vast areas where high-yielding crops cannot be grown, and do so with very little attention or economic input. 54 It would be naive to conclude that the world's tight food supply problem could be solved by affluent nations foregoing consumption of grain-fed animal products. However, this possibility does illustrate a "safety-valve" in case of calamitous situations. Such a development probably would not come about as a charitable gesture but as a result of grain prices being bid up during a period of severe shortage. In fact, recent trends indicate that the severe worldwide inflationary forces of the past year or two actually have had a dampening effect on meat consumption. IMPLICATIONS FOR CALIFORNIA The future of California agriculture is tied inextricably to U.S. and world conditions. Technological change, new irrigation developments, and shifts in location of agricultural production within the state have thus far permitted California to retain its traditional share of U.S. markets despite growing competition within the state for land and water resources. This section considers future development patterns of the agricultural sector of the California economy, as it attempts to adjust to resource use pressures within the state and to changes in both foreign and domestic demand for its products. Agricultural tech- nology has accounted for steady increases in crop yields in California in the past and, on the basis of known technology not yet fully adopted, yield increases for another decade seem assured. Beyond this period, projections reflect the assumption that there are many potential yield-increasing technologies which will be developed over time. More efficient use of known technology is also expected as agricultural management becomes better informed and more scientific. However, one should be aware of uncertainties involved in such assumptions. Projected Acreage and Available Land. The planned rate of irrigation development in California is sufficiently rapid, even in view of expected losses of agricultural land to urbanization, to provide the levels of irrigated acreage required to meet California's projected output of food and fiber. The irrigated acreage requirement--allowing for irrigated pasture and double-cropping--is 8.86 million acres in 1985. Extrapolating from Department of Water Resources estimates gives a net area of irrigated land available of 9.1 million acres. This would appear more than adequate to meet CaliLornia's projected food and fiber production. Trade Rice and high-value specialty crops--including fresh and processed fruits, vegetables and nuts--comprise most of California food exports. Cotton is also an important state export commodity. Because specialty crop consumption is,closely correlated with per capita income, 55 most shipments of these specialty products go to other developed countries. Thus, economic growth rates and trade policies, especially in Europe and Japan, are important determinants of future export demand for these California crops. If the food gap between "have" and "have not" countries widens, export demand for California rice--in commercial trade and as food aid--may also increase. World cotton demand is expected to remain strong, given relative price changes for natural and synthetic fibers . California agriculture also will be affected by the impact of export demand on all farm product prices. California, as well as the U.S., consumer prices will be influenced by food imports and exports. The state also will have a stake in national policy decisions on current trade negotiations, food reserves, and food aid. Environmental Quality Direct impacts on California agriculture have resulted from environnlental quality controls on land use, solid waste disposal, use of crop protection chemicals, air quality, and water quality. These are enforced through state regulatory agencies--such as Water Resources Control Board, Air Resources Board, and Solid iJaste !Ianager,1ent Board-- and various local or regional agencies. It seems likely that in the future, agriculture will operate within an increasingly complex framework of policies and procedures designed to simultaneously achieve two central goals: protection of the environment and increased output of food. Crop and Livestock Projections The crop and livestock outlook for California in 1985 relies largely on projections of trends in such key parameters as population, income, yields per acre, feed efficiency rates, per capita consumption, and market shares. The following numerical estimates of projected California output should not be regarded as unconditional forecasts. Rather, they are projections of California output and acreage which would be required to meet future food and fiber requirements under a specific set of assumptions--which are made explicit in Chapters I11 and IV of the Supple- men t . Acreage trends. From 1968-72 to 1985, the acreage of field crops is projected to increase about 6%; vegetables, melons, and strawberries as a group about 11%; and tree fruits, nuts, and grape acreage by almost 10%. In terms of harvested acres of these crops, the 1985 projection is about 690,000 acres above the 1968-72 average acreage, with increases roughly of 389,000 acres of field crops, 85,000 acres of vegetables, melons, and strawberries, and i64,UOO acres of tree fruits, nuts, and grapes (see Table). This projected composi- tion would indicate continuation of the trend toward higher-value specialty crops in Cali- fornia. Although increases are noted for grain acreage (barley, wheat, grain sorghum, corn, and oats), California is now and will continue to be a substantial importer of small grains. Vegetables. Processing tomatoes are by far the most important single vegetable crop occupying more than 25% of the state vegetable crop acreage. Primarily because 56 Table Summary of California Harvested Acreages of Field Crops, Vegetables, Tree Fruits, Nuts, and Grapes: Projections to 1985 Compared With 1968-72 Averages and 1970 to 1972 Annual Acreages Harvested acreages/ X change 1968-72 1968-72 average 1970 1971 1972 1985 average Crop actual actual actual actual projected to 1985 Field crops Rice Other grains Sugar beets Cot ton Dry beans Potatoes Safflower Alfalfa seed Alfalfa hay Other field crops Subtotal Vegetables Tomatoes (all) Dark green & deep yellow Other vegetables Melons Strawberries Subtotal- b/ Fruits & nuts Citrus fruits Subtropical Deciduous Tree nuts Grapes Subtotal Total """""" 362,800 2,221,200 310,440 730,480 179,400 84,080 211,800 92,800 1,168,200 661,573 6,022,773 205,520 78,480 345,920 79,610 8,320 768,198 292,302 82,235 375,551 414,203 495,590 1,659,881 8,400,504 """"""_ 331,000 2,363,000 320,500 662,400 174,000 87,500 201,000 104,000 1,152,000 670,800 6,066,200 177,000 74,700 341,500 80,800 8,500 732,200 293,220 82,150 383,280 401,990 475,050 1,635,690 8,384,390 -acres------ 331,000 2,241,000 346,500 741,600 148,000 82,600 242,000 91,000 1,210,000 685,900 6,119,600 192,800 80,700 336,900 73,900 8,300 741,370 298,795 88,750 358,373 433,557 500,473 1,679,948 8,492,148 .-"""""" 331,000 2,003,000 326,000 860,400 157,000 67,200 235,000 70,000 1,198,000 689,000 5,936,600 208,900 87,200 352,800 75,000 7,800 785,300 303,276 89,450 351,099 474,509 547,927 1,766,261 8,434,561 """"" 356,890 2,432,529 329,175 851,007 179,450 83,431 211,800 92,800 1,213,463 661,573 6,412,118 231,931 87,523 388,309 88,622 6,719 853,452 299,718 95,057 315,441 632,691 481,000 1,823,907 9,089,477 percent -1.63 9.51 6.04 16.50 0.03 -0.77 0.00 0.00 3.87 0.00 6-. 4 6 11.30 11.52 12.25 11.32 -19.24 11.10 2.54 15.59 -16.01 52.75 -2.94 9.88 8.20 57 tomato harvesting has been successfully mechanized, California's share of the U.S. production has risen since the early 1960's and is projected to stabilize at about 85%. Sharp increases in tomato yields are projected. Thus, the increase in demand is projected to be met with about 25,000 additional acres above 1968-72 levels. Fresh tomato acreage will increase only slightly. Citrus fruits. U.S. citrus production increased by almost 50% between 1961-65 and 1968-72. California's average share of U.S. orange production has been about 20% in recent years. This share has been declining due to urbanization in Southern California and increased competition from Florida-based processed oranges. Plantings in the San Joaquin Valley have increased significantly in recent years. That region now accounts for over 60% of the state's citrus acreage. Most of this is young bearing acreage, which should reach maximum productivity in the next ten years. Therefore, California's market share for oranges is projected to increase slightly to about 22% by 1985. Total acreage is projected to increase only slightly, to about 225,000 acres. Bearing acreage, however, is projected to increase from about 170,000 acres to 212,000 acres. For total lemon acreage, a small increase is projected from about 54,000 to 58,000 acres. A significant increase in bearing acreage is projected, from about 39,000 to 49,000 acres. California grapefruit total acreage is projected to remain almost constant, with bearing acreage increasing about 2,000 acres due mainly to a larger national market share. Subtropical fruits. California accounts for over 90% of U.S. subtropical fruit production. Total acreage of this group is projected to increase from about 82,000 acres to 95,000 acres from 1968-72 to 1985. Fig acreage is projected to remain about constant. Dates show a decline in acreage, with yield increases resulting in production increases. Olive and avocado acreages both show increases. Substantial plantings of olives have occurred in the San Joaquin Valley, with nonbearing acreage currently almost 50% of the total acreage. New high-yielding plantings in the San Joaquin Valley should contribute to increased production of olives in the near future. Deciduous fruits. In terms of acreage, peaches (mainly clingstones) and prunes are the major deciduous crops. For total deciduous fruits, bearing and total acreage are projected to decline 38,000 and 60,000 acres, respectively, from 1968-72 to 1985. Such significant decreases reflect declining per capita consumption of apricots, plums, and prunes. Acreages of deciduous fruits continue to shift out,of the Central Coast areas into the Sacramento and San Joaquin Valleys due to urbanization pressures. Deciduous fruit acreage in Southern California now accounts for only about 1% of the total state acreage. Tree nuts. The percentage of nonbearing acreage of almonds and walnuts continues to exceed historical averages, but has decreased recently from the high average achieved in the mid- and late-1960's. Production has more than tripled in the last ten years, and exports have increased about fourfold since 1968. These factors, together with favorable prices, have led to optimism for the almond industry. The key to future prices and industry I - growth clearly lies in the rather uncertain export market and the ability to increase domestic per capita consumption at favorable prices. California production is projected to increase significantly for both nut crops, especially almonds. Bearing and total acreage are both projected to increase about 220,000 acres from 1968-72 to 1985. Grapes. California produces about 90% of the U.S. grape crop. All three types-- raisin, wine and table grapes--are produced in California. Total grape acreage is projected to decrease slightly from about 495,000 to 432,000in 1985, with bearing acreage holding constant at about 450,000 acres. Increased yields will about offset increased per capita consumption requirements. However, there will be a substantial change in varietal classes from raisin and table to wine varieties. Livestock Projections Projections of California production of milk and eggs can be reasonably tied to popu- lation growth and per capita consumption within California. Although some dairy products are shipped between states and while California has exported a significant percentage of its egg production, the high cost of transporting bulky perishable items such as fluid milk and fresh eggs suggests that major interstate shipment is unlikely. A suitable projection basis is less evident for meat products. California presently imports about 47% of the beef, 98% of the pork, and 70% of the broiler meats consumed in the state and is a major exporter of turkeys. Therefore, projections of beef cattle, sheep, hogs, broiler and turkey production are based on national trends modified by judgment con- cerning new developments. Dairy cattle numbers are projected to decline from 759,000 in the 1968-72 base period to 733,000 in 1985, a 3.4% decrease. Projected decreases in per capita consumption of milk and increased production pzr cow account for tlie projecteti reauction in cow numbers. The U.S. consumption per capita of beef and veal is projected to increase from 117 pounds (carcass weight) per capita in 1968-72 to 144 pounds in 1985. Prospective Califor- nia consumption per capita is higher by about 16 pounds. This projection may be high, considering recent declines in per capita consumption. Cattle feedlot marketings in Cali- fornia are projected to increase from a level of 2 million head in 1968-72 to 2.3 million head in 1985. However, this depends on the tenuous assumption that California feedlots can remain competitive with large, efficient lots now being developed in the southwestern states and the Great Plains where feed grain and feeder cattle prices are lower. In the poultry industry, layers for egg production are projected to decrease slightly from about 39 million annually in 1968-72 to 37 million in 1985. Broiler numbers are pro- jected to increase from 81 million annually to 123 million. Turkey numbers are projected to increase sharply from 16 million birds annually to 22 million. Given these grain and livestock projections, it appears that California Will remain a major deficit area in feed grains. California and The World Food Problem California, as an important producer of many crops, will play a significant role among the developed regions of the world in confronting and, it is hoped, helping to solve the 59 food problems of the future. There are important implications to be drawn regarding policies and programs in this state. First, the present trend of diverting prime agricultural land to nonagricultural purposes must be analyzed and considered in a broad context of land use planning. Use of our best land for industrial, residential, and other purposes and relegation of agriculture to less productive land may not serve the long-range public interests. Second, water, the life-blood of much of the state's agriculture, should be looked on as a finite resource to be managed more efficiently not only by agriculture but for all uses. Recycling both by agriculture and industry should be more diligently pursued not only because of limits to availability but because of energy costs in getting water to the site of use. Third, increasing energy use in agriculture should be viewed with greater concern at all levels. Procedures should be devised to preserve and extend the availability of fossil fuels for those vital purposes for which no feasible alternative now exists. Al- ternative nitrogen sources should also be explored. Fourth, although commodity or crop opportunities in California are very extensive, produc- tion costs (labor, land, taxes, etc.) have climbed rapidly and are higher than many competing areas. Double-cropping, now only done on a limited scale, offers one possibility, not . available to many areas, of overcoming some of these competitive disadvantages. Fifth, the State of California should continue to maintain a strong, far-ranging and forward-looking agricultural research program, firmly rooted in agriculture and the rural environment in the broadest sense. The research should be recommitted to problem- solving activities, including the kinds of basic research that can remove barriers con- straining future food production and rural development. IMPLICATIONS FOR RESEARCH AND EDUCATION Population Research on population control has expanded greatly during the past decade. Although good progress has been made, acceptable methods applicable to rural areas of many developing countries still are not available. Further research on technological, psychological, cultural, and political aspects of birth control should be pursued vigorously. It should aim specifi- cally to solve problems of countries with dense and rapidly growing populations whose food problems are acute and health care facilities are limited. c I *-. ! J I'm no farmer; my closest connections to food growing these days are my. trips to the supermarket. But I work for the County of San Diego as an environmentalist, and I was the Project Manager for the preparation of the Environmental Impact Report for the Regional Growth Management Plan adopted last year by the County. In preparing that report, I had to examine the state of the County's agriculture and try to determine the impacts of public policy on farming. The results of this investigation were disturbing. A are tvorkinz to hasten the decline of the County's agriculture, and express concern, there appears to be no immediately available, realistic, and workable policy that can effectively help the situation. "- And yet the County's agriculture is not only a valuable resource, it has gained national recognition both for its uniquely high productivity and for the urbanization pressures which imperil its very existence. I can offer no solution' to this dilenm, but thc following article may at least serve to acquaint the readers of San Die20 County Farm Eureau Agriculture with some details of the problem. It may not yet be too late for popular action to influence official policy; but the problem is deep and perplexing, and information is essential. Most of the following article is taken from the report referred to above. It was prepared with the help of the County Department of Agriculture and the County Farm Advisor's Office. - 1- - Any significant population growth in San Diego County will have an adverse impact on the County's agriculture, and the survival of most of the agriculture under existing trends is problematic. This is because agriculture and urbanization conflict in two primary areas: 1. Competition for land, since both productive farming and population growth are largely restricted to areas where imported water is available, and since agricultural uses are traditionally considered "lower" uses; and 2. Competition for imported water, in which agriculture will be unable'to meet swift and drastic price increases, and in which water deliveries may be restricted or denied by lQarst di5+ribUfl;79 yencfe'. --- . These impacts will exert pressures on agriculture which will intensify with population growth. To preserve agriculture-in the face of such mounting pressures, a strong commitment and vigorous political action will be required. One of the declared goals of the Regional Growth Management Plan is to "encourage continuance and expansion of agricultural (land) use in the unincorporated area". The Plan recommends that completion of an Agricultural Element of the County General Plan be expedited. Until an Agricultural Element is adopted, areas designated as Agricultural Preserves on the County General Plan should not be subdivided. The Agricultural Element is currently being prepared by tne Integrated Planning Office. Completion of the Element is crucial because many of the County' agricultural lands are now and will continue to be under development pressure. This is especially true in the coastal areas, and Otay Mesa. \ Otay Mesa and the adjacent areas contain approximately half the County's most productive fresh vegetable acreage, with most of the remainder in the Carlsbad area and also under heavy pressure for urbanization. If existing trends are allowed to continue unchecked, Otay Mesa agriculture is doomed. Already much - 2- .- of the land is zoned R-1 and is leased or rented to farmers by large landholders. Studies are currently underway that could result in the formation of an Economic Development District; these studies will determine the development future of Otay Mesa. The Mesa could develop in two basic directions: 1. It could be totally industrialized or urbanized. In this case the agricultural industry would no longer exist there; or es+abic'shwn+ 2. It could mix compatible industry with a strong agriculturak If agriculture is to survive on the coast, it must be -besp'lfe intensive residential uses. An agricultural industry can, however, be compatible with other light-industries. The future of Otay Mesa, and of coastal dependent agriculture in general, is an unresolved. question, and a ?rea+ deal depends QY\ reachin3 a -~uccessFo\ soldion. Farming operations in the County's other prime vegetable growing area, near Wherever farming operations are conducted within city limits, the problem is compounded. Incorporated cities are, by their very nature, oriented more toward coping with urban matters than rural ones. In practice, this tends to hasten the conversion of farm- lands to urban use. rl Even dere there is a desire to preserve farmlands, the t0obJ.s presently used by local government are inadequate. For the most part, preservation is dependent on two methods: ' \c 1. Restrictive zoning; and 2. Designated agricultural preserves. -5- Zoning is subject to change as rising land values and taxes result in pressure to make changes in permitted land uses. Even if the grower owns the land this is often true; and in San Diego County, where so much productive acreage is leased, landowners are particularly susceptible to development pressure. If strong safeguards for agriculture are desired, zoning is neither permanent nor binding enough to be relied on. c Designation of agricultural preserves, as presently practiced, has three major drawbacks : 1. 2. 3. Most of the-productive agricultural lands in the imported water areas, such as those near Otay, Carlsbad, and Fallhrgok, are not under Williamson Act Contract; Landowners in areas where development seems likely are reluctant to enter into long-term agreements such as Williamson Act contracts, since this precludes profitable sale or conversion to other use; and Preservation contracts may have minimum acreage provisions, whereas the high productivity in the County can make relatively small parcels profitable for growing. Agricultural areas are often the ones most favored for development, since less grading is required, drainage is good, and rudimentary services such as water lines and roads already exist. Furthermore, farming operations are usually regarded as transferable to other areas.; but in San Diego County, the areas under greatest threat from urban expansion are dependent on a very strictly defined coastal cli’ate zone. This same climate zone is already heavily urbanized, and little room for agri- cultural expansion or transfer is left. - -4- Some thought is now being given to another method of preservation, the transfer of development rights from farmland to other parcels. The owner would then waive the right to -the original property to any other use. It's a method which has been used with some success in other parts of the country, but has yet to reach official status in the County. Unless a comprehensive, binding, and long-term method of land use restriction can be accomplished, the County's most productive vegetable-growing areas are likely to succumb to development pressures. Even if such a restriction :can be imposed, however, County farming is still likely to suffer from competition for available water with residential and industrial users. "- The County's semi-arid climate and lack of extensive natural groundwater reservoirs make irrigation largely dependent on imported water. Imported water is expensive; its price has been steadily increasing, and even steeper increases are forecast as energy costs increase. Furthermore, the parent agency for the importation of water into Southern California, the Metropolitan Water District (EWD), is not sympathetic to the use of water for agriculture. The feeling of ElWD is that the District was established, as its founding act states, to provide water for "municipal and domestic uses and purposes". Water has been provided for agriculture, to be sure, but blWD's attitude is that this was Ilsurplusl' water, supplied as a convenience and not as an obligation. A rebate has been applied to agricultural water, but this is because the water is c as an encouragement to farming. The feeling at mmed up in the following statement: With respect to the District, there is probably little that can be done \ other than recognize the problem, and ensure that drastic changes are not made in rates for water sold for agricultural purposes which would have the effect of triggering the abandonment of agriculture prior to the time that other economic forces lead to a more orderly transition to other uses of the land. (MWD, 1974 Water Pricing Study.) -5- Actually, the attitude at MWD may be even less sympathetic than this quotation suggests. An official at MWD recently told San Diego County Farm Bureau farming will simply be priced out of existence in the district's service areas. MWD supplies - all imported water entering San Diego County. It is a public corporation and none of its officials are elected by the public. Its response to public opinion is likely to be somewhat limited, despite the power itswoly gives it. m0n to a certain extent, agriculture may be able to bear higher water prices, although =L. the dwill beh in higher food prices. But an increase of several \tncreaSe reFlee+d/ times the present price, while it might-be an annoyance to the homeowner, would be difficult for the grower to bear since water prices consitute an already large proportion of his operating expenses. Therefore, the important factors for the farmer in the 'competition for water are these: 1. MWD may impose restrictions on water for agriculture, or interrupt agricultural deliveries under increased demand in other areas; and 2. Farming is less likely to bear swift and drastic water price increases than competing uses. Even if prices could be met, an expanding population in Southern California means a greater demand on imported water supplies. It appears that MWD will consider agricultural uses undesirable as the demand for other uses increases. Further, the problem is not simply confined to San Diego County, Growth anywhere in the service boundaries of the MWD, for example in Orange or Riverside Counties, could adversely affect local growers. The problem, therefore, may be beyond the reach of local policies, no matter how effective or bene'ficial. - 6- It is possible, but by no mea)ms certain, that deliveries of Northern California - water will be adequate for all MWD customers until 1995. Even so, agriculture may well be priced out of the water market by that time. The competition for water can affect those growing operations, such as avocado and citrus orchards, which are not under immediate development pressure or which have ample room for expansion. In such competition, plant growers are almost always assigned lower priority than residential and industrial uses. The impacts of growth on agricultural activities, while generally conforming to the conditions stated above, may vary accorcling to particular crops. It is convenient to divide the County's most prominent production into the following four main groups in order to consider impacts: Fresh Market Produce The County's production is centered in two coastal areas near Carlsbad in the North and Otay in the south. Unless protected by government intervention, rising land values will act to make these lands too highly taxed for agricultural use and exert irresistible pressure for urban development. Rising water prices may increase production costs to such an extent that the advantage of climate will be negated, and competition from Mexico and greenhouse operations in other areas will take over the market. Major consequences in the County in such an event will be: 1. Irrevocable loss of the land for future farming enterprises, once the land is co v erted to industrial or residential uses; 2. An increase in the cost of fresh vegetables in local markets; 3. In the case of fresh market tomatoes, a loss up to one-sixth of the entire production of the United States, and a lesser but significant loss in a number of other crops; -7- w es 4. Loss of dependent suppo ting industries and businesyand 5. Loss of open space. Even if present growing areas are exempted from development, rising water prices may force cannot be resources abandonment of irrigated farming. Distribution agencies such as MWD expected to subsidize farming, and it will probably be w P 11 beyond the of local government agencies to provide relief. Citrus and Avocados Here the greatest problem is water. Undeveloped lands suitable for groves are s~ll abundant, but orchards will have to compete with the human population for imported water. The operative conditions are much the same as those affecting v A" fresh market produce. In the case of avocados, the result would be curtailment of the production of up to one-third the crop of the entire United States. Nursery, Ornamentals, and Cut Flowers Greenhouse operations will be affected by increased water prices; field crops may, in addition, be affected by land development pressures. These corps are probably more likely to withstand increased water prices than other plant growing endeavors, but here, too, greatly increased prices may overcome the competitive advantage of climate. Again, the result would be the loss of productive land as well as the economic benefits of the production. Milk and Eggs Dairies are presently declining in the County and population pressures will hasten their demise. Egg production may be the single major farming enterprise which can survive a large population increase. This is becuse egg ranches need adequate but not massive quantities of water, and so may not need imported water. can be raised in areas not immediately threatened by urbanization. But any adverse - 8- change in the delicate market-feed-transportation equation could make egg ranching unprofitable. Agriculture in San Diego County has shown remarkable resilience and tenacity in the face of spreading urbanization. However, some of the County's most productive lands are now under great pressure to yield to urban land-hunger. As land values, water prices, and energy costs continue to rise, vegetable operations in Otay and the coastal areas of North County may not be able to continue product'ion without government intervention. The plight of San Diego County agriculture has drawn national attention. In a 1974 "" . National Academy of Sciences study of "Productive Agriculture and 3 Quality Environ- ment", the recommendations for land use policies stated that: Special emphasis should be given to the eneuragement of methods for controlling undesirable development in rural areas that should, instead, be preserved for their natural beauty, cultural significance or high inherent food productivity. (Emphasis added.) The report recognized that in arid or semi-arid regions, the competition for water and energy would militate against efforts to preserve agriculture, but considered such efforts desirable where 'Iunique production capabilities" exist. Finally, the academy recommended the funding of "prototype areas" for the study and evaluation 9 of methods of preserving agriculture. Only six ares in the United States were specifically named as desirable locations for such studies: among them was San Diego County. I would suggest that if this needs to be published in two parts, that the break be made after the second paragraph on p. 4 of this copy. We could use the following conclusion and intro: ... residential and industrial users. Next week the second part of this article will explore some of the implications of the competition‘wwater, and the likely effects of continued urbanization $6 r pressure on important segments of the County’s farming. I ### ”- Last month San Diego County Farm Bureau~Jgriculture began an examination of the xmpxxx impacts of urbanization on the County’s agric ture .kdiscussion “A*/ d centered on the competition for land between urban and farm enterprises. This month we will begin by examining the implications of competition for avail- able imported water. The County‘s semi-arid climate. .- END OF PREVIOUS DOCUMENT. ANOTHER DOCUMENT FOLLOWS February 16, 1977 . DATE TO: Nancy A. Lucast, Coastal Zone Planner . San Diego Coast Regional Commission c FROM:. ' Robert J. Buckner, Deputy Agricultural Commissioner . San Diego County Department of Agriculture, blts. & Meas. File No. F-5031 and Coastal ,Related Agriculture Subject: Re: "Playmor North . The proposed project site is located within the 'Maritime Areaclimate Zone of San Diego County.* - This climate zone is uniquely capable of producing certain economically important plants and plant products which are dependent upon the mild influence of the coastal climate in order to be grown and marketed at times. of year (or at a lesser production cost) when those same crops cannot be grown and marketed from elsewhere.. This "off-season" production is an important source of agricultural products for nationwide marketing and consumption, and. is a major contributor to the regional economy. Lands within the Maritime and Coastal. Areaclimates capable of producing coastal "dependent crops constitute .a unique and finite natural resource that continues to be consumed by urbanization and attending developments, including investment and speculation for uses other than agriculture. .. ,. Examples of coastal crops dependent upon this limited resource include: cut fiotlers, greenhouse groprn cut flowers and indoor decorative plants, and such vegetables as tomatoes, snap beans, cabbage, cauliflower, celery, cucumbers, bell peppers, leaf lettuce, stra\.rberries and squash. *- b 4 * *See map in ''Climates of San Diego County, Agricultural Relationships" University of California .Extension Service and the San Diego County Farm Advisor, Victor Brown, Director. * -. " -2- gOff-season" vegetable crops are mostly grown in the Maritlme Areaclimate, x but they can also be produced in some areas of the Coastal Areaclimate Zone. ._ On the other hand, greenhouse production of plants and plant products is confined nearly 100%. to the Maritime Areacl imate Zone. This particular Encinitas site is fully capable of growing many of the coastal dependent vegetable or floral crops, But, no doubt normal open field cultural and harvest operations and practices would provoke complaints from people in the surrounding urban developed area. Therefore, one of the best agricultural uses for the site Lvould be the production of greenhouse qrown plants or plant products. Just because a site is well suited for agricultural use, does not assure it wi'll be so used; conversely, it can pretty well be assured it will never be used in the future for agriculture if committed to an urban'use now, It climate. It is not marginal in capabilities ....q uite the opposite is true for a greenhouse operation, The expenditures of fuel energy to control greenhouse .- conditions (cooling and heating) would be minimal as compared to locations even .. c -. just a bit further inland, " The soil, even though not classified as "prime", is capable of growing 1. under the Mi 11 iamson Act becomes mute and irrelevant. - - . It is a simple matter for land investors/developers not to farm or lease out their land to growers in order to keep it from producing $ZOO/acre-for .. . L. 4 :r fa -3- *+-X three of the previous five years. By-so doing, the land cannot be classified as "prime" on the basis of dollar returns/acre as set forth in the Idilliamson Act. Hence it will be argued by some that the land has "no agricultural value" because it is "not prime" even though it is adjacent, .in this case, to an - ongoing successful greenhouse operation of no small size. \ *. . The gross value of coastal related/dependent crops compared to countywide production is shown below. The estimated countywide grqss value of plants and 1 ! plant products is 188 million dollars. Gross values of livestock and livestock. products amount to an additional 89.9 mi1lion.doilars. X of Countywide Value of Estimated Value Plants ahd Plant Products Greenhouse products* $ 23.5 million. 12.5% Field grown floral products** 18.6 million Subtotal Floracul ture Vegetables*** Strawberries**** $ 42I1 million 67.6 million 5.8 million Total Coastal Depzndent Crops $1 15.5 million 10% 22.5%\ - 35;5% -- 3% 61 X .. .. . *Predominately produced in the Maritime Areaclimate Zone \vi th rather minor production in the Coastal Areaclimate Zone. . . **Predominately produced in the Maritime Areaclimate Zone; hardly ever east of the Coastal Areacl-inate Zone. - - 7 ._ . .. . .. *** Vegetables are grown in both the Hari time and Coastal Areaclimate Zones. ****Most of the strawberries, although coastal dependent ire grown in-the coastal * I influenced areas of Vista and Fallbrook; a new large scale operation is currently being devel oped in the Ti juana River Valley. c " I : -.. , 1 1 '. .. -,r - 4" It is evident then, that coastal and near coastal lands account for 61% 8. of the gross value of plants and plant products produced in San Diego County, Citrus and avocado fruits are erroneously visualized as beinq the "major" plant products of this County; coastal dependent vegetable, floral and qreenhouse industries exceed the citrus and avocado industries by over 40 million dollars. The greenhouse industry alone is over 40% of the .subtropical fruit industry. - Io terms of regional economics, greenhouse operations generate a base value of about 23.-5 million dollars each year. This is "new" money and is the gross value of the commodity prepared for market. It includes growing, harvesting, packing, selling and other costs and represents the generated cash flow going directly into the economy, It does not include a multiplier factor which theoretically enhances the economic effectiveness of each dollar generated. If a conservative factor of 3 were applied to coastal greenhouse operations i't would result in an economic benefit of some 70+ million dollars .... this is 4 not a one shot deal, but is repeated year after year, It is reported that gross returns per acre of greenhouse operations range from perhaps 'as low or lower than.$30,000 for some types of operations to as high as $250,000 for other kinds depending upon intensity of use and turnover of plants, Some operations may require only a few workers per acre while others may require up to 20 or 25, again depending upon intensity and turnover of plants; the h1ghe.r the plant turnover the greater the labor needs. Unfortunately there is no inventory of lands which show how many acres of land suitabje for coastal dependent agriculture. have been lost to: urbanization,, sold to non-agricuTtural interests, or otherwise taken out of production for related reasons. However, the enclosed graph shows the guild up of harvested . acreage over the last 25 years to a peak of 15,600 acres in 1961- -. . and . the " steady decline since- to about 9,050 acres. The graph does not explain why. this happened, only that-it-did, Indications are that it will continue' to decline, assuming the same forces prevail in the future as in the past- .. ___~~- ~~~~~~ ~ The estimates of acreages and values contained herein or in the attached graph were obtained from annual Crop Reports published by the San Diego County *. Department of Agriculture, Kenneth KO Little, Jr., Agricultural Commissioner. Some estimates, not yet published are taken from data for use in the 1976 -Crop Report. Enclosed are two public information papers on floraculture prepared by Seward To Bessemer, Farm Advisor in the San Diego Office of the University of California Extension Service. -. .: .. -. I' ORN. - GENFRAL CF-Zg9-300-6/76 Seward T. Besemer Farm Advisor Cooperative Extausion Service 'Clniversity of California Eldg. 4, 5555 Overland Avenue San Diego, California 92123 I Floricultur~l - Crops Produced ic "" San I33 Ssn Diego County quite possibly produces the greatest variety of floral products of any similar geographic area in the world. Produced in the area are all the major greenhouse and field-grown flowers such as carnatiocs, chrysanthemums, roses, gladioli and potted phqts. Also, there is commercial produetion of unusual items such as proteas, .GeraIdton Waxflower, leptospernurn, 2nd Caspia. The fcllowing list includes only items which are primarily used for indoor decoration, rather than landscaping. Only generic groups ?.re listed. There are many more species, items. .- Acreage figures 'are estimates only. No accurate survey figures hzve been develo2ed for individual floral -crops. I i varieties, and cultivars which would expand the total items produced to possibly 1, OGO TOTk L GREENHOUSE' ABEA IN 1975 - 430 t?CRES TOTAL FIELD FLOWERS IN 1975 - 2500 ACRES Cut Flowers in Greenhouses Carnations Chrysanthemums Roses Orchids Snapdragons -. 6. Stephznotis 120 Acres 90 Acres 30 Acres .8 Acres 1 Acre "- Potted Plants in Greenhouses Foliage plants 75 A.cres (Leading groups Ere Aglaonema, Aralia, 1! sparzgw Ferns, kuracaria, Brassaia, Cacti, Chlorophytum, Cissus, Coleus, Croton, Dieffenbachia, Dracaeria, Ferns, Ficus, Fittonia, Hoya, Hypoestes, Iiedera, Maranta, Falms, Fellionia, Peperomia, Fhilodendron, Pilea, Plectranthus, Pothod, i. ._ - ' Saaseveria, Saxifraga, Succulents, Syngonium, Tohiea, Vitis.) Flowering pot plants 60 Acres (Leading groups are Aechmea, P: eschynanthus, A hana, Aphelandra, I! zalea; Begonia, Calathea, Calceolaria, Cinneraria, Chrysanthemum, Cyclamen, Dipladenia, Episcia, Euphorbia, Fuchsia, G!oxiuia, Hydrangea, Impatieng, Kalanchoe, Lily, Felargonium, Orchids, Saiutpaulia. ) . .- - Other Greenhouse Crcns 46 Acres Stock plants and propagation, and some European cucumbers. - 2500 P cres '8 .' : Field FIoral Crops .. Cut FIow&rs "" Cut Flowers Acacia Agapanthus Anemone krtichoke (Om. ) &stars (3 types) Banksia Fells of Ireland . . .. "Bird of Feradise CPIendula Calla Candy Tuft Cardooa (Artichoke) Caspia Chrysanthem-urn Cockscomb Cornflower Daffodil . : ..+ *Daides Cktyks) .- ' . ..- .- . -, . " ? Dahlia ' ' Delphinium Freesia .- Gerbzra. __ .. Cut Foliagz i? sparagus Ferns (4) Hezthor Hyacinth Iris Eucnlyptus .. . Euonymus Larkspur . Leptospermum Leucospermum Leuczdendron Myrtle .* Fittosporum Fussy Willow .. Lilac Marigold Nerine Smilax Flower Bulbs and Feouy . Stock Plznts Poinsettia FOPPY A nemone Freesias Protea Gereniurns Queen ktm'a Lace Gladiolu 6 Ranunculus '3 *Statices (3 types) Ixia Crnathogalum .. Oxalis ', - Stock Strawflower . .- RanuncuIus Sparaxis Sweet Fea I- .. Sweet William Tulip Waxflower- - *GladioIus *Gypsophila :-- . Yarrow Zinnia a *The leading vblume 'crops. -2 .y . - - -.- - . IMPORTANCE OF THE FLORAL INDUSTRY TO $AN DIEGO COUNTY>:: -.*:)? e:: f - .,. . ; ;,-. ; ,," 1 ",, <<,.\jS s:; 1.. ..- -a,.. ..,. '1. . , - . " _.. . -. 1 J;, :.-:+::- ." , . ,.",-. 2'. c.:. : ?;. ..' e'. - i. :.-<;!:,3. * ** ;;.-? 4.7;: . C,*r ,?..: The ornamentals industry ranked second in annual dollar volume of production for major agricultural commodities.prbduced in San Diego County for 1973. .. -::: ._ .... il .. , -. . ,& b.; 13" J According to the San Ciego County Department of Agriculture Crop Report, the total .value of the cou.ntyvs agriculture for 1973 was $219,342,100, the highest in history. Agriculture is San Diego County's fourth major industry, after military, manufacturing, and tourism. The production of nursery prod-ucts-and commerciaf flowers es valued at $37,283,000 for 1973. Thls is about 15 times the reported value for nursery and flower products in 1949. The County Department of Agriculture separates.the 1973 value of nursery and flower crops so that flowers have a value of $20,619,000 compared with ntirsery products at $16,664,000. If the value of .cactus and succulents, bulbs, and a portion of herbaceous perennials was' accepted as.entering the florist-type trade, the flora1 iixlustry would have a current annual production value of about $22,000,000. This would pIace the floral indus- try in fourth rank, behind eggs, tomatoes and avocados, for the major agricultural com- modities in the county. .. -. .. f. ._. - ">A L *. ............ -.- . - ........... .-!-;,->L.".,. . "-., -:,a z,;;r.; .. ... ... ... .. - *.:a -. " .._ __. ". . .- . - _. .- -. ........ " . ...... ........ .::. L. , :.,. . -. . q. .: .. - - ". . ... ..... I". - ...... -b- ......... ._ . . ...... .. ............. *:. ..... ..... , ,. ~ . L.,, ::.- .- - . . ,. .._ -. r . .-. -2 :; . . . .' . .......... .. .. , .- ....... .............. .... ... ......... .... ... . " . ....... ..... . . ": . ......... .. . * I. I( c , . .>-! ::_7. ,i :,P." -:- :. .- . ._.:__ :.. ' ..I . -. - .- Froduction of floral products in San Diego County had a subtle beginning. Early production consisted of small field units in the north coastal area. Most of the merchandise was marketed.through the &s Angeles flower m&&;-: .>;' : i . %.$ ..,;A : ... ;-. ..... ......... ;-.:- .. .-.-'** .. -. . .. ... .... . ...... . ,_ -. .? _, ,- 8 .... "" >. ;..7 - ..* : ,j . .:;= >..:'......-?.. 2. 2' ........ ..' :. .. -_ ,- .; .,, .? ." - ....... ._. ........ - . Until about 1960,. gladiolus was the, major cut flower crop.'in .the county;.-producing an annual value of over one million dollars. Prior to 1950, there was a group of perhaps 40 to 50 small gladiolus growers producing a total of about 400 acres of ffowers per year. Today, there 'are only two- growers who produce over 800 acres of gladiolus each year, with a value of $2,025,000. . i r,.- '.. : .-. Greenhouse production in San Diego County started Witli'one commercial cgrnation grower at Encinitas in 1949. In 1960, the carnation acreage was 35 acres and had surpassed gladiolus as' the number one flower crop.. For 1967, the.Agricultura1 Crop Report listed 132 acres of greenhoube.carnations, generating an income of $6,727,000.7 .-. . ' . . .. Greenhouse chrysanthemums began to be :produced in.the mid-1950's. By 1967, the pro- duction of cut pompon and standard chrysahhemums amounted to 52 acres, with a vque of $2,988, OOC), making it the number two flower crop.. In 1973, the value of chrysanthemums is estimated to be. about equal to'carnations. - . -. . _I_. .. :.-..-. .? . ....... ..... .- ' ........... ...... ..... .. -. ." .. .: ... .. - . ~. :. - . ... ._ .. .- _. - ._ .. _. ._ .;. -.- -. _, ; . 3- .. .. .. _I -. ,. 7. .. ..... .'; . - . .- ~.'C . .. .... . " ~ .... .. .. .. . 4. L. .. ,"' f$: ..... *,. ... ._ . -2- .r. :, A - .: - .:. ;. . .... .......... .. .,.\ -, Until 1965, there was ody one greenhouse rose operation in the county. This was started in the mid-1930's in Spring Valley. In 1955, roses were produced at Encinitas by two other growers. Today there are nine rose growers producing 25 actes of flowers. The comme'rcial production of greenhouse orchids in the county is also increasing. There are many small units Which together produce at Ieast six acres of commercial orchid blooms, Potted chrysanthemums; other potted flowering crops,.. such aa poinsettias and EasteE lilies; potted foliage plants; and poinsettia and chrysanthemum cuttings are other crops produced in greenhouses;-: Libout 100. acres is the estimated area in the county for these " . . . .;* ., . : .. ._ ? .. ......... ~ ". . " ' : _._._ . ..... _: - . . .. .' . . .... :t' ,a~r .. 12: ?-+-.: . ';. ;,rf...;..:u;* <;.-!:..>:> fa--". ;- ........ z . " g.r:-* -4". ..)::;;'.??.< . *%-, ""' ..* .? ~ .. ;.! ;.:.c:. ~ - .I " . -. ite& ; . "~ +. .. .:.-.$ g ;.; ic :"!,<if <,:;f ,'. .......... ,: ' . , ",.". ... - A F1 - .... -i ,. ...-.-: , .- .. -,>; ?Ti..:: *:*.: .:-:, : '; - " .............. ..--.:. -.-? .>>...:;;;:":: . . -!-":>i: .. v ~ ..: '.;3;:.<. c-,.:::::.2.:;? ::.-:;.- ..J:-,;;--:; ... r--:;:*:...* .. 4.:. ; . e.. -: 8 .... . , ._ ... :.:Importance of the Floral Kndustrg .. -;.;-; .. .... _. . -. . ;". ;- ..... .. .i__ - . . " ........ i -y: . .:. I ...- ..i.. The production of floral crops is probably the most intensified type of agricultural pro- duction.-" This high degree of htensification requires enormous capitalization per unit. TO set-u@'one acre of a controlIed-environment plastic greenhouse facility to produce roses, carnations, chrysanthemums or orchids, requires $60,000 to $loo., 000 for land, structure, and:dquipmen€.:' Planting stock is an additional cost. ranging from $5,000 to $15, OWper acre: Labor represents 25' to 60 percent of the total production costs .of greenhouse and .,:: .,r:;- '.::;: !,, t" . .1 ..... .... 7 :>-. .... .. .................. .;; "' : ........ . ...... ... . >.-:.x .,,, f. ..,. ~ -jJ &.:-.- .:. .. - : .: - .- ,i-t. ... .... " .... ,-A* < .. - .. field flora1 crops.. .. -: - .... r,': .. ; :- -. ... i.: .. . ......... .. .. ...... ..... -y. ::::- .'; L, ,?, .... .. .... ..J. .. * .IT\ .. " ....... .I.- . . : ~ .. I . - -.-l." The total investment in land, structures, and equipment for the floral industry in San Diego County is presently estimated . - ........ to be'in. - 7 excess- .... of $~O,O@O,OOO. The estimated in- vestment for 350 acres of land .and equipped greenhouses .is $28,000,000 and for 2,500 acres of capital equfpment for field floral'crops, -$2,000, 0@0..?+,-~:!~-.:.. I- 1 SF; '-:: ..-< i i-;*. .a- : . The annual operating costs of the above total acreage is estimated to be over $18,000,000, A Iabor force of about 2,000 workers accounts for over $10,000,000 of this annual cost of operating. Plats, water, fuel, chemicals; taxes, etc. make up the remaining production . costs. . 3: : .. -; .. :.". ... -4 ... :I,.' ........... ....... ..... . ..:+ 1;. ..... -i '": .. ::,. :.; ? " ....... ................. !.,*:-,.. . It is' estimated that 3SO greenhouse acres produce more annual income. (wholesale value) than 2,500 acres of field floral crops. Greenhouse income is about $17,000,000 and field prpduction over $5,000,000. The total annual wholesale value of San Diego. County floral products.is,'therefoe, at least~$22,000,000. "..::. I- .> - .._ . -*.:.- : . .. .. ..... *i< I * .- . 1.. 6) .. !'e;- ! ,. 2.. _. .. i : ~.C, 1:;. ... . -. .!? __ . ... ....... ,'; :. Shipments of floral production frorn.'San Diego County for 1973 amounted to- nearly 20,000,000 pounds,- or about- 10,000 tons.- Over -90 .percent of these: products - are sold-- outside the comty, and are shipped to all parts of the United States and Canada. ....... -_ .... :... \:-I: .. . . .. .... , ." .-. . a. . 7 - - ?:,. ,"..:-.., .* <,y,.. ;.--:=-.y; "..;*.., :- ..-;.-.- : 7 2'. ... 1_1 - - .. .... ........ I .!-. .C'? r:. ..IS. :- .... .- .. . .... .. - . -, 4 5' c-i .......... -4 .. .- . .,; ~ ._ .. .. -.. I .- .. ................. .I; _. .. . ,. .- .: 1.. .. -. . * .. .... . L. . - . ._ _..> .. . r ... ,. .... ..... <Y , '.; : . ,. " -.. ... .. :. I . . : ... . '. . a. .. . I .. ;:. , 7 . .. .. ,. . - "'The production of floral products in San Mego County :is.a dly~mic in*stry.\vMch rapidly gained -its identity $%!ithii5; the last 15 years. Production area has .been expanding at average rate of 10 percent per year. A stable rate of expansion is expected to continue for 8 .. "" . -3- several years as long as certain economic factors remain favorable. Increasing taxation, . untenabIe zoning and building restrictions, and other factors could seriously curtail the industry's development. I The market for floral products is strong. Due to modern refrigerated trucks and'& . transportation, the San Diego floral industry has the capability of selling its products to customers anywhere in the world. Location in the coastal areas of the county, containing some of the f€nest cIimate in the world, enables the industry to produce at the highest potential rate at relatively lower costs than other competitive areas. The narrow coastal strip, only one to two miles wide, from Solana Beach to Oceanside, is characterized with . a high percentage of winter sunlight, mild wintdrs and cool summers, natural ventilation from the ocean, and sandy loam acid soiL The floral industry is not dependent upon government contracts or subsidies. It is a basic industry utilizing the 10ca.l natural resources of climate, soil, water, and labor. The very existence of the industry depends on these local resources. Dr. Harry Kohl, member of the Environmental Horticulture Gepartment at the University of California at Davis, has stated that the flower business represents "one of the last of the free private enterprises largely unregulated by government. '1 , The floral industry does not rely on a local market. Its market is presently the whole ,. United States and some foreign countries. Over 90 percent of the products are sold out- side the county. This brings in "newtT or ttoutsidett money to the local economy. Most of this new money is reinvested in new production units, and payments to the local labor force. The floral industry expends more capital and produces more revenue per acre of land than other agricultural commodities. It is probable that intensified greenhouse production . (which is virtually a factory) generates more econornlc income per space unit than many types of non-agricultural manufacturing. . The floral industry is clean, attractive, and blends wellwith all types of land development. Acres of blooming p-ts are an enticement to tourists to visit the area. There are over 200 species and varieties of floral items produced by San Diego growers for the .commercial trade. The floral industry of San Diego has a future-providing that county officials and the public recognize the potential and make it possible for the industry to grow and thrive. +. *******,* Cooperaiive Extension Work in Agriculture and Home Economics, U. S. Department of Agriculture, University of California and County of San Diego cooperating The University of California's Agricultural Extknsion Programs are available to all, without regard to race, color, or 'national origh I fd